The effect of judicial selection processes on judicial quality: the role of partisan politics.
Sobel, Russell S. ; Hall, Joshua C.
The quality of a state's judicial system is an important
determinant of economic growth and vitality. The decisions made within
state judicial systems affect the degree to which private property
rights are well-defined and enforced, which is an essential building
block for entrepreneurial activity and economic growth. The key link
between free-market institutions, such as secure property rights, and
entrepreneurial activity has been demonstrated by Kreft and Sobel (2005)
and Ovaska and Sobel (2005). Bad court decisions often infringe on the
individual liberties and freedoms that are essential underpinnings for
civil society and a well-functioning market economy (see Dorn 1985 and
others in that special issue of the Cato Journal on this general topic).
In addition, decisions made within state judicial systems also have
important effects on the cost of doing business in a state. Poor
liability rules reflected in state judicial decisions have been blamed
for high medical malpractice rates, high workers" compensation
rates, and high automobile insurance rates in many states. Judicial
decisions also impact the costliness of mandates and other regulations
faced by businesses. Thus, it is clear that the judicial system is
important for economic activity, and thus so is the selection mechanism
that is used to determine the membership of state courts.
States use different methods for the selection of judges. In 29
states, the governor or legislature appoints judges, while in 21 states
popular elections are used to select judges. (1) Among those states that
elect judges, 8 rely on partisan elections, in which the judicial
candidates run as a member of a particular political party, while the 13
other states use nonpartisan elections. (2)
The extremely politicized nature of partisan elections casts some
doubt on their ability to efficiently select unbiased judges. The 2004
state supreme court election in West Virginia provides a good example.
This was the most expensive judicial election in the nation in 2004,
with the Democratic incumbent spending $376,000 to the opponents
$540,000. In addition, this spending was dwarfed by the spending on
political advertisements and publicity by other groups in the state. One
pro-incumbent group spent more than $1 million by itself, while the
largest anti-incumbent group spent $2.5 million. The organized labor union interests in the state took the incumbent's side while the
business associations supported the challenger. The candidates
themselves ran on political platforms reflecting their party
affiliation. The incumbent, well known for his reputation of deciding
cases for labor interest and against business interests, stressed this
reputation in his media ads, while the challenger outwardly vowed to
decide cases in a more business friendly manner if he were to be
elected.
In partisan election states, citizens are used to this political
bias in judicial elections, and there is no veil of judicial decisions
being unbiased. Public opinion polls from these partisan election states
confirm this claim. Geyh (2003) cites polls from Texas and Ohio that
find more than 80 percent of adults believe that campaign contributions
to judges running for election have a significant influence on
subsequent judicial decisions they make.
If an unbiased and fair judicial system is important, it is clear
that having judicial candidates run for office on political platforms,
with heavy support from labor or business groups, works contrary to this
goal. In this article, we focus on two issues related to the
determinants of judicial quality. Do states using partisan elections
have lower judicial quality? If so, do states with partisan judicial
elections have judicial outcomes that clearly differ depending on which
political party controls the court?
The article proceeds by first reviewing the previous literature on
judicial appointment versus judicial election. We then continue by
presenting data on the quality of state judicial systems and on other
measures of judicial outcomes, and attempt to uncover the impact of
partisan elections, and of specific party control.
Literature Review
An enduring question in the existing literature is whether judges
should be appointed or elected. This topic has engendered considerable
debate among scholars and according to Dubois (1986) is the single most
discussed topic in legal scholarship. Among the many arguments put forth
by those in favor of appointing judges instead of electing them is the
hypothesis that judicial elections undermine public confidence in the
judiciary and thus are incompatible with a strong and independent
judiciary (see, e.g., Link 2004). The research on this topic is so large
and extensive that we refer the reader to Hanssen (2004) for a more
comprehensive review. However, for our purposes, we focus here
specifically on several recent studies that examine specific measurable
outcomes of the judicial process, and how those outcomes differ between
the two groups of states.
In a study of state employment discrimination charges filed during
the 1973 to 2000 period, Besley and Payne (2003) find that states
appointing their judges have significantly lower levels of filings when
compared with states electing their judges. They hypothesize that there
are two potential reasons why judicial outcomes may differ between
elected and appointed systems. First, the choice of the judicial
selection method might cause a difference in what types of individuals
actually become judges. This can happen not only because the selection
criteria is different, but also because different types of potential
judges may self-select into the potential pool of judicial candidates.
The second source of potential difference stems from the incentive
effects created by the need for elected judges to face popular
reelection. Facing a reelection constraint may alter the incentives
judges face when deciding cases. Besley and Payne conclude that it is
the incentive effect of facing reelection that causes the difference
they document in their data.
Tabarrok and Helland (1999) and Helland and Tabarrok (2002) examine
state tort awards, and hypothesize that when state judges are elected
they will have a stronger incentive to redistribute wealth from
out-of-state businesses to in-state plaintiffs (who are, of course,
voters). Their prediction is that states with judicial elections should
have larger trial awards. In addition, they predict this effect to be
even larger in states using partisan elections. Using large samples of
cases from across the United States, they find strong support for their
hypothesis that elections, and their partisan nature, matter in both of
their studies. Thus, like Besley and Payne (2003), Tabarrok and Helland
(1999) and Helland and Tabarrok (2002) find that judicial outcomes
differ significantly between states electing judges and those appointing
judges.
In addition to examining differences between states that elect
judges and those that appoint judges, the literature has also examined
whether there exist differences between states electing their judges on
a partisan basis and those electing judges on a nonpartisan basis.
Hanssen (2000) finds, for example, that partisan elected judges side
less frequently with challengers to a regulatory status quo, and Hall
and Brace (1996) find that partisan elected judges dissent less
frequently on politically controversial issues. Even within the
literature on the importance of judicial independence, such as Hanssen
(9.004), judges elected on a partisan basis are considered the category
least independent, with nonpartisan elections being the second least
independent.
Absent from this previous literature, however, is an analysis of
whether the outcomes from judicial systems using partisan elections
differ depending on which political party holds a majority in the court.
That is, is there evidence that judicial outcomes differ between
Republican majority state courts and Democratic majority state courts?
The absence of an inquiry into whether party control matters in state
judicial systems is made more intriguing by the relative abundance of
literature on how party control affects legislative and executive
decisionmaking and outcomes. Even when party control is not a primary
focus of the study, political party affiliation is nearly always
included as a control variable to capture any party control effect. Some
recent representative studies of this literature are Pjesky and Sutter
(2002) and Lopez and Sutter (2004).
The issue of whether party control matters for judicial outcomes is
uniquely important for several reasons. First, if there are differences,
previous studies that simply group them together to find the average
outcome for elected judicial systems may be averaging away the true
magnitude of this election effect. Second, to the extent that there are
differences depending on party control, this can create problems in the
long term with stability of judicial decisions in a state, creating
uncertainty and a larger amount of litigation attempting to overturn
previous decisions. (3) Finally, if we can find no difference in
judicial outcomes depending on party control this would suggest that the
substantial resources devoted by parties to win these elections
represents a waste of resources from a societal perspective, equivalent
to the social losses associated with rent seeking and political lobbying
in the legislative branch of government.
Data and Empirical Findings
To measure the quality of state judicial systems we exploit a new
survey-based ranking of state legal liability systems conducted by the
U.S. Chamber of Commerce. This index scores state judicial quality on a
scale of zero to 100 based on a nationwide survey of lawyers. (4) While
there are potential problems with any survey-based measure, we can see
whether we can replicate the results found by other studies comparing
appointive and elective systems before proceeding to examine the impact
of party control within elected systems. If our findings are similar,
this would suggest that this measure is consistent with other, more
specific and limited measures of judicial outcomes. However, as we
proceed, we will also supplement our judicial quality data with
additional data that potentially can reflect the quality of state
judicial systems. These additional measures include state use of eminent
domain for the takings of private property, state medical malpractice
cases filed, and state unemployment compensation premiums.
Table 1 presents data showing the average state ranking and the
underlying average score by method of judicial selection. As can be seen
in the table, states selecting judges through appointment have an
average ranking in the survey of 21.1 (out of 50), with an average
underlying judicial quality score of 61.0, compared with an average
ranking of 31.5 (out of 50), and an average underlying score of 53.5,
for states selecting judges by elections. This finding is consistent
with the studies cited earlier, namely that state judicial quality
declines when elections are used to select judges. In Table 1 we also
show the average ranking and underlying score for the two subsets of
elections, partisan and nonpartisan. The difference between these two
groups is even more striking than the difference between elected and
appointed systems in general. States using partisan elections to select
judges have a judicial quality score substantially lower than states
using nonpartisan elections; however, both subsets remain below the
average for states that appoint judges. Thus, the selection of judges by
election lowers judicial quality, and this impact is even larger when
those elections are of a partisan nature. Both of these results are
consistent with the findings of previous literature. We now turn to
regression methodology to see whether these differences remain once
other variables are taken into account.
Our empirical specification takes the following form:
[Y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[[beta].sub.i] + [X.sub.i] +
[[delta].sub.i][Z.sub.i] +_ [[epsilon].sub.i]
where [Y.sub.i] = judicial quality within a state as measured by a
state's score on the state liability system ranking, [X.sub.i] = a
vector of control variables, [Z.sub.i] = 1 if a state elects its judges
and 0 otherwise, and [[epsilon].sub.i] is the random error term. The
coefficient of interest is [[delta].sub.i]. A negative and statistically
significant estimate would support the hypothesis that the election of
judges decreases the quality of a state's judicial system. A
positive and statistically significant value of [[delta].sub.i] would
imply that judicial elections lead to an increase in judicial quality.
If [[delta].sub.i] is not significantly different from zero, it would
suggest that the method of judicial selection does not influence
judicial quality.
The vector of control variables, [X.sub.i], consists of state-level
data that might influence [Y.sub.i], the measure of judicial quality in
a state. Appendix Table 1 gives the sources and definitions of all of
the variables used in the regression. The control variables we include
reflect education levels within the state, number of lawyers per capita,
percent voting Democratic in the 2000 presidential election, and
judicial salary level. States with higher education levels are generally
found to have better judicial quality. Although judicial salaries are
generally included in an analysis such as ours, their impact is
theoretically ambiguous. The number of lawyers per capita should be
negatively related to a state's judicial quality because more
lawyers lower the cost of litigation (Hanssen 1999). However, we run our
regression both including and excluding this variable because of
potential problems with endogeneity. It is, of course, likely that more
lawyers result from a system with more litigation and redistribution.
The results of our regression analysis are presented in Table 2. As
expected, the sign on ELECTIVE is negative and statistically significant
at the 10 percent level. The coefficient on the elective variable can be
interpreted as showing that a state moving from an elected system to an
appointive system, other things equal, could expect an increase in their
ranking on the U.S. Chamber of Commerce's index by around 4.5
points. Depending on where a state was in the rankings that could be
quite a significant jump. For example, fewer than 4.5 points separate
the 9th ranked state, Indiana, from the 26th ranked state, New Jersey.
Table 3 breaks down the elective variable between those states in
which judges run in partisan elections and those in which elections are
nonpartisan. Here we wish to see whether the real difference in judicial
quality found in the regression results presented in Table 1 is not
simply a difference between elective and appointive states, but rather
between partisan elective states and appointive states. The regression
results presented in Table 3 give some credence to the idea that it is
the partisan nature of judicial elections, not just the elections
themselves, which really influence state judicial quality. The sign on
PARTISAN is negative and statistically significant at the 1 percent
level. Although the sign on NONPARTISAN is negative, it is statistically
insignificant at the 10 percent level. Thus, the results in Table 3
would suggest that there is not a significant difference in judicial
quality between nonpartisan elective states and appointed states, but
that there is a significant difference for states using partisan
elections. In other words, the divergence seen between elective states
and appointive states is really due to the subset of elective states
using partisan elections.
We now turn to an examination of whether party control of state
supreme courts matters in states with partisan elections. Unfortunately,
given the relatively small number of states in these subsamples,
regression methodology cannot be used. However, Table 4 presents the
mean values of our key measures of judicial quality, split by party
control of the judicial system, as well as showing the overall means for
elected versus appointed system states.
First, looking at the overall judicial quality scores, there
appears to be a sizable difference between partisan election states in
which the majority of the state's highest court is Democratic and
those in which the majority is Republican. The average score for states
with Republican court majorities is 52, suggesting a higher level of
judicial quality than in states with Democratic court majorities, whose
average score is 41. In Table 4 we also present a few additional, more
specific measures of outcomes of the judicial process including the
usage of eminent domain, workers' compensation premiums, and
medical malpractice suits filed. In states with "worse"
judicial systems we would expect more use of eminent domain (less secure
property rights), higher workers' compensation premiums, and more
medical malpractice lawsuits. From Table 4, it is clear that eminent
domain filings occur more often in states where Republicans control the
judiciary, with one filing for every 55,054 state residents compared
with one filing for every 605,411 residents of partisan election states
where Democrats control the highest court.
Interestingly, when Democratic and Republican controlled courts are
averaged together, under the category of all elected and then compared
with all appointed, this huge difference is completely masked away by
the result of averaging. Simply comparing elected versus appointed
systems might be meaningless without explicitly controlling for party
control, a potentially important problem not addressed by the previous
literature on the issue. Workers' compensation premiums (largely
dependent on court abuse of lenient benefit provision) are twice as high
in states with Democratic controlled high courts. Again, this huge
difference is masked when they are averaged and compared with appointed
states. Finally, in the case of medical malpractice claims, which we
would expect to be associated with judicial quality, there does not
appear to be any significant difference between partisan election states
where Republicans control the courts and states where the high court is
controlled by the Democrats.
Conclusion
The results presented here confirm previous research showing that
judicial quality is lower in states that utilize elections to select
their judges. Utilizing a new dataset measuring judicial quality across
the 50 U.S. states we also find it is the partisan nature of judicial
elections that is the primary reason for lower judicial quality in
elective states that utilize partisan elections. Although regression
analysis is not possible due to the limited nature of the data
available, we present some evidence that party control of a state's
supreme court seems to matter for judicial quality and some outcomes
generally considered to be related to judicial quality, such as
workers' compensation premiums and eminent domain usage.
As our results seem to suggest, the outcomes under partisan
elections, when taken as an overall average, tend to obfuscate the
markedly different outcomes between Democratic and Republican controlled
courts. This party difference is important, but has been ignored in
previous research. Given the vast amount of previous literature
suggesting party control of the legislative and executive branch
matters, and the commonplace acceptance of at least controlling for
party control in empirical models, we believe that this phenomenon is
equally important to control for in empirical analyses of judicial
outcomes. Thus we view the main contribution of our article as the
insight that it is the partisan nature of elections that causes judicial
quality to decline, not simply the electoral process as has been the
commonly accepted wisdom from previous research.
More important, this study suggests that the large sums of money
spent to influence judicial races are being spent because money can have
an impact if it affects which party controls a state's supreme
court. This has important implications for those analyzing judicial
behavior and the impact of judicial selection processes on judicial
outcomes. Models of legislative behavior have long included party
affiliation. Perhaps it is time models of judicial behavior do the same.
Appendix: Description of Data
Appendix Table 1 provides a description of the variables used in
this article and a detailed list of the data sources.
APPENDIX TABLE 1 DESCRIPTION OF DATA
Variable Definition
Judicial Quality Ranking of the quality of a state's
liability system on a 100 point scale.
Education Percentage of the state's population 25
and older with at least a college
degree in 2003.
Population State population in 2003.
Lawyers Number of lawyers in 2003 divided by
2003 state population.
Salary Salary of judges of state courts of last
resort in 2003.
Elective Dummy variable equal to 1 for states
that elected judges in 2003.
Appointive Dummy variable equal to 1 for states
that appointed judges in 2003.
Partisan Dummy variable equal to 1 for states
that elected judges in a partisan
election in 2003.
Nonpartisan Dummy variable equal to 1 for states
that elected judges in a nonpartisan
election in 2003.
Democrat Percentage of the total state popular vote
for the Democratic presidential
candidate during the 2000 election.
Medical Paid medical malpractice claims per
Malpractice 1,000 active, nonfederal physicians,
2003.
Workers' State workers' compensation benefits per
Compensation $100 of covered wages, 2003.
Eminent Domain Number of state residents per filed
eminent domain taking, 1998-2002.
Republican Dummy variable equal to 1 if a state has
Control partisan elections and a maajority of its
Supreme Court was Republican in
2003.
Democratic Dummy variable equal to 1 if a state has
Control partisan elections and a majority of its
Supreme Court was Democratic in
2003.
Variable Source
Judicial Quality State Liability Systems Ranking Study
(2004), U.S. Chamber of Commerce,
Washington, D.C.
Education Statistical Abstract of the United States:
2004-2005 (2004), Bureau of the Census,
Department of Commerce, Washington,
D.C.
Population Statistical Abstract of the United States:
2004-2005 (2004), Bureau of the Census,
Department of Commerce, Washington,
D.C.
Lawyers The Lawyer Statistical Report (2004),
American Bar Foundation, Chicago.
Salary The Book of the States (2004), The Council
of State Governments, Lexington, Ky.
Elective The Book of the States (2004), The Council
of State Governments, Lexington, Ky.
Appointive The Book of the States (2004), The Council
of State Governments, Lexington, Ky.
Partisan The Book of the States (2004), The Council
of State Government, Lexington, Ky.
Nonpartisan The Book of the States (2004), The Council
of State Governments, Lexington, Ky.
Democrat Statistical Abstract of the United States:
2004-2005 (2004), Bureau of the Census,
Department of Commerce, Washington,
D.C.
Medical "Number of Paid Medical Malpractice
Malpractice Claims, 2003," Kaiser Family Foundation,
www.statehealthfacts.org.
Workers' Workers' Compensation: Benefits, Coverage,
Compensation and Costs, 2003 (2005), National Academy
of Social Insurance, Washington, D.C.
Eminent Domain Public Power, Private Gain (2003), Institute
for justice, Washington, D.C.
Republican Author calculations using justice party
Control affiliation information available at "Judical
Selection in the States," American
Judicature Society, www.ajs.org/js/.
Democratic Author calculations using justice party
Control affiliation information available at "Judical
Selection in the States," American
Judicature Society, www.ajs.org/js/.
References
Besley, T., and Payne, A. (2003) "Judicial Accountability and
Economic Policy Outcomes: Evidence from Employment Discrimination
Charges." Working Paper, London School of Economics.
Dorn, J. A. (1985) "Introduction: Economic Liberties and the
Judiciary." Cato Journal 4 (Winter): 661-87.
Dubois, P. (1986) "Accountability, Independence, and the
Selection of State Judges." Southwestern Law Journal 40 (May):
31-52.
Geyh, C. G. (2003) "Why Judicial Elections Stink." Ohio
State Law Journal 64: 43-79.
Hall, M. G., and Brace, P. R. (1996) "Justices' Response
to Case Facts." American Politics Quarterly 24: 237-61.
Hanssen, F. A. (2000) "Independent Courts and Administrative
Agencies: An Empirical Analysis of the States." Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization 16: 534-71.
-- (2002) "On the Politics of Judicial Selection: Lawyers and
State Campaigns for the Merit Plan." Public Choice 110 (January):
79-97.
-- (2004) "Learning about Judicial Independence: Institutional
Change in the State Courts." Journal of Legal Studies 33 (June):
431-73.
Helland, E., and Tabarrok, A. (2002) "The Effect of Electoral
Institutions on Tort Awards." American Law and Economics Review 4
(Fall): 341-70.
Kreft, S. F., and Sobel, R. S. (2005) "Public Policy,
Entrepreneurship, and Economic Freedom." Cato Journal 25 (Fall):
595-616.
Link, B. (2004) "Had Enough in Ohio? Time to Reform
Ohio's Judicial Selection Process." Cleveland State Law Review
51:123-52.
Lopez, E. J., and Sutter, D. (2004) "Ignorance in
Congressional Voting? Evidence from Policy Reversal on the Endangered
Species Act." Social Science Quarterly 85 (December): 891-912.
Ovaska, T., and Sobel, R. S. (2005) "Entrepreneurship in
Post-Socialist Economies." Journal of Private Enterprise 21 (Fall):
8-28.
Pjesky, R., and Sutter, D. (2002) "Searching for Cincinnatus:
Representatives' Backgrounds and Voting Behavior." Atlantic
Economic Journal 30 (March): 74-86.
Tabarrok, A., and Helland, E. (1999) "Court Politics: The
Political Economy of Tort Awards." Journal of Law and Economics 42
(April): 157-88.
U.S. Chamber of Commerce (2004) State Liability Ranking Study:
2004. Washington: U.S. Chamber of Commerce.
(1) In some states the governor can only appoint from a slate of
candidates put forth by a nominating commission., however, the governor
generally appoints some or all of the members of this nominating
committee. For this reason, the literature generally does not make a
distinction between these two alternatives (see Helland and Tabarrok
2002).
(2) The states using partisan elections are Alabama, Illinois,
Louisiana, Michigan, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Texas, and West Virginia. Note
that while party affiliations do not appear on the ballot in Ohio,
candidates are nominated for the court by a party and thus are
considered to be running in a partisan election.
(3) See Hanssen (2002) for a discussion of why lawyers themselves
prefer judicial selection processes that promote uncertainty, such as
merit plans for selecting judges.
(4) The ranking uses a random survey of approximately 1,000 lawyers
throughout the United States. The lawyers were first asked which states
they were familiar with and then were asked to evaluate those
states' legal systems on a variety of criteria. These criteria
pertained to the perceived quality of a state's legal system, such
as judicial impartiality, judicial competence, and overall treatment of
tort and contract litigation. Their answers were then used to construct
the overall ranking.
Russell S. Sobel is James Clark Coffman Distinguished Chair and
Professor of Economies and Joshua C. Hall is Ken and Bandy Kendrick
Fellow, respectively, at West Virginia University.
TABLE 1
AVERAGE JUDICIAL QUALITY RANKING BY SELECTION
PROCESS, 2004
Type of System Average Ranking Average Score
Appointed 21.1 61.0
Elected 31.5 53.5
Partisan 39.9 47.9
Nonpartisan 26.4 56.9
SOURCE: U.S. Chamber of Commerce (2004).
TABLE 2
DETERMINANTS OF STATE LEGAL LIABILITY RANKINGS
OLS Estimates
Variables Model 1 Model 2
Constant 43.640 *** 49.19 ***
(4.43) (5.18)
Elective -4.524 * -4.629 *
(1.72) (1.73)
Education 1.063 *** 0.811 ***
(3.28) (2.74)
Salary 0.00003 0.00002
(0.35) (0.27)
Democrat -0.166 -0.291 *
(0.90) (1.69)
Lawyers -2.445 * --
(1.72) --
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.261 0.229
Observations 50 50
NOTE: * indicates significance at the 10 percent level,
** at the 5 percent level, and *** at the 1 percent level.
Absolute t-statistics are in parentheses.
TABLE 3
COMPARISON OF PARTISAN VS. NONPARTISAN ELECTIONS
OLS
Variables Model Model
Constant 42.373 *** 39.881 ***
(4.43) (3.90)
Partisan -9.360 *** -9.526 ***
(2.64) (2.61)
Nonpartisan -2.091 -1.364
(0.73) (0.47)
Education 0.935 ** 0.621 **
(2.91) (2.22)
Salary 0.00005 0.00002
(0.71) (0.30)
Democrat -0.154 0.010
(0.86) (1.19)
Lawyers -2.072 --
(1.49) --
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.306 0.272
Observations 50 50
NOTE: * indicates significance at the 10 percent level,
** at the 5 percent level, and *** at the 1 percent level.
Absolute t-statistics are in parentheses.
TABLE 4
COMPARISON OF OUTCOMES BY JUDICIAL
CONTROL OF STATE SUPREME COURT
Variable Republican Democratic
Judicial Quality 52.04 40.97
Eminent Domain Filings 55,054 605,411
Workers' Compensation Benefits 1.09 2.18
Medical Malpractice Claims 19.06 19.90
Number of observations 5 3
Variable Elective Appointive
Judicial Quality 53.50 61.00
Eminent Domain Filings 649,719 535,418
Workers' Compensation Benefits 1.26 1.25
Medical Malpractice Claims 17.13 17.36
Number of observations 21 29