Reflections on the financial crisis.
Meltzer, Allan H.
I am going to make several unrelated points, and then I am going to
discuss how we got into this financial crisis and some needed changes to
reduce the risk of future crises.
Some Observations
First, we should close down as promptly as possible Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. There never was a reason for those two institutions, other
than to avoid the congressional budget process. The benefit that people
got from Fannie and Freddie came from the subsidy to the mortgage
interest rate. Congress could have passed that subsidy over and over
again. They avoided passing it by taking the program off budget. That
led to a benefit to members of Congress who participated in the profits
of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. It is an example of bad government
policy.
Second, looking ahead, the debt of the United States as a share of
GDP is going to go from 40 percent to at least 60 percent. If you look
at Japan, Italy, or Belgium, that doesn't seem like a startling
number. The difference is that much of that debt is owed to foreigners.
Looking ahead, get used to the idea that we're going to have to
export more and probably see consumption grow at a slower rate. After
years of rising expenditure on consumption in the United States, we are
going to have to learn to tighten our belts a bit. That's not going
to be an easy thing to do politically; woe to the president who presides
over that period.
Third, I get a lot of questions from the press every day, and one
of the questions these days is deflation. The last time somebody asked
me that question--it must have been the 15th time I'd heard it--I
said that was one of the most stupid question I'd heard in 40 years
of dealing with the press. It's time that the people who talk about
deflation went back to school and learned about the difference between
maintained rates of change and one-time changes in level. The so-called
deflation that we're going to have is the decline in oil and food
prices that are the reverse of the increase in oil and food prices.
Those are changes in the level of prices, but not in the sustained rate
of change of prices. Deflation properly understood refers only to a
sustained decline in the rate of change of prices. Incidentally, in
Federal Reserve history, there are six or seven periods in which we had
deflation. Only one of them was a disaster: the Great Depression. It was
a disaster because while the deflation was going on, money growth was
falling, so that the expectation was that deflation would continue. In
the others cases of deflation, if you look at the footprints of those
recoveries you wouldn't be able to distinguish them from any other
recovery.
Fourth, is the bankruptcy law. There's a lot of pressure to
change the bankruptcy law to adjust to the current circumstance. If we
do that, the simple fact is, we won't have a bankruptcy law. The
benefit of the bankruptcy law is it gives people some ideas as to what
they can expect under troublesome circumstances. If we change it in
relation to those circumstances, we violate the rule of law.
Finally, I believe that the Congress and the administration are
working on the wrong problem. You can solve the mortgage problem by
solving the housing problem. But you can't solve the housing
problem by adjusting the mortgage market. Let me expand on that a little
bit. A major problem that the economy faces in the housing and mortgage
market is that the price decline in houses stimulates defaults. And the
expected decline for 2009, which the market puts at 11 percent, means
there are going to be many, many more defaults as the price of houses
falls even further below the mortgage value. You want to solve that
problem.
The difficulty is that if policymakers seek to benefit people by
reducing the value of their mortgage, or the interest rate on their
mortgage, then other people will be encouraged to come and ask for help.
To solve the problem caused by declining house prices, and the future
problem of the mortgage market, there needs to be an increase in the
demand for houses. If 2008 were a normal year, roughly 1.5 million
houses would have been sold rather than 500,000. So there's a lot
of room to increase demand, and we have to find a way to stimulate
demand.
My proposal is simple and transparent. Instead of depending upon
government bureaucrats to decide who's in and who's out, it
allows individuals to make their own choice about what they want to do.
If a buyer makes a down payment on a house between now and the end of
2009, he or she gets a tax credit for the amount of the down payment, or
enough of it to make it attractive. If the buyer doesn't pay taxes,
they get the credit anyway. I don't care whether they're
buying their first, second, third, or in the case of John McCain, their
eighth house. The important thing is to remove the excess supply. That
will do two things: It will slow or stop the decline in prices and
therefore work on future defaults; it will also eventually stimulate the
return to work of the people in the building trades, who are a big part
of the economy.
The problem in the mortgage market is that mortgages are being sold
at very low prices: about $45 per $100. Why so low? Because nobody knows
how far those prices are going to fall, they take a big discount. If
Secretary Paulson went through with his original plan, and actually
bought up mortgages, he would have bankrupted many of the people who
sold him the mortgages. They don't have enough equity to sell their
mortgage portfolios for $45. We need to work directly on the excess
supply of housing by increasing demand.
Deregulation Did Not Cause the Financial Crisis
Now I would like to turn to one of the problems that annoys me
greatly. The Congress blames everyone they can think of for the problems
that it helped to create. They talk a great deal about deregulation. I
would challenge anybody to point to something important that was
deregulated during the last eight years. Nothing much was deregulated.
The last major financial deregulation was the 1999 act that President
Clinton signed, removing the Glass-Steagall provisions separating
commercial and investment banking. No other country in the world
separates commercial and investment banking, and none of them have
problems on that account. Nor have we had problems on that account.
George Benston (1990), years and years ago, wrote a paper pointing out
that all of the arguments in favor of Glass-Steagall were based on
somebody's conjecture. Everyone else who talked about it referred
to the conjecture. No one produced evidence showing that the combination
of commercial and investment banking was a cause of the Great
Depression. And of course, we now understand that the Federal Reserve
was the main cause of the Great Depression.
What Needs to Be Changed?
There are several things that need to be recognized and improved.
First, we need to do something about the government-sponsored
enterprises like Fannie Mae and Freddy Mac. Congress passed the
Community Reinvestment Act in 1977. At the time it wasn't
innocuous, but it wasn't as harmful as it later became. The
requirements of the CRA for home buyers kept getting easier. In 2005,
the Housing and Urban Development Agency encouraged the use of
no-down-payment mortgages. There was tremendous political pressure to
put people into houses even if they couldn't pay the mortgage. That
pressure and the government-sponsored financing agencies like Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac began to buy subprime loans, which often required no
down payment.
The extent of the problem is revealed by what happened from 1980 to
2007. During that period, the amount of mortgages acquired by Fannie and
Freddie went from something like $200 million to $4 trillion. We need to
change incentives. If we are going to subsidize housing for the poor,
then we should do it on budget and not in this roundabout method. One
great reform in Congress that we'll never get is to take all of the
off-budget agencies and close them. If Congress votes to keep them, it
should make direct appropriations.
Second, we must note the role of the Federal Reserve in the
financial crisis. Alan Greenspan did make a mistake. He kept interest
rates too low, too long. He was afraid of deflation. That was a mistake.
The risk of deflation in an economy with our budget deficit and the
long-term prospect of the decline of the dollar seems to me to be
minimal. In any case, he thought we faced deflation, so he kept monetary
policy too easy for too long. But no one made the people in the banks
and the financial institutions buy mortgages; they could have bought
Treasury bills.
Thus, although the Fed helped to encourage an environment in which
credit was plentiful, the decision to overleverage and to make risky
loans falls on the private sector. Financial institutions may have been
encouraged by a belief in the so-called Greenspan put (namely, that if
they got into trouble, the Fed would bail them out), but there is no
hard evidence to support that contention.
In writing the history of the Fed, one of the things I found was
that in 95 years the Fed never announced what its "lender of last
resort" policy was (see Meltzer 2003, 2009). Sometimes it bailed
out banks; sometimes it let them fail; and sometimes it did something
intermediate. It negotiated some arrangements like those with Long-Term
Capital Management and, more recently, Bear Stearns, where somebody
would take them over. The Fed would not let them go bankrupt. Absence of
a clear policy creates uncertainty, particularly in times like these.
In the case of Bear Stearns, the Fed semi-rescued the financial
giant, but then let Lehman Brothers fail. If you are running a portfolio
what are you supposed to believe is the next step? The next step may be
that the Fed helps you or that they don't. Uncertainty increased.
After Lehman failed, portfolio managers ran for Treasury bills and drove
the Treasury bill rate down to something close to zero. Creating massive
uncertainty was a mistake, a mistake that needs to be corrected. The Fed
needs to announce, and insist upon--that's the hard part--its
"lender of last resort" policy. It must get rid of "too
big to fail." If a bank is too big to fail, it's too big.
Third, I would say there is a problem about compensation. We had
MBAs who were 5 years or 10 years out of the best business schools in
the world buying and selling stuff that is junk. Why did they do it?
They were well rewarded for doing it and they got fired if they
didn't do it, so they did it and they made a lot of money. It
didn't happen at all banks. JPMorgan Chase is obviously an example,
as is Pittsburgh National. Bank of America was an example before it
acquired Countrywide and Merrill Lynch. They didn't do what
Citigroup and some of the others have done. Management has to think
about the way in which they compensate people and to spread compensation
over a longer period of time. Management and its employees must have
something at stake when they transact. The fact that we have had two
crises within a few years--the dot-com crisis and the
banking-financial-housing crisis--has a lot to do with the way people
are compensated. This is an issue for managements, not governments.
Fourth, the regulators never mention the fact that the Basel Accord contributed to the current problems. In my book, A History of the
Federal Reserve (2009), I say, and repeat very often these days, that
lawyers and bureaucrats make regulations but markets learn to circumvent
the expensive ones. The Basel Accord was an agreement which said to
banks, if you hold more risky assets, you have to hold more capital.
What did the banks do? They didn't hold more capital; they took the
risky assets off their balance sheets. That's a good example of
circumventing costly regulation. There are many other examples:
Regulation Q was one. In my book I give other examples of circumvented
regulation.
Fifth, Wall Street firms got too clever. They invented mortgage
instruments that they can't now unwind. That contributes a lot to
the present crisis. When Sheila Bair says we should just "forgive
the people who default," she overlooks that it's not going to
be easy to collect the pieces of those mortgages and put them back
together again. They're not just sitting there the way they were in
the days of the old savings and loan associations where there was a
mortgage and even if it had been sold, it was sold in a piece. Today
it's not clear who is responsible for putting together the package
of the mortgages. People were much too clever for the circumstances that
later developed.
Conclusion
If we are to prevent future financial crises, a good place to start
would be to (1) get a "lender of last resort" standard; (2)
get the Congress to appropriate on the record the amount of money that
they are going to use to subsidize housing; (3) improve the compensation
system in the market; (4) get rid of some of the worst of the Basel
Capital standards; and (5) close down Fannie and Freddie.
References
Benston, G. (1990) The Separation of Investment and Commercial
Banking. London: Macmillan.
Meltzer, A. H. (2003) A History of the Federal Reserve, Volume 1,
1913-1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
--(2009) A History of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, 1951-1986.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press (forthcoming).
Allan H. Meltzer is the Allan H. Meltzer University Professor of
Political Economy at Carnegie Mellon University and a Visiting Scholar
at the American Enterprise Institute.