Origins of the financial market crisis of 2008.
Schwartz, Anna J.
I begin by describing the factors that contributed to the financial
market crisis of 2008. I end by proposing policies that could have
prevented the baleful effects that produced the crisis.
Factors Contributing to the Financial Crisis
At least three factors exercised significant influences on the
emergence of the global financial crisis.
Factor One: Expansive Monetary Policy
The basic groundwork to die disruption of credit flows can be
traced to the asset price bubble of the housing price boom. It bas
become a cliche to refer to an asset boom as a mania. The cliche,
however, obscures why ordinary folk become avid buyers of whatever
object has become the target of desire. An asset boom is propagated by
an expansive monetary policy that lowers interest rates and induces
borrowing beyond prudent bounds to acquire the asset.
The Fed was accommodative too long from 2001 on and was slow to
tighten monetary policy, delaying tightening until June 2004 and then
ending the monthly 25 basis point increase in August 2006. The rate cuts
that began on August 10, 2007, and escalated in an unprecedented 75
basis point reduction on January 22, 2008, was announced at an
unscheduled video conference meeting a week before a scheduled FOMC meeting. The rate increases in 2007 were too little and ended too soon.
This was the monetary policy setting for the housing price boom.
In the case of the housing price boom, the government played a role
in stimulating demand for houses by proselytizing the benefits of home
ownership for the well-being of individuals and families. Congress was
also more than a bit player in this campaign. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were created as government-sponsored enterprises. Beginning in 1992
Congress pushed Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to increase their purchases
of mortgages going to low- and moderate-income borrowers. In 1996, HUD,
the department of Housing and Urban Development, gave Fannie and Freddie
an explicit target: 42 percent of their mortgage financing had to go to
borrowers with incomes below the median income in their area. The target
increased to 50 percent in 2000 and 52 percent in 2005. For 1996, HUD
required that 12 percent of all mortgage purchases by Fannie and Freddie
had to be "special affordable" loans, typically to borrowers
with incomes less than 60 percent of their area's median income.
That number was increased to 20 percent in 2000 and 22 percent in 2005.
The 2008 goal was to be 28 percent. Between 2000 and 2005 Freddie and
Fannie met those goals every year, and funded hundreds of billions of
dollars worth of loans, many of them subprime and adjustable-rate loans
made to borrowers who bought houses with less than 10 percent down.
Fannie and Freddie also purchased hundreds of billions of dollars worth
of subprime securities for their own portfolios to make money and help
satisfy HUD affordable housing goals. Fannie and Freddie were important
contributors to the demand for subprime securities. Congress designed
Fannie and Freddie to serve both their investors and the political
class. Demanding that Fannie and Freddie do more to increase home
ownership among poor people allowed Congress and the White House to
subsidize low-income housing outside of the budget, at least in the
short run. Unfortunately, that strategy remains at the heart of the
political process, and of proposed solutions to this crisis (Roberts
2008). Fannie and Freddie were active politically, extending campaign
contributions to legislators.
Factor Two: Flawed Financial Innovations
A second factor that influenced the emergence of the credit crisis
was the adoption of innovations in investment instruments such as
securitization, derivatives, and auction-rate securities before markets
became aware of the flaws in the design of these instruments. The basic
flaw in each of them was the difficulty of determining their price.
Securitization substituted the "originate to distribute
securities" model of mortgage lending in lieu of the traditional
"originate to hold mortgages" model. Additional banking
innovations, notably the practices of the derivatives industry, made
mortgage lending problems worse, shifting risk that is the basic
property of derivatives in directions that became so complex that
neither the designer nor the buyer of these instruments apparently
understood the risks they imposed and implicated derivative owners in
risky contingencies they did not realize they were assuming. Derivatives
as well as mortgage-backed securities were difficult to price, an art
that markets haven't mastered. The securitization of mortgage loans
spread from the mortgage industry to commercial paper issuance, student
loans, credit card receivables, and other loan categories. The design of
mortgage-backed securities collateralized by a pool of mortgages assumed
that the pool would give the securities value. The pool, however, was an
assortment of mortgages of varying quality. The designers gave no
guidance on how to price the pool. They claimed that rating agencies
would determine the price of the security. But the rating agencies had
no formula for this task. They assigned ratings to complex securities as
if they were ordinary corporate bonds and without examining the
individual mortgages in the pool. Ratings tended to overstate the value
of the securities and were fundamentally arbitrary. Absent
securitization, all the various peripheral players in the credit market
debacle including the bond insurers, who unwisely insured securities
linked to subprime mortgages, would not have been drawn into the
subsidiary roles they exploited.
Securities and banking supervisors knew that packaging of mortgage
loans for resale as securities to investors was a threat to both
investors and mortgage borrowers, but remained on the sidelines and made
no attempt to halt the processes as they unfolded and transformed the
mortgage market.
Factor Three: The Collapse of Trading
A third factor leading to the emergence of the credit crisis was
the collapse of the market for some financial instruments. One
particularly important instrument was the auction rate security, a
long-term instrument for which the interest rate is reset periodically
at auctions. The instrument was introduced in 1984 as an alternative to
long-term debt for borrowers who need long-teen funding; but serves as a
short-term security. In 2007 outstanding auction rate securities
amounted to $330 billion. Normally, the periodic auctions give the bonds
the liquidity of a short-term asset that trades at about par. The main
issuers of auction rate securities have been municipalities, hospitals,
museums, student loan finance authorities, and closed-end mutual funds.
When an auction fails, there are fewer bidders than the number of
securities to be sold. When this happens, the securities are priced at a
penalty rate--typically, the state usury maximum, or a spread over
Libor. This means the investor is unable to redeem his money and the
issuer has to pay a higher rate to borrow.
Failed auctions were rare before the credit market crisis. The
banks that conducted the auctions would inject their own capital to
prevent an auction failure. From the fall of 2007 on, these banks
experienced credit losses and mortgage writedowns as a result of the
subprime mortgage market collapse, and became less willing to commit
their own money to keep auctions from failing. By February 2008 fears of
such failures led investors to withdraw funds from the auction rate
securities market. The rate on borrowing costs rose sharply after failed
auctions. The market became chaotic with different rates resulting for
basically identical auction rate securities. Different sectors have been
distressed by the failure of the auction rate securities market (Chicago
Feel Letter 2008).
The flaw in the design of this instrument has been revealed by its
market collapse. A funding instrument that appears long-term to the
borrower but short-term to the lender is an illusion. A funding
instrument that is long-term for one party must be long-term for the
counterparty. The auction rate securities market is another example of
ingenuity, similar to the brainstorm that produced securitization. Each
seemed to be a brilliant innovation. Securitization produced products
that were difficult to price. Auction rate securities could not survive
the inherent falsity of its conception. Both proved disastrous for
credit market operations.
How to Avoid a Replay of the Three Factors That Produced the Credit
Market Debacle
With respect to the first factor I've mentioned--the role of
expansive monetary policy in propagating the housing price boom--let me
first respond to Alan Greenspan's argument that no central bank
could have terminated the asset price boom because, had it done so, the
economy would have been engulfed in a recession that the public in a
democracy would not stand for (Greenspan 2008: 523). The argument is
fallacious. Greenspan does not explain why the Fed could not have
conducted a less expansive monetary policy that did not lower interest
rates to levels that made mortgage lending and borrowing appear riskless
and encouraged house price increases. If monetary policy had been more
restrictive, the asset price boom in housing could have been avoided
The second factor I mentioned that led to the credit market debacle
was the premature adoption of innovations in investment instruments that
were flawed, principally because pricing the new instruments was
difficult. Credit markets cannot operate normally if an accurate price
cannot be assigned to the assets a would-be borrower includes in his
portfolio. The lesson for investors' embrace of mortgage-backed
securities and other new types of assets that were profitable to many
purveyors of services in the distribution of these ingenious ways of
making loans is to be wary of innovations that have not been thoroughly
tested.
The final factor that credit markets have contended with is the
collapse of trading in selected instruments that revealed their
weaknesses. The losses investors experienced as a result will keep these
markets from operating until tranquility returns to the credit market as
a whole and the weaknesses have been corrected.
Conclusion
Much turmoil may still batter the credit markets. Capital
impairment of banks and other financial firms remains to be dealt with.
Insolvent firms must not be recapitalized with taxpayer funds. A
systematic procedure for examining portfolios of these institutions
needs to be followed to identify which are insolvent.
References
Chicago Fed Letter (2008) "Navigating the New World of Private
Equity: A Conference Summary." No. 256 (November).
Greenspan, A. (2008) The Age of Turbulence. New York: Penguin
Group.
Roberts, R. (2008) "How Government Stoked the Mania."
Wall Street Journal (3 October). 2008.
Anna J. Schwartz is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.