Global imbalances and financial reform with examples from China.
Rajan, Raghuram G.
I will focus on a familiar issue, the problem of global current
account imbalances, and will describe how financial sector reform can
help narrow them, using examples from China.
The United States is running a current account deficit approaching
6.25 percent of its GDP and over 1.5 percent of world GDP. To help
finance it, the United States pulls in 70 percent of all global capital
flows. Clearly, such a large deficit is unsustainable in the long run.
The current situation has its roots in a series of crises over the
last decade that were caused by excessive investment, such as the
Japanese asset bubble, the crises in emerging markets in Asia and Latin
America, and most recently, the IT bubble. Investment has fallen off
sharply since, with only very cautious recovery. This is particularly
true of emerging Asia and Japan. The policy response to the slowdown in
investment has differed across countries. In the industrial countries,
accommodative policies such as expansionary budgets and low interest
rates have led to consumption- or credit-fueled growth, particularly in
Anglo-Saxon countries. Government savings have fallen, especially in the
United States and Japan, and household savings have virtually
disappeared in some countries with housing booms.
By contrast, the crises were a wake-up call in a number of emerging
market countries. Historically lax policies have been tightened, with
some countries running primary fiscal surpluses for the first time, and
most bringing down inflation through tight monetary policy. With
corporations cautious, and governments abandoning the grandiose projects
of the past, investment has fallen off. Instead, exports have led
growth. Many emerging markets have run current account surpluses for the
first time. In emerging Asia, a corollary has been a buildup of
international reserves.
Two Kinds of Transition
The world now needs two kinds of transitions. First, consumption
has to give way smoothly to investment, as past excess capacity is
worked off and as expansionary policies in industrial countries return
to normal. Second, to reduce the current account imbalances that have
built up, demand has to shift from countries running deficits to
countries running surpluses.
There are reasons to worry whether the needed transitions will take
place smoothly. Perhaps the central concern has to be about consumption
growth in the United States, which has been holding up the world
economy. I will not dwell on the obvious risks to it, which include
energy prices, stretched housing prices, and inflation. My greatest
worry is not that U.S. consumption growth will slow--it has to because
it is being fueled by unsustainable forces. My worry is that it will
slow abruptly, taking away a major support from world growth before
other supports are in place.
One of those other supports is more investment, especially in
low-income countries, emerging markets, and oil producers.
Parenthetically, China is an exception in needing less, not more,
investment. The easy way to get more investment is a low-quality
investment binge led by the government or fueled by easy
credit--emerging market countries are only too aware of the pitfall of
that approach. The harder, and correct, way is through structural
reforms that would improve the business environment, increase labor
market flexibility, raise expected rates of return, and improve the
allocation and utilization of capital by the financial and corporate
sectors, all of which would promote more high-quality investment.
Somewhat paradoxically, though, the favorable global economic
environment and the resulting ability of many countries to rely on
exports for growth have allowed their governments to neglect the
structural reforms that would have strengthened investment and helped
sustain domestic demand. As a result, these countries are overly
dependent on demand from other countries.
In sum, then, one reason global imbalances have emerged is that
emerging markets have recognized the risks posed by volatile
cross-border flows, especially given the fragility of their own
financial and corporate systems. They have learned to fit their
investment coat within the domestic savings cloth they have available,
even leaving a bit over to finance rich countries.
While, as I have just argued, reforms are needed in emerging
markets to reverse this paradox of the poor financing the rich, we must
not neglect the need for reforms in developed countries. There is a
tendency to attribute the volatility of cross-border capital solely to
the inadequacies of policies and governance in emerging markets.
Developed countries, however, are not without blame. The tendency of
asset managers in these countries to bid up emerging market asset prices
overly and discount risk when industrial country interest rates are low,
only to withdraw en masse when industrial country rates rise, poses
immense problems to emerging markets. Surely, past experience with this
volatility accounts for some of the caution, and some of the reserve
buildup in emerging markets. There is a need to shine a spotlight on the
incentives of these asset managers and ask whether in fact they are
appropriate. If regulators in developed countries are reluctant to shine
this spotlight, it is in the interest of authorities in emerging markets
to press them: responsibility for international financial stability is
not one way.
The Case of China
Let me now turn to China. One quickly runs out of superlatives to
describe China's growth. Yet the macroeconomic picture looks
increasingly distorted. With investment at around 45 percent of GDP,
China is investing more than Japan or Korea relative to their GDPs even
in their boom years. The return on capital invested has been falling
steadily, so China has to invest yet more to keep up its growth.
Nevertheless, this investment has been more than financed by domestic
savings so that China runs a growing current account surplus.
One might think that behind these huge volumes of savings and
investment lies a strong financial sector. Yet I will argue that the
weakness of the financial sector might be a more appropriate
explanation. That progress in the Chinese financial sector has not
matched the rest of the economy is well known. While the ratio of credit
to GDP is one of the highest in the world, the state-dominated Chinese
banking system is weighed down by nonperforming loans. It lends
primarily to state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Corporate governance has
been weak, and because of constraints on listing, the stock market has
not been an effective source of capital for the private sector.
Households have few safe avenues for financial investment, which is why
the state-guaranteed banks still look attractive despite their poor
investment record.
China has grown rapidly nevertheless. In part, this is because the
role of the financial system in allocating capital to its highest-return
use has been relatively unimportant thus far. China has been catching
up. It does not require genius to understand that at its stage of
development, roads, bridges, ports, airports, and power plants have high
returns, and the banking system has focused on these, often urged on by
local authorities who are rewarded for generating growth. But as
infrastructure has been built up, further financing has to become more
capable of discrimination; do we build a chip plant here or a toothpaste
factory there? Also, further consumption growth will need steady support
from retail financing. And it is in these areas that the inadequacies of
the Chinese financial system are becoming more apparent.
In fact, China's macroeconomic imbalances are not unrelated to
problems with its financial system. Start first with the extraordinarily
high savings rate. Many see high savings as the natural reaction of
households emerging from communism with few assets to their name. Those
households face an uncertain safety net as state-owned companies shed
employees and are absolved of their duty to provide cradle-to-grave
support. In addition, they have only limited ability to rely on emerging
Asia's traditional source of social security, children, because of
the one-child policy. Yet the low return on savings deposited in the
banking system, and the high risk associated with anything invested
outside the banks must also play a part--increasing the amount
households have to save to attain retirement goals. With financial
investment options limited, it is little wonder there is a frenzy to
invest in real estate, one of the few seemingly "safe" assets
households can access.
Also, a substantial part of the savings, as well as recent savings
growth, is accounted for by corporations. Instead of paying out
dividends, corporations are reinvesting their cash flows. While some of
this investment may be warranted, some of it is indeed excessive. It is
unlikely the chairman of a state-owned corporation will prefer to return
cash to the state via dividends rather than retaining it in the firm,
particularly when banks are under orders to restrain credit growth. And
with financial investments returning so little, far better to reinvest
cash flows in real assets. Indeed, liquidity plays a greater role than
profits in determining real investments.
Similarly, the chairman of a private firm knows that financing from
either the stock market or the state-owned banks is very uncertain. So
he too will be unlikely to pay dividends, preferring instead to retain
the capital for investment. Again, instead of storing this as financial
assets and awaiting the right real investment opportunity, given the
poor returns on financial assets, he has an incentive to invest right
away.
These tendencies imply a lot of reinvestment in existing industries
especially if cash flow in the industry is high, which inexorably drives
down their profitability. And they imply relatively little investment in
new industries. The inadequacies of the financial system would thus
explain both the high correlation between savings and investment and the
oft-heard claim that over 75 percent of China's industries are
plagued by overcapacity. They also suggest why uniquely among
fast-growing Asian economies, China has not raised its share of
value-added coming from high-skilled industries, even as its per capita GDP has grown. Of course, if unprofitable investments are being financed
and output prices are being driven down to unremunerative levels, some
sectors like the extremely efficient Chinese export sector benefit. But
the burden will eventually be borne by Chinese households, either in
taxes to finance financial sector bailouts, or in miserable returns on
savings. Anticipation of these costs will further increase household
incentives to save.
Reforming China's Banking System
The Chinese authorities clearly understand that financial sector
reform is critical to future growth. The financial system has to be able
to recover capital from mature industries and redeploy it in sunrise
ones. While it will be important to revive the stock market by
overcoming the vested interests who oppose improved governance and fresh
listings, and while it will be important to improve governance so that
SOEs pay more dividends, the banking system is key to any reform. There
are, however, no easy options. Opening up the financial sector to
foreign bank entry according to the terms of China's WTO agreement
could be seen as a way to pressure the domestic banking sector to
reform. But it is extremely unlikely that foreign competition will work
miracles by itself.
There is really no escaping the need for rapid root and branch
reform of incentives in the banking system. The organizational
restructuring and the depoliticization being undertaken by banks, as
well as the infusion of foreign management expertise, will help. But
market forces also have to be made to play a greater role. And here the
need to make Chinese corporations and banks face a realistic cost of
capital is essential so that they use capital more carefully. The recent
liberalization of lending rates should eventually help banks make more
commercially oriented lending decisions. The flexibility to charge an
appropriate interest rate has, unfortunately, not been used, in part
because deposit rates are fixed at low levels by the government. Banks
continue to pass through those low rates to the firms lucky enough to be
able to borrow from them. A bank that attempts to charge a state-owned
firm a more appropriate rate typically sees that firm migrate to a
cheaper competitor. The effective cost of capital is too low, and it
will stay low until firms are forced to pay dividends and until deposit
interest rates rise.
Here is where other policy choices such as the exchange rate regime
enter into the picture. In order to maintain a fixed exchange rate in
the face of capital inflows and pressures for appreciation, the
government has had to keep interest rates low. This implies cheap
capital for banks and firms. And it also means that to control growth in
credit and investment the authorities have little choice but to use
administrative measures (including moral suasion) rather than
market-oriented measures. This is clearly not consistent with training
the banking system or state enterprises to be able to respond to market
incentives.
With investment growth at unsustainably high levels, an increase in
the cost of capital would serve a useful purpose. An increase in deposit
rates, for instance, would raise the cost of funds for banks and
eventually enable them to impose a higher cost of capital on firms, thus
reducing the profits of state enterprises and making it harder to
justify lending to the ones that are only marginally viable. Better loan
recovery processes would also help. Lending might then be reoriented
toward relatively more efficient private-sector enterprises, and allow
China to march faster up the quality ladder of growth. Better governance
of enterprises by banks could also facilitate the development of deeper
arm's-length financial markets, and afford households a wider
investment choice. Higher and safer returns could well reduce their
incentives to save, and spur greater consumption.
Of course, as with all reforms, changes have to be measured. For
example, too rapid an increase in deposit interest rates, without a
commensurate improvement in bank management and lending controls, could
decapitalize the banks and increase risk-taking. The point, however, is
that changes in the cost of capital should be seen as part of a menu of
changes, all of which need to be implemented at a concerted pace.
The Exchange Rate Controversy
Let me turn finally to an issue of some controversy. Some have
argued the International Monetary Fund has been remiss in not pushing
China to appreciate its exchange rate more, with some economists asking
for a large step appreciation of the order of about 25 percent. First, I
reject the premise of the accusation. The Fund has been discussing the
need for greater exchange rate flexibility with China for some
time--starting as early as 2000--long before others woke up to the
growing global imbalances. Nevertheless, more action is needed. With the
imbalances increasing, China's reserve buildup reaching enormous
proportions, and China's current account surplus starting to grow
significantly, it is in both the world's and China's interest
to allow the renminbi to appreciate more.
However--and this is my second point--a huge step appreciation will
probably do much more harm than good. For one, a number of the most
efficient Chinese enterprises will be driven out of business and others
forced into distress. In a developed economy, the necessary
restructuring could be speedily effected. In an economy like
China's, with an underdeveloped financial system, the restructuring
would be long drawn-out, painful, and could even damage the banking
system significantly. If there is one lesson we have learned in recent
years, it is that emerging markets do not handle large, rapid exchange
rate movements well. Moreover, it is far from clear that such a large
step appreciation would have much of an effect on the U.S. current
account deficit--quite possibly other countries in emerging Asia would
simply take up China's export share. Simply put, a measure that
could do serious damage to a country that accounts for 28 percent of
world growth, without much impact on imbalances, is not in anyone's
interest.
Instead, the Fund has been advocating a less interventionist
approach in which the authorities let the exchange rate react more
flexibly to market forces--the authorities already have a framework for
this, and they should use it. A more flexible exchange rate, especially
if accompanied by more flexibility elsewhere in emerging Asia, will
allow the underlying forces adjusting international demand more room to
play.
Conclusion
Financial sector reform is critical to continued growth in many
emerging markets. It will also help reduce global imbalances. In
particular, in China's case, greater exchange rate flexibility
might also help financial sector reform by making possible more
market-driven interest rates. More generally, China is not an exception
to the general proposition that financial development aids economic
development--it may indeed prove the rule.
Raghuram G. Rajan is Economic Counselor and Director of Research at
the International Monetary Fund. The views expressed in this article,
which is based on remarks delivered at the Cato Institute's 23rd
Annual Monetary Conference on November 3, 2005, are his own and do not
necessarily reflect those of the IMF, its management, or its staff. This
article also draws on the author's remarks before the Chinese
National Development and Research Council Conference on Reforms in July
2005.