The Healthcare Fix: Universal Insurance for All Americans.
Gokhale, Jagadeesh
The Healthcare Fix: Universal Insurance for All Americans
Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Cambridge: The MIT Press, 2007, 96 pp.
This book is about how and why a severe economic and financial
crisis may well unfold in the United States within the next few years.
The main reason: politicians have been increasingly profligate with the
public purse--expanding government entitlement and nonentitlement
spending, seemingly without regard for future economic consequences.
The main focus of the book is on the runaway costs in the health
care sector--the main threat to future fiscal solvency and economic
security. The book draws a clear contrast between the conventional view
that higher health care spending properly reflects our collective
preference to allocate more of our money to health care for
retirees--versus the alternative--according to which today's
decisions to increase pay-as-you-go retiree health expenditures
expropriates resources from future generations.
The author has convincingly argued, here and elsewhere, that the
intergenerational redistributive effects of current fiscal
decisions--which may well bankrupt the nation--are underemphasized in
public policy debates and ignored by lawmakers motivated more by their
desires for reelection than by their duty as stewards of the
nation's economic future.
The Healthcare Fix identifies three problems plaguing the U.S.
medical care system: Many millions of uninsured people, escalating
federal and state health care entitlement costs for Medicare and
Medicaid, and increasing costs of employer-provided and privately
purchased health insurance. The book's goal is to show how
scrapping the current system and adopting a new Medical Security System
(MSS)---could resolve all three problems--without raising taxes, to
boot.
The main problem concerns accommodating the projected rapid growth
in the health care sector's output share at a time when GDP growth
is projected to slow because of slower labor force growth from
baby-boomers retirements. The book describes its proposal as
"radical but simple." It is, indeed, radical because it
eliminates major government health care subsidies: Medicare, Medicaid,
and employer tax deductions for health insurance expenses. But it is by
no means simple because it envisions an even larger government role in
determining the allocation of public health care dollars by adopting a
universal health insurance system.
A significant expansion of government intervention is justified by
claiming that paternalisms runs deep in American society--even among
those that overtly profess to be anti-government. That justifies
government determination of minimum provision of basic goods such as
food, shelter, children's education, health care, and so on. In
regard to health care, Kotlikoff claims that market failure from adverse
selection in health insurance is so severe that adopting a universal
health care insurance system is the only solution.
In theory, adverse selection arises because those in good health
and with low risk of health problems choose not to purchase health
insurance because premiums based on average health risks do not
adequately reflect their relatively better health. The resulting higher
insurance premiums may induce low-income individuals to also drop out of
the health insurance market.
In the United States, only about one-half of the 47 million
non-insured individuals are low income or jobless persons, whose health
tends to be worse than average. Moreover, several millions are illegal
immigrants, so underinsurance among legal residents is smaller still.
Even among children, the data suggest alternative federal and state
sources of insurance for partial years, which imply a lesser degree of
non-insurance compared to official estimates based on the absence of
insurance during the full calendar year. Many who are counted as
uninsured are eligible for Medicaid but are not enrolled in the program.
And a large segment of the uninsured comprises healthy individuals who
may voluntarily choose to forego health insurance at existing premiums
as predicted by adverse selection theory. Thus, the widely cited 47
million estimate of the number of uninsured is considerably overblown,
as is the book's case for universal health insurance based on it.
Although future budget expenditures and health insurance costs are
projected to increase too rapidly for comfort, those factors alone do
not support the case for universal health insurance.
Health care reform proposals are a dime-a-dozen today. The book
provides a "paternalist's" critique of three major ones:
President George W. Bush's proposal to exempt from income taxes up
to $15,000 in health care expenses for everyone--even those not covered under employer plans--lacks compulsion, doesn't help low-income
groups, does not address problems of adverse selection, and is too
generous toward high-income groups. "Hillary-care"--the plan
developed under President Bill Clinton's Administration in 1992--is
too complicated and would require a huge bureaucracy to operate; and
more recent proposals in California and Massachusetts for mandating
health insurance purchases with subsidies for low-income individuals
would expand Medicaid enrollments and worsen government budgets. None of
these plans adhere to the author's paternalist vision of universal
health care "without subsidies."
Kotlikoff claims that his 10-point Medical Security System would be
superior. MSS makes participation mandatory and awards vouchers to all
for purchasing health insurance. Voucher awards based on individual
experience ratings would provide more resources to high health risk
individuals for purchasing broader health insurance coverage. It would
also reduce insurers' incentives to deny coverage to those with
high health risks. Growth in total voucher value would be limited to GDP
growth. Insurers would compete to provide health plans in conformity
with basic coverage as defined by the government.
A problem could arise, however, if there were insufficient data for
constructing experience ratings. The government currently has
considerable data on the health risks facing the elderly, but similar
data may not be available for younger age groups of all types. Second,
experience ratings for different groups are usually based on the
assumptions of independence and homogeneity (across both risk types and
over time), but both assumptions may be violated in practice. For
example, it remains unclear to what extent the government would be
"on the hook" under a contagious disease outbreak such as the
much-feared avian flu.
Kotlikoff proposes to limit voucher growth to growth in aggregate
GDP. But vouchers by themselves will not solve the Samaritan's
dilemma, which lies at the core of the current system's problems.
Lawmakers can refuse neither to spend more on newer and more costly
procedures under Medicare and Medicaid nor to recognize and cover
additional health conditions and "diseases." A voucher system
also will not eliminate deadweight costs of intense lobbying by the
patient and provider groups--coalesced around specific diseases and
specialties--for obtaining additional vouchers and being included under
the government's "basic insurance coverage" category.
Further, future GDP growth will likely become increasingly divorced
from growth in health care needs due to population aging. Absent
government intervention, market supply and demand would probably cause
the health care spending to increase as a share of GDP: A larger share
of relatively wealthy retirees would spend more because of age-related
needs. Even successive generations of young individuals would spend more
as their incomes increase because, as the book explains, health care is
a superior good. Thus, if government spending were held constant as a
share of GDP, private spending would increase faster as would the scope
for adverse-selection to play out vis-a-vis out-of-pocket purchases of
health insurance. Even in the short term, tying voucher awards to GDP
growth would cause them to shrink during recessions--precisely when the
need for heath care peaks from groups vulnerable to job losses and
negative income shocks. Fundamentally, a rationale for why aggregate
voucher awards should be pegged to GDP growth--or, indeed, be maintained
at any particular (slower or faster) rate of growth compared to GDP
growth--is never presented.
Another shortcoming in the book's approach is its exclusive
focus on the demand side of the health care sector (via health insurance
reform) to the complete disregard of its supply side. This is an
elementary economics issue: If the relative price of a good or service
increases consistently, it is because demand continues to outstrip supply. Reform proposals should focus on expanding supply in addition to
slowing demand growth, and not just on the latter.
Indeed, imposing tight expenditure constraints could adversely
impact the long-term supply of health care services. Even today, many
hospitals and doctors--especially the more qualified and highly reputed
practitioners--reject Medicare and Medicaid patients on account of
strict price controls exercised by the government. Introducing more
draconian non-market controls (those not driven by citizens'
preferences) may exacerbate the relative unavailability of coverages and
health services to low-income groups unable to supplement government
vouchers out of their own funds. If the rationing and price controls
that the book advocates affect health care supply adversely, the
relative price differential between health care and other consumption
may become larger rather than smaller.
Finally, the proposal envisions government control over all types
of health care services, the amount of coverages allowed and disallowed,
the rate of growth of vouchers, who receives rebates and who
doesn't, what type of behaviors earn rebates, what types do not.
This is tantamount to introducing non-market rationing with a large
scope for errors. It is instructive to note that market failure in a
sector doesn't necessarily justify massive government
intervention--or, in this case, a replacement of one type of
intervention with another--because government failure under the new
system could turn out to be even more serious.
Jagadeesh Gokhale
Cato Institute