The welfare implications of global financial flows.
Prasad, Eswar
Any discussion of whether the global financial system has served
the world well requires us to think about what it is that capital flows
could achieve in the best of circumstances. The basic neoclassical model
suggests that, with rising financial globalization, capital should flow
from rich to poor countries, making people in both sets of countries
better off by enabling a more efficient international allocation of
capital from countries where capital is less productive to those where
it ought to be more productive. In addition, financial flows should
allow for more efficient sharing of risk across countries, thereby
facilitating the smoothing of national consumption against
country-specific shocks to national output. These benefits are likely to
be greater for developing countries as they have less capital and more
volatile growth, implying that both the growth and risk sharing benefits
would be larger for them.
Have international capital flows delivered these benefits? The
macroeconomic evidence that financial integration has accounted for
systematically higher growth rates in developing economies is not
robust, especially when one controls for other determinants of growth
(Kose et al. 2006). And there is certainly no evidence that developing
economies, or even the smaller group of emerging market economies, have
been able to better share their income risk and achieve improved
consumption smoothing during the recent period of financial
globalization. Indeed, some observers have argued that financial
globalization is the proximate determinant of the financial crises
experienced by many developing economies over the last two decades.
And yet, financial globalization has continued apace, with rising
cross-border financial flows and with developing countries actively
seeking to open up their capital accounts. So what have these flows
wrought? And do the patterns of these flows imply that the international
financial system is working well or not?
Patterns of Flows
One of the remarkable features of recent capital flows, especially
since the beginning of this decade, is that total capital flows (private
plus official) have been from relatively poor non-industrial countries
(emerging market economies and other developing countries) to advanced
industrial countries, exactly the opposite of the direction predicted by
theory (see Figure 1; Figure 2 shows similar calculations excluding the
United States). This is despite the fact that there have been no sudden
stops, drastic capital flow reversals or other types of financial crises
that have hit developing economies during this decade. Furthermore,
among non-industrial countries, more capital seems to go to
slower-growing economies rather than faster-growing economies, a
phenomenon that has been dubbed the allocation puzzle by Gourinchas and
Jeanne (2006). Indeed, as a group, the faster-growing developing
economies have been exporting capital during this decade (see Prasad,
Rajan, and Subramanian 2007).
[FIGURES 1-2 OMITTED]
A large portion of the flows of capital from developing to
industrial economies is of course in the form of official accumulation
of international reserves. But, from a financing perspective, the net
effect is still the same--that of reducing the quantum of capital
available for investment in developing countries. In short, the flow of
capital from developing countries would seem to be starving these
already capital-scarce economies of capital and sending it to richer
industrial countries where, given the relative abundance of capital, its
productivity should be lower.
Does this seemingly perverse flow of capital from developing to
industrial countries adversely affect growth in the former group? The
recent strong growth performance of emerging market economies suggests
that this is not the ease. Remarkably, the historical evidence also
suggests that such uphill flows of capital do not adversely affect
growth in developing economies, at least in one very basic sense.
Contrary to the predictions of standard theoretical models, there is
some evidence that, among this group of countries, those that run larger
current account surpluses (or smaller current account deficits) tend to
have superior growth performance (Prasad, Rajan, and Subramanian 2007).
Consistent with other evidence that financial integration (as measured,
for instance, by net capital inflows) does not have a robust positive
association with growth, this suggests that a dearth of financing for
domestic investment may not be the primary factor holding back growth in
developing countries.
Why is it that a reduced reliance on foreign capital is associated
with higher growth among non-industrial countries? One possible
explanation for this correlation is that the pattern of flows is
indicative of weaknesses in the financial sectors of the
capital-exporting developing countries. These weaknesses imply that the
ability to absorb and effectively intermediate foreign capital is
limited in these countries. Indeed, capital inflows in economies with
weak absorptive-capacity may also generate real exchange rate
appreciations and consequent "Dutch Disease" effects that hurt
long-term growth. Hence, economies that are less reliant on foreign
capital may in fact grow faster. Another possible explanation for the
positive correlation between current account balances and growth is that
domestic savings constitute a less volatile and more reliable source of
financing for domestic investment.
All of this is not to say that financial integration has no
discernible benefits--indeed, there is accumulating, if yet
circumstantial, evidence that there are strong indirect benefits.
Openness to foreign capital appears to serve as a catalyst for domestic
financial market development as well as improvements in institutional
quality and governance, and may also serve as a disciplining device for
domestic macroeconomic policies. These "collateral benefits"
may prove to be even more important than raw financial capital in terms
of boosting long-term productivity growth.
The complication is that the cost-benefit tradeoff for countries
undergoing integration into international financial markets seems to be
subject to certain threshold effects. For instance, when an economy has
an underdeveloped financial system and weak institutions, financial
openness increases vulnerability to risks. The benefits of financial
integration, on the other hand, are more clearly evident only when
financial systems and institutions reach the level of development
typically seen only in advanced industrial economies. This creates an
obvious conundrum for developing countries that view financial
integration as an avenue to gain some of the potential collateral
benefits but fall short of the threshold conditions on some of the same
dimensions.
These threshold effects are also relevant in the context of
realizing the potential risk sharing benefits of financial flows.
Existing evidence suggests that the risk sharing benefits of financial
globalization have in large part accrued only to countries that are
highly integrated into global financial markets; these levels of
integration are typically seen only among industrial economies. One
reason for the inability of emerging market economies to attain the
risk-sharing benefits may be that access to international financial
markets has turned out to be procyclical for these economies, implying
that they lose access to external financing just when they need it the
most. (1)
The fact that financial integration has important indirect benefits
for growth and promotes efficient risk sharing, but only beyond certain
thresholds, has important implications. It may be one reason why
countries that are in the process of opening up their capital accounts
may be self-insuring against the risks associated with open capital
accounts by building up a large cushion of international reserves
(which, in effect, involves exporting financial capital through official
channels). In principle, this allows developing countries to try and
attain some of the benefits of financial globalization, but without
fully exposing themselves to the transitional risks associated with
volatile capital flows.
Implications for Global Imbalances
The pattern of capital flows described above, combined with factors
such as the demand for capital arising from the financing needs for U.S.
private and public consumption, has fueled global current account
disparities. These widening disparities--rising current account deficits
in many industrial countries, most notably the United States, and
surpluses in many emerging market economies--are now referred to rather
ominously as global imbalances. Some analysts have made dire predictions
that massive exchange rate adjustments will be needed among some of the
key economies in order to correct these imbalances. In light of the
earlier discussion of financial globalization, should these imbalances
really be a source of deep concern?
Now that these current account disparities have persisted and,
indeed, continued to grow with no apparent disruption of international
financial markets, there is a legitimate question about whether it makes
sense to continue crying wolf. It would of course be rash to rule out
the possibility of a shift in market sentiment that caused these
imbalances to correct in an abrupt manner with pain all around.
Moreover, it is likely that the tail risks of a disorderly adjustment
increase with the level of imbalances.
Even if these imbalances turn out to be sustainable in the sense
that they do not trigger any abrupt adjustments and dissipate smoothly
in the course of a decade or two, however, it is worth asking what the
welfare implications of these imbalances are. Or, more precisely, are
there any welfare costs associated with the policies required to
maintain this configuration of imbalances.
As exhibit A, consider China, where current account and capital
account surpluses have led to a massive buildup of reserves over the
last few years. This reserve buildup has been facilitated by the
maintenance of a stable nominal exchange rate relative to the U.S.
dollar even in the face of strong pressures, based on fundamentals such
as productivity growth, for an appreciation of the currency's
external value. The maintenance of a fixed exchange rate has complicated
domestic macroeconomic management since it has, despite the existence of
moderately effective capital controls, effectively meant that monetary
policy can not be targeted to domestic objectives. Thus, while the
reserves may serve as a useful cushion against external shocks and
instabilities associated with a dilapidated banking system, the
financial repression (and relatively closed capital account that has
limited outflows) that has helped sustain the fixed exchange rate regime
may have longer-lasting consequences. In particular, the lack of an
independent monetary policy has further hindered the already difficult
process of financial sector reforms by forcing monetary policymakers to
rely on ad hoe policy actions, including moral suasion and
non-prudential administrative measures, rather than market instruments
such as interest rates to control and guide credit growth.
In short, some of the policies that have helped foster and sustain
global imbalances have significant distortionary consequences that
should be part of the welfare calculations when assessing the effects of
these imbalances. This argument has one important implication--even if
each country did the right thing in terms of changing such policies, it
is not immediately obvious that this would eliminate current account
imbalances. (2) Take China as an example again. Notwithstanding recent
modest movements in the exchange rate, the relative rigidity of the
nominal exchange rate has complicated domestic macroeconomic management.
An appreciation of the currency could in fact reduce savings by
increasing the wealth of Chinese households even at a given level of
income. More importantly, an independent monetary policy would foster
macroeconomic stability and could help push along financial sector
reforms, which could also reduce savings. At the same time, a
better-functioning financial system may, in addition to shifting the
financing of investment to a process more driven by commercial
principles, reduce the level of investment. Thus, the net short-run
effects of financial sector reforms on the saving-investment
balance--i.e., the current account--are not obvious. Nevertheless, these
measures would help China get on to a more sustainable and
welfare-enhancing growth path, which would be good both for China and
the world economy.
Conclusion
The apparently perverse flows of capital that we have been seeing
are not in themselves indicative of deficiencies in the international
financial system. This is not to suggest that all is well with the
international financial system or that it has reached a level of
maturity wherein a policy of benign neglect by policymakers and
international institutions would be appropriate. Indeed, rising
financial integration has the potential for taking existing weaknesses
and blowing up their effects on a larger scale.
But a constructive way of looking at global imbalances--rather than
just arguing about whether they will spell disaster or not--is that they
could serve as a useful device to focus the minds of policymakers on
underlying policy distortions and institutional weaknesses that
represent departures from the first best. In an ideal world, relatively
capital-poor economies would have better financial systems that would
allow them to absorb and effectively intermediate both domestic savings
and foreign capital, and thereby achieve higher growth rates both
through direct and indirect benefits accruing from financial
integration. And industrial countries would generate surpluses to
finance investments in developing economies, rather than running
deficits to finance consumption.
Rather than asking whether seemingly odd patterns of capital flows
may reflect irrational behavior, it may be more useful to ask what it is
that the patterns of international financial flows may be signaling to
us about more basic problems in different parts of the world economy. In
short, whether or not global imbalances are destined to end badly, they
are a sign of things gone awry.
References
Blanchard, O. (2007) "Current Account Deficits in Rich
Countries." IMF Staff Papers 54 (2): 191-219.
Gourinchas, P.-O., and Jeanne, O. (2006) "Capital Flows to
Developing Countries: The Allocation Puzzle." Manuscript,
International Monetary Fund.
Kose, M. A.; Prasad, E.; Rogoff, K.; and Wei, S.-J. (2006)
"Financial Globalization: A Reappraisal." IMF Working Paper
06/179.
Prasad, E.; Rajan, R.; and Subramanian, A. (2007) "Foreign
Capital and Economic Growth." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
(forthcoming).
(1) One implication of this discussion is that financial markets
are far from complete and having institutions such as the IMF catalyze the development of financial instruments that allow countries to better
share macroeconomic risk would be helpful. Regional pooling arrangements
may serve a useful purpose as well. But it is often the case that
countries in a region tend to be vulnerable to similar sorts of shocks,
and regional pooling would not provide much insurance against such
shocks that affect a majority of the countries in a region.
(2) Blanchard (2007) makes a similar point.
Eswar Prasad is the Tolani Senior Professor of Trade Policy at
Cornell University.