The role of monetary policy in the face of crises.
Schwartz, Anna J.
In this article I first review the Greenspan Fed's record of
providing liquidity in response to its perception of shocks the economy
is facing. It assumed that the shocks were likely to generate financial
crises. No financial crises, however, have occurred. Yet the Fed was
dilatory in draining the market of unneeded liquidity. Failure to do so
meant that monetary policy remained accommodative.
I next discuss whether there is a connection between the Fed's
accommodative policy and the depreciation since 2002 of the exchange
value of the dollar as well as the twin deficits and growing global
imbalances. In that discussion I refer to the need to raise the national
saving rate, in part by eliminating the budget deficit as well as
projected deficits from the unfunded liabilities of Social Security and
Medicare. Monetary policy, however, must be independent of fiscal
policy.
I conclude with some observations on the advisability of adoption
by the Fed of inflation targeting.
The Accommodative Fed
Note the difference in the Fed's behavior in 2000 compared
with the way it performed from 2001 to 2005. Because of apprehensions
that the 2000 millennium would create widespread computer problems, the
Fed undertook to provide a massive infusion of reserves into the
monetary system. The year ended without incident. At the start of 2000,
the Fed promptly withdrew the additional reserves.
In 2001, the Fed perceived that the economy would sustain shocks
that it was prudent for it to counter with low interest rates. Among the
shocks it observed were the recession that began in March, then the
terrorist attacks in September, corporate accounting scandals, low
employment growth in the initial months of the recovery, hikes in the
price of gasoline, and in each case, the financial crisis the Fed feared
would ensue did not eventuate. Yet the Fed kept the Fed funds target
rate unchanged at i percent from July 2003 to June 2004, unjustified in
view of the economy's growth rate, and then only slowly raised the
rate 25 basis points each month until it paused at 5.25 percent in
August 2006.
Among the consequences of the policy of maintaining interest rates
at an inappropriate low level were credit and mortgage market
distortions, discouragement of personal savings, incipient inflation,
and deprecation of the dollar foreign exchange rate.
Are There Links between Fed Policy and Indicators of Global
Imbalances?
In the quarter of a century between 1980 and 2006, in only three
years was the U.S. current account in surplus and the capital account in
deficit. (1) In every other year the current account was in deficit,
that is, the United States imported more goods and services than it
exported. The deficit in the past was small, $1 billion or $2 billion.
Currently, the deficit is about $800 billion. Matching the current
account deficit is the capital account surplus, that is, foreign
investors financed the current account deficit by purchasing U.S. assets
in excess of the purchases by U.S. investors of foreign assets.
The U.S. domestic saving rate is low. Perhaps the Fed's recent
low interest rate policy has contributed to this trend, but there are
surely other forces. One is that increasing individual wealth raises
consumption at the expense of saving. A recent discussion paper by
economists at the Minneapolis Fed and New York University proposes that
the fall in U.S. cyclical volatility, greater than that experienced by
its partners, reduces incentives to do precautionary saving, and can
account for 20 percent of the U.S. external imbalance (Figli and Perri
2006). While personal saving has been declining, corporate saving has
been stable, but public sector saving has also been declining. The
fiscal deficit has contributed to the demand for foreign saving to
finance the current account deficit.
So U.S. domestic savings are inadequate to provide funds for U.S.
domestic investment opportunities. What attracts foreign capital to the
U.S. is the economic growth differential here compared with the growth
rate in their native countries, U.S. high productivity growth, low
transaction costs owing to large and efficient financial markets, a
welcoming business climate, and the willingness of foreigners to hold
dollars and dollar-denominated assets.
The evidence does not support the notion of a reliable relation
between the fiscal deficit and the current account deficit--the
so-called twin deficits. The relationship has sometimes been observed,
and at other times has not. This is true for the United States as well
as other countries. Thus in the United States from 1983 to 1989,
domestic private saving and domestic investment were about equal, as
were the trade deficit and the federal budget deficit, fostering the
notion of a relation between the twin deficits. In the 1990s, however,
the budget deficit declined and became a surplus, while the current
account deficit surged. In recent years, as the federal budget deficit
has grown along with the trade deficit, the twin deficits notion has
been revived. The unreliability of the twin deficits framework is
illustrated by the experience of Japan and Germany, where current
account surpluses and capital outflows have been accompanied by large
fiscal deficits that were more than offset by private saving balances.
The idea was that the federal budget deficit and private sector
investment were sources of demand for capital. Domestic private savings
and the trade deficit were sources of supply of capital. It is true that
since 2001, expansionary fiscal policy has created budget deficits that
increased domestic spending for capital and imports. Expansionary
monetary policy then lowered interest rates, which should have
discouraged foreign investment but did not, and depreciated the dollar
exchange rate. The weak dollar should have made American goods cheap for
foreigners and imports expensive for Americans, which has not occurred.
The validity of this framework is obviously questionable as an
explanation of external developments, even though in recent years both
the budget deficit along with the trade deficit rose.
Some observers conclude that the persistent current account deficit
is a U.S. problem that only the United States can solve (Steil and Chinn
2006). They are wrong. The current account deficit is a global problem
that other countries and the United States must cooperate to manage. The
reason the United States is the world's largest recipient of net
capital inflows from industrialized countries (Japan, Germany, China)
and from oil-producers and exporters (Russia, Saudi Arabia, et al.) has
much to do with the conditions in those countries that yield lower
returns on investment there than can be earned in the United States. In
addition, central banks of some capital exporters as a policy choose to
hold foreign reserves in dollar assets.
What then is the path to reduce global imbalances not only of the
U.S. current account deficit but also the imbalances of capital
exporters to the United States?
What the United States can contribute is a program to raise
national savings, in order to narrow the gap between domestic saving and
investment, and thus to lessen the need for other countries'
savings. That step will require political will to eliminate the existing
fiscal deficit as well as the projected unfunded liabilities of
entitlements. The United States must also undertake a sustained campaign
to induce the public to increase its personal saving rate.
The Fed must be a bystander with respect to action or inaction in
the matter of the unfunded liabilities of Social Security and Medicare
entitlements. These are fiscal problems that should not affect monetary
policy. In the past, the Fed was snookered into coordinating monetary
policy with fiscal policy. The 1968 income surtax the Johnson
administration persuaded Congress to enact is an infamous example of the
erroneous response by the Fed to fiscal action. The misguided Fed
decided that it was its responsibility to provide monetary ease to
offset fiscal tightening, unwittingly accelerating ongoing inflation.
Coordinating monetary with fiscal policy is not the Fed's mandate.
Sooner or later the polity must confront the problem of the
government's unfunded liabilities. The Fed should stand clear of
any involvement.
I now discuss the adjustments by the leading capital exporters with
current account surpluses that are required to reduce their own and the
U.S. imbalances. In all four countries--Japan, Germany, China, and
Russia--domestic savings exceeded domestic investment. Each country
exported its surplus savings, with Japan sending the lion's share,
not because the Japanese savings rate has increased, but because its
domestic investment rate has declined. That decline occurred as a result
of slow economic growth for many years until 2005 following the bust in
the late 1980s of boom conditions. If Japanese economic growth
strengthens and persists, its savings will be needed for home
investments rather than sent abroad.
Germany was a capital importer in the decade ending 2000, but by
2004 became second to Japan as the largest capital exporter, also
because of a declining rate of home investment rather than a rising rate
of saving. Germany's economic growth has been impeded by legal and
policy regulations that stifle business formation and employment. Labor
market reforms have been introduced, but it remains to be seen whether
the effort to improve flexibility in labor and product markets succeeds.
If it does, and economic growth revives, German savings will be needed
to finance home investment rather than exported.
Although China is the recipient of large capital inflows, it is a
net capital exporter, third in order of magnitude, after Japan and
Germany. China's capital outflows are occasioned by its central
bank's hoarding of foreign reserves. Increases in its foreign
reserves are matched by increases in its current account surpluses.
China's saving rate, the highest in the world, has outstripped even
its colossal domestic investment rate. The high saving rate can be
attributed to China's aging population, the absence of a social
safety net, and a lack of financial market provision of consumer loans.
China's exchange rate policy to deter currency appreciation also
limits consumption. A stronger yuan would increase China's global
purchasing power.
The prescription for China to reduce its current account surplus is
to shift to domestic production instead of overemphasizing exports, to
promote financial development that will finance consumer purchases, and
to liberalize its exchange rate to a greater extent than it has
hitherto. The U.S. Treasury has pressured China to accelerate the
appreciation of the yuan as a way of constraining its exports to the
United States. I suggest a different form of pressure on China that may
be more effective than the exchange rate gambit. China requires its
exporters to deliver to a government agency the dollar proceeds of their
exports, for which they obtain yuan. The Treasury should pressure China
to allow exporters to keep their dollar revenues. Some dollars would
probably be spent on U.S. goods and services, reducing the U.S. current
account deficit, and raising the standard of living for China's
consumers.
Russia became the fourth largest capital exporter in 2004. It has
enjoyed larger export proceeds from rising oil and natural gas prices
and its current account surpluses have risen in tandem. Fiscal surpluses
have also risen. Although national saving has increased, the share of
saving by the private sector has fallen. Other oil and gas producers
have also increased their capital outflows and current account
surpluses. Russia and the other oil and gas producers need to increase
investment in domestic projects to reduce their national saving rates.
Some investment spending, however, could be directed to improve oil
sector production.
The foregoing assessment of global imbalances has not mentioned the
Federal Reserve. Historically, the Fed has not regarded the balance of
payments as its responsibility. The role of the Fed is limited to its
core responsibility: deliver price stability. By performing this role,
it will assure the soundness of the dollar, maintain the attraction of
the United States as a desirable place for investment, and facilitate
the global adjustment of imbalances.
Let me conclude with remarks about scenarios proposed by some
alarmists. They envision that holders of dollar reserves will dump them
because the dollar magnitude of U.S. indebtedness to the capital
exporters has magnified the risk of dollar repayment. The U.S. will be
compelled to raise interest rates yielded by dollar assets, resulting in
a depression that will imperil the whole world. The dollar, alarmists
believe, will be replaced by the euro as the reserve currency.
The U.S. net foreign debt in 2004 was $2.5 trillion, or 22 percent
of GDP. Despite the level of foreign debt, the U.S. earned $30 billion
in net foreign income It earned over $200 billion in net foreign income
from 1995 to 2004, although its net foreign debt grew by $3 trillion
during that period. When debt earns a positive return, it does not
appear to be a burden. Moreover, net capital inflows are likely to
decline in the future as the adjustment process proceeds.
The scenario that envisages foreign holders dumping dollar assets
is not credible. If China and other hoarders of dollars were willing to
accumulate them from 2001 on, when the interest return on short-term
government securities was minimal, why would they dump them in 2006,
when the size of the return is more normal? A switch from dollars to the
euro is also questionable. Is the stagnant economy of the European Union
a credible competitor to the vibrant U.S. economy? The dollar's
role as a reserve currency is not threatened by the euro. In 1995, 59
percent of global foreign reserves were in dollar assets. In 1999, the
percent rose to 71 percent. In 2004, the percent declined to 66 percent.
A flight from the dollar by holders of dollar-denominated assets is not
under way.
Should the Fed Adopt Inflation Targeting?
The Fed has already informally adopted one element of inflation
targeting. It has announced that its target for the core consumer price
index is 1 to 2 percent inflation. The element that it has so far not
adopted is communicating with the public by means of a periodic report
that summarizes the Fed's concerns and how it proposes to deal with
them. Whether or not the Fed formally operates as an inflation targeter,
it should certainly improve its communication with the public. Too often
the statement it issues about the Fed funds rate after each Federal Open
Market Committee meeting uses language that can be interpreted in a
variety of ways. A flood of commentaries appears after each statement
and after the release of the transcript of an FOMC meeting. This is not
the experience of the Bank of England, the European Central Bank, and
other central banks that target inflation. They issue reports that are
unambiguous. The Fed should study these reports and try to improve the
content of its communications.
On the central issue of whether the Fed should formally declare
that it will target inflation, Alan Greenspan's opposition to such
a course should give advocates pause. He cautioned that an inflation
target would imperil the Fed's independence, that Congress would
feel free to advise the Fed that the target was too low, that a
recession labeled "a jobless recession" would motivate
legislators to draft legislation instructing the Fed to raise the target
enough to generate jobs, and that, if the Fed has a target for
inflation, it can also have a target for real GDP growth. I believe
these are serious reasons for the Fed to hesitate about adopting an
inflation target.
References
Economic Report of the President (2006) Transmitted to the Congress
February 2006 Together with the Annual Report of the Council of Economic
Advisers. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Feldstein, M. (2006) "Chapter 6: The Capital Account
Surplus." Journal of Economic Literature 44 (September): 676-79.
Figli, A., and Perri, F. (2006) "The Great Moderation and the
U.S. External Imbalance." IMES Discussion Paper Series 2006-E-22
(September). Available at www.imes.boj.or.jp.
Steil, B., and Chinn, M. (2006) "Why Deficits Matter."
The International Economy (Summer): 18-23.
(1) The source of dollar and percentage numbers cited in this
section is the Economic Report of the President (2006). Martin Feldstein
(2006) criticizes the analysis in Chapter 6 of that report, "The
Capital Account Surplus," for attributing the inflow of capital to
the United States to private sector investors attracted by high earnings
of U.S. businesses. That explanation was true in the 1990s but is no
longer accurate. The equity share of the total capital inflow to the
United States has fallen from 54 percent in 1999 to only 12 percent in
2004. Feldstein asserts that almost 90 percent of the capital inflow is
now in the form of fixed income coming from governments that the data do
not fully identify, and that the United States cannot assume that
governments will continue to hold and acquire U.S. Treasury securities.
He assumes that what has happened since 2004 is a trend change rather
than a temporary deviation from past practice.
Anna J. Schwartz is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.