The case for price stability with a flexible exchange rate in the New Neoclassical Synthesis.
Goodfriend, Marvin
The New Neoclassical Synthesis is a natural starting point for the
consideration of welfare-maximizing monetary arrangements in the
international context. Alternatively known as the New Keynesian model,
this consensus model of monetary policy deserves our attention because
it embodies cumulative advances in theory and policy informed by decades
of monetary experience from around the world. The consensus model with
its prescription for price stability serves today as the foundation for
thinking about monetary policy at central banks and universities
worldwide. (1)
The purpose of the article is to review the fundamental principles
of monetary policy in terms of the New Synthesis. The first section
describes briefly the structure of the baseline NNS model. The second
section presents the ease for price stability in the NNS model. The
third section extends the discussion to the open economy and presents
the NNS case for a flexible exchange rate. The fourth section tells why
monetary policy is fragile that simultaneously attempts to fix the
foreign exchange rate and pursue interest rate policy to sustain price
stability.
The New Neoclassical Synthesis
The convergence of thinking embodied in the modern consensus model
of monetary policy is reflected in the fact that it goes by two
names--the New Neoclassical Synthesis and the New Keynesian model. The
NNS framework inherits intertemporal optimization, rational
expectations, and a real business cycle (RBC) core from the classical
side, and monopolistic competition, nominal price rigidities, and a
prominent role for monetary stabilization policy from the Keynesian
side. Both classical and Keynesian contributions are compatible in the
NNS framework because of its microeconomic foundations.
The baseline NNS model is built up from household intertemporal
utility maximization and firm profit maximization. (2) In the NNS model,
representative households maximize utility by choosing life-time
consumption, and how much work effort to supply each period to firms
which produce the consumption goods.
Monopolistically competitive firms produce differentiated
consumption goods, exercise market power, and maximize profits by
pricing their differentiated products at a markup over marginal
production costs. Firms are owned by households, which earn both wage
and profit income. Households have access to a credit market where they
can borrow or lend. Households take product prices, the red wage in the
labor market, and the real interest rate in the credit market as given
in making their choices. Firms take wages as given when choosing how
much work effort to hire in the labor market.
A firm incurs decision costs to determine the relative price that
maximizes its profits. Pricing decisions must be overseen by management.
Pressing problems compete for scarce management time. Hence, pricing
gets management's attention on a stochastic basis depending on its
perceived urgency relative to other pressing concerns.
The NNS model puts the markup at the core of the pricing decision.
According to the model, a firm considers changing its nominal product
price only when demand or cost conditions are expected to move its
actual markup significantly and persistently away from its
flexible-price profit-maximizing markup. For instance, a firm would
raise its nominal product price if higher nominal wage growth or lower
productivity growth threatened to compress its actual markup relative to
its flexible-price profit-maximizing markup. On the other hand, a firm
would consider lowering its nominal product price if lower nominal wage
growth or higher productivity growth threatened to elevate its actual
markup relative to its flexible-price profit-maximizing markup.
The Case for Price Stability
The case for price stability; in the NNS model is as follows. (3)
An environment in which the price level is stable must be one in which
actual markups equal flexible-price profit maximizing markups.
Otherwise, firms would not be content to keep their product prices
constant. The fundamental NNS insight is that price level stability
makes the economy behave as if firms adjusted their product prices
flexibly and continuously to sustain their flexible-price
profit-maximizing markups. Hence, NNS logic tells us that price
stability rids the economy of monetary frictions due to price stickiness
of the kind long ago identified by Keynes and other economists as a
source of employment fluctuations due to fluctuations in aggregate
demand.
But there is more. According to the NNS framework, price stability
therefore makes the economy conform to potential output, defined as the
fluctuating level of aggregate output determined by supply factors such
as productivity shocks in the real business cycle core of the economy.
Moreover, price stability maximizes household welfare in the NNS
framework because price stability eliminates fluctuations in actual
relative to flexible-price markups that would otherwise occur due to
sticky prices.
The case for price stability carries over also to a targeted trend
rate of inflation. An environment in which inflation is credibly
targeted by a central bank is one in which firms raise product prices at
the trend rate of inflation because they expect the central bank to
sustain an environment in which nominal wage growth in conjunction with
productivity growth raise nominal marginal cost at the targeted rate of
inflation. Then firms can be confident that raising prices at the
targeted trend rate of inflation will keep actual markups stabilized at
flexible-price profit-maximizing markups.
The NNS framework makes clear why monetary policy must put a
priority on anchoring inflation expectations. Failing to act against
elevated inflation expectations encourages firms to move actual prices
up with expected price increases. The only way that monetary policy can
block an "inflation scare" from being passed through to actual
inflation is by tightening monetary policy sufficiently. A policy
tightening must create a deficiency of aggregate demand to weaken labor
markets, depress wage growth relative to inflation, and elevate markups
to create a countervailing deflationary force.
In other words, failing to anchor inflation expectations exposes a
central bank to circumstances that force it deliberately to create a
recession in order to stabilize inflation. Numerous recessions in the
United States and elsewhere occurred prior to the secular stabilization
of inflation in the 1980s because central banks were insufficiently
preemptive of rising inflation and inflation expectations. The pattern
of rising inflation followed by a monetary tightening and a recession
was repeated so often that it is known as "go-stop monetary
policy." The tendency toward go-stop policy has greatly diminished
since the mid-1980s, aim the volatility of both inflation and output are
so much reduced that the period has come to be known as the "Great
Moderation."
The Case for a Flexible Exchange Rate
The question of exchange rate regime in the NNS is best approached
by asking how inflation should be targeted in an economy with both a
monopolistically competitive sticky-price sector and a flexible-price
sector. For instance, food and energy prices are highly flexible. So the
question arises whether an inflation target should include both sticky
and flexible prices.
NNS reasoning is clear on this: monetary policy should target the
measure of inflation that makes the economy behave as much like a
flexible-price economy--that is, as much like the flexible-price
monopolistically competitive RBC core of an NNS economy--as possible. It
follows that a central bank should target an objective for low core
inflation, an index that includes only sticky prices of monopolistically
competitive firms. Targeting core inflation allows the economy to adjust
to fluctuations in relative prices for such goods as food and fuel while
core inflation and employment in the monopolistically competitive sector
are stabilized.
To target headline inflation, on the other hand, a central bank
would counteract an increase in flexible prices by tightening monetary
policy to contract employment in the monopolistically competitive
sector. Doing so would elevate markups and induce sticky-price firms to
cut their prices in order to offset the effect of higher flexible prices
on headline inflation. According to NNS logic, that would be inefficient
because such policy would produce fluctuations in the NNS economy
relative to its flexible-price monopolistically competitive RBC core.
Moreover, a core inflation objective would be more stable and serve
better as a nominal anchor for monetary policy.
The above reasoning carries over to an open economy that imports a
share of consumption goods at a foreign currency price and exports
output at a foreign currency price given in world markets. In an open
economy, NNS logic suggests that monetary policy should target a core
index of domestic currency denominated prices of goods and services produced for domestic use by monopolistically competitive firms. Export
and import prices should be free to adjust relative to targeted core
prices. Import prices could be included in the targeted core index to
the extent that domestic value added in imports associated with
assembly, transportation, and marketing is a significant part of cost.
Otherwise, export and import prices should be free to adjust with
foreign exchange rate movements and foreign price movements relative to
targeted core prices.
In addition to the logic above, the case for a flexible exchange
rate gels support from the fact that the exchange rate must float freely
to clear the foreign exchange market to enable interest rate policy to
freely target domestic rare inflation. From the perspective of the NNS
framework, a flexible exchange rate is beneficial because it frees
interest rate policy to stabilize domestic inflation. According to the
NNS, monetary policy makes its greatest contribution to macroeconomic stability by stabilizing domestic inflation. The NNS case for a flexible
exchange rate is strong whether or not exchange rate flexibility turns
out to be helpful in restoring trade balance. (4)
The Fragility of Independent Interest Bate Policy with a Fixed
Exchange Bate
A country that wishes to secure interest rate policy independence
with a fixed exchange rate has two options: (1) it can impose controls
on the international mobility of capital, or (2) it can satisfy the net
demand for foreign exchange at the fixed exchange rate with sterilized
foreign exchange intervention. Each option is inherently fragile.
Capital controls retain their effectiveness over time only as long
as the international interest differential is small enough that the
profit from moving funds internationally does not overwhelm respect for
controls or corrupt their enforcement. Capital controls are likely to be
effective over time only if the "no interest arbitrage
condition" is approximately satisfied. Countries that encourage
exports and foreign direct investment find it particularly difficult to
impose capital controls effectively because speculative capital flows
are disguised relatively easily as legal commercial transactions.
Interest rate regulations can supplement capital controls to create
additional scope for independent monetary policy. A ceiling can be
imposed on bank deposit rates and a floor on bank loan rates so that
regulators can raise loan rates to stabilize domestic inflation and keep
deposit rates low so as not to attract capital from abroad. However,
interest rate regulations that artificially raise the markup of loan
rates over deposit rates create a profit opportunity for those willing
or able to evade the regulations. And competition among bankers will
degrade the regulations--by lowering effective loan rates with (hidden)
rebates or by raising effective deposit rates by bundling explicit
interest payments with other transactions. Moreover; to the extent that
regulators succeed making interest rate regulations effective in the
formal banking sector, banking will tend to move to the informal sector.
Thus, both capital controls and interest rate regulations are fragile
means of delivering independent interest rate policy with a fixed
exchange rate.
The second option for protecting independent interest rate policy
with a fixed exchange rate works without capital controls and instead
accommodates the resulting capital flows, but sterilizes the effect of
these flows on the money supply. There are a number of ways in which
this option is fragile. In the first place, the fiscal cost of
sterilization depends on the circumstances. For instance, sterilization
can be costly when domestic interest rates are higher than foreign
interest rates and a central bank must sterilize capital inflows (that
would otherwise create domestic inflation) by buying foreign exchange
with (1) funds acquired by, selling domestic securities from its balance
sheet or with (2) funds acquired by creating and selling debt securities
office central bank itself. In such circumstances the cost of
sterilization encourages international speculators to attack the
exchange rate peg.
The country has some choices. The central bank can sterilize less
of the capital inflow and instead allow some inflationary growth of the
money supply. The country could revalue its exchange rate, which might
create expectations of a further revaluation and precipitate a
speculative attack on the exchange rate peg. Or the authorities could
raise reserve requirements, which pay little or no interest to banks. By
raising reserve requirements the central bank could prevent the capital
inflow from increasing the money supply at lower net interest cost to
itself. But doing so would reduce the fiscal cost of sterilization to
the central bank at the expense of commercial banks that would be forced
to hold low-interest reserves instead of higher-interest loans. All
three options are fragile.
On the other hand, if a country is faced with capital outflows that
threaten to devalue the exchange rate, the country's capacity to
prevent this outcome with sterilized foreign exchange intervention is
constrained by the stock of international reserves on hand. Again, the
policy regime would be fragile in these circumstances.
Conceivably, circumstances could be such as to allow a long period
of sterilization to deliver exchange rate stability together with
independent interest rate policy appropriate for domestic stabilization.
Nevertheless, the viability of such a regime would always depend on
fortuitous circumstances beyond the county's control. The regime
would be fragile inherently because it could never be fully credible.
(5)
References
Goodfriend, M. (2004) "Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical
Synthesis: A Primer." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 90 (3): 21-45. Reprinted from International Finance (Summer
2002): 165-91.
--(2007) "How the World Achieved Consensus on Monetary
Policy." Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (4): 47-68.
--(2008) "International Adjustment in the New Neoclassical
Synthesis." Carnegie Mellon University, Tepper School of Business Working Paper (February).
(1) Goodfriend (2007) explains how the world achieved a working
consensus on the core principles of monetary policy in the last quarter
of the 20th century.
(2) Goodfriend (2004) contains an exposition of the baseline NNS
model and its implications for monetary policy.
(3) Goodfriend (2004) explains in more detail why inflation
targeting is a welfare-maximizing monetary policy in the baseline NNS
model.
(4) Goodfriend (2008) develops the cause for a flexible exchange
rate in a two-country extension of the baseline NNS model in Goodfriend
(2004).
(5) Goodfriend (2008) contains an analysis of credibility crises in
a flexible exchange rate regime and in a fixed exchange: rate regime in
a two-country baseline NNS model.
Marvin Goodfriend is Professor of Economies at Carnegie Mellon
University's Tepper School of Business.