Dealing with exchange rate protectionism.
Schwartz, Anna J.
In this article, I first review protectionist allegations against
China, particularly that its currency is undervalued and is being
manipulated so that the renminbi (RMB) will not appreciate. Next, I
discuss China's reasons for not changing its foreign exchange
policies for the time being. Finally, I assess the U.S. position on the
conditions it faces that have led it to pressure China to change those
policies forthwith. In a postscript I mention what China must do before
planning an exit from its present exchange rate regime.
The Complaint against China
Protectionism is expressed in two main forms: the traditional
attack on a foreign country's trading practices, and the more
recent attack on a foreign country's exchange rate policies. Both
are a response to a deficit in the balance of trade with a foreign
trading partner, but the first form of protectionism may be directed
against a deficit in the balance of trade of a particular industry
(e.g., steel or textiles).
The current prime target of protectionism is China. Previously
Japan was the target. Complaints about China's trade practices
allege that it is counterfeiting patented and copyrighted products,
granting illegal subsidies on exports of agricultural products, and
erecting non-tariff barriers against soybean imports. China in turn has
faced restrictions on its textile exports under the Multi-Fiber
Agreement. The Agreement expired at the end of 2004, and the prospect of
larger textile exports by China in 2005 is leading textile manufacturers
to demand "safeguard" provisions that importing countries
obtained as one of the conditions for admitting China to the WTO.
The case for protectionist opposition to China's exchange rate
policy is that it deliberately undervalues its currency to gain a
competitive advantage for its exports. It is this policy in the view of
the critics that contributes to the U.S. growing current account
deficit. If the exchange value of the RMB were to appreciate relative to
the dollar, Chinese goods would for a while become more expensive in the
United States and its trade surplus with the United States would be
reduced.
Since 1995 China has maintained its nominal exchange rate against
the dollar within a narrow band at 8.28 yuan. (1) (The yuan is the unit
of account. RMB translates as "the people's money.") Over
the past two years China's real exchange rate has depreciated while
a surplus in its balance of payments has strengthened. Its current
account surplus in 2003 with the United States was more than $120
billion, much larger than its overall surplus with the world of $46
billion. Over the past decade capital inflows have produced a surplus in
the capital account of about 4 percent relative to GDP, and a large
inflow in 2003 in anticipation of expected appreciation of the renminbi.
The current account surplus relative to GDP is something like 3 percent
of GDP. In addition, China uses the surplus to purchase dollar assets.
Its foreign exchange reserves, now more than $600 billion, have been
accumulating over the past decade, and at a particularly rapid pace
since 2003, suggesting that it is trying to hold down the real exchange
rate. This is the ground for the charge that it is manipulating its
exchange rate.
China's alleged currency manipulation has been the basis for
the introduction of bills in Congress to impose a surcharge on its
exports to the United States if it fails to end the practice. When U.S.
Treasury Secretary John Snow visited Beijing last fall, he recommended
that China immediately move to open its capital market and float its
currency. John Taylor, Under Secretary of the Treasury for International
Affairs, extended an invitation to China to attend a dinner meeting of
finance ministers of the G-7 countries scheduled at the start of October
2004, with the implication that it might be admitted to the group
provided that China ended its practice of pegging the yuan to the
dollar. Treasury Secretary Snow was expected to press China on its
currency at the dinner. It was anticipated that China would make some
concessions on its currency at the October 1 dinner meeting of its
central bank governor and finance minister with the G-7 country
representatives. Instead, the Chinese officials told their U.S.
counterparts that they intended to float or revalue the yuan without
committing themselves to a date when the change would begin. Secretary
Snow found the Chinese position unsatisfactory, but acknowledged that
progress was being made. Earlier Taylor also had expressed the
administration's satisfaction with the steps China had taken to
prepare for making its currency flexible.
This sentiment was not shared by an alliance of American
manufacturing companies and labor unions. They recently petitioned the
Bush administration to sue China at the WTO for keeping the value of its
currency fixed against the dollar. Although it is the IMF's
responsibility to resolve international currency disputes, the
petitioners asserted that they had turned to the WTO for a remedy
because the IMF was not doing its job. The administration denied the
petition. The response of the managing director of the IMF to the
critics was evasive, but he told the Chinese government that it should
immediately adopt a more flexible exchange rate. On the eve of its
annual meeting in 2004 the managing director of the IMF told journalists
that China's currency, as well as the currencies of the rest of
Asia, should be more flexible. The IMF World Economic Outlook (September
2004) also recommended greater exchange flexibility.
A group of Democratic Party senators and House members signed a
petition to the administration to sue China at the WTO for violating
trade laws by failing to revalue its currency.
In Defense of China
The authorities of the central bank, the People's Bank of
China, probably know all the arguments in favor of a flexible exchange
rate but, at this juncture, given the problems in their economy, they
are reluctant to make the move. To increase the dollar value of the RMB
would solve their inflation problem but worsen the problem of the zombie banking industry and the problem of finding employment for the rural
population.
Capital inflows have been so pronounced because the prospect of
supplying the enormous Chinese population has been irresistible to
worldwide exporters. Until some recent modifications, (2) Chinese firms
were precluded by capital controls from purchasing foreign assets. They
were required to convert the dollar proceeds of their exports into yuan.
If the People's Bank did not acquire the dollars, the exchange
value of yuan would appreciate. By purchasing dollars, however, unless
the purchase is offset, the central bank increases the monetary base,
which has been growing at a fast enough annual rate so that broad money
balances in 2003 were growing at close to 20 percent.
GDP growth has been in the 10 percent range, and investment as a
share of GDP is up to 47 percent (with savings at 44 percent). In this
situation China has adopted measures to counter overheating, such as
slowing credit growth, restraining investment in certain sectors such as
steel, cement, and real estate. Local authorities have sponsored many of
these investments, pressuring state-owned banks to lend money to provide
finance for projects that zoning and environmental regulators have not
approved. China began banning projects in overheated sectors in 2003 in
order to rein in growth. Although fixed-asset investment slowed in 2004,
GDP growth reached 9.5 percent, compared with 9.1 percent in 2003.
The central bank for its part is trying to restrain demand to curb
inflation, which was running as high as 5.3 percent in July and August
2004, as measured by the consumer price index. The CPI measure, however,
understates inflation because of price controls and other distortions.
Less regulated industrial prices rose 14 percent in the first half of
2004. To curb inflation, the central bank increased reserve requirements on deposits from 6 to 7 percent in 2003 and to 8 percent in 2004, relied
on moral suasion to restrict commercial bank loans, particularly real
estate loans, and recently increased the benchmark interest rate for the
first time since 1995. The central bank has also tried to restrain the
rate of monetary growth by selling interest-bearing central bank bills,
which are unattractive at a low market rate of interest. At the same
time the government's weekly auction of one-year Treasury bills in
September 2004 was heavily subscribed at a 3.46 interest rate, an
indication that the four troubled state-owned banks have large cash
holdings.
To cut back the growth rate of the monetary base and bank loans,
some way has to be found to lower the number of yuan per dollar. The
undervalued RMB increases exports, the proceeds of which the central
bank uses to accumulate foreign exchange reserves. The accumulation in
turn expands bank reserves, which enable the banks to lend freely. The
undervalued exchange rate is the source of the banking and loan excesses
that must be dealt with.
This conclusion has been challenged. The argument offered is that
credit expansion can be controlled without altering the RMB exchange
rate. All would be well if the central bank increased the scale of its
sterilization operations. The central bank's yield on its dollar
reserves, it is claimed, exceeds the interest cost it incurs when it
sells bills to offset the increase in bank reserves. Hence,
sterilization could continue indefinitely. The solution for excessive
credit creation would be at hand. The argument is unconvincing because
the profit calculation on sterilization is a conjecture. The
government's involvement in the banking system casts doubt on the
estimate. The need for banking reform and purging their portfolios of
nonperforming loans (NPLs) is too urgent to be sidetracked by a dubious
conjecture. The need to adjust the exchange rate to rein in credit
overexpansion cannot be gainsaid.
One suggestion is for China to float the RMB but retain controls on
the ability of its people to hold foreign assets. The reason to retain
such controls is that otherwise there would be a capital flight. To
prevent the outflow the rate of interest on deposits would need to be
raised. At the end of October 2004, the People's Bank of China
announced a modest increase of 0.27 percentage points in the rate on
deposits to 2.25 percent. A more substantial increase, however, would
have produced a crisis for the Chinese banking industry, which is
dominated by the four state-owned banks that intermediate between
depositors and state-owned enterprises at low interest rates. Their loan
portfolios are awash with NPLs. If loans to the state-owned enterprises,
which employ half of all industrial workers, were cut back, it would be
a calamity for the firms and the workers. The banks are already
insolvent but permitted to continue in operation because the authorities
do not know how to cope with the fallout. If higher interest rates
actually took effect, it would be a further calamity for the banks and
the authorities. The central bank also increased one-year lending rates
by 0.27 percentage points to 5.58 percent. (3)
There is another complication. China is confronted with the problem
of finding employment in the traded goods industries in urban areas for
workers shifting from farms in rural areas. Robert Mundell (2004)
maintains that if China appreciated its currency, the problem would
worsen. The cities would be swamped with unemployed migrants because the
export industries would be harmed by the currency appreciation. For the
sake of social stability, China cannot change its exchange rate policy.
This, of course, is a tacit admission that the RMB is undervalued.
By way of contrast, Morris Goldstein (2004) makes a strong case for
RMB revaluation. It would strengthen domestic demand instead of export
expansion as the source of economic growth, improve financial
intermediation, strengthen the domestic banking system, and spare China
a protectionist backlash against its exports. China's high saving
rate would provide domestic funds for high investment. Increased imports
into China would promote domestic efficiency, and spur competition and
higher productivity growth. The bottom line for Goldstein is that a
revalued RMB would be in the interest of China's sustainable
noninflationary economic growth.
The U.S. Position
Two immediate concerns account for the U.S. critique of
China's exchange rate. One is the size of its bilateral trade
deficit with this trading partner. The U.S. textile industry has borne
the brunt of Chinese competition. In general, however, Chinese exports
to the United States compete with exports from other developing
countries rather than with U.S. industries. The decline in demand for
U.S. manufactures is attributable less to Chinese competition than to
slow growth in other U.S. trading partners, and it is rapid U.S.
productivity increases that fundamentally have contracted manufacturing
employment. Thus, revaluation of the RMB by itself would not suffice to
achieve balanced trade with China.
Nevertheless, the decline in profitability of U.S. firms and the
loss of employment by its workers as a result of inexpensive Chinese
exports create a political problem for the administration, particularly
so in an election year. Disaffected firms and workers, one might expect,
would gain some political payoff by clamoring for protectionist redress.
That definitely happened in the case of the steel industry earlier in
this administration. It did not happen until after the election in
response to the plaintiffs in the present case against China.
The administration just days before the election agreed to consider
a petition from a coalition of textile manufacturers and the textile
workers union that would limit some imports from China. The petition
would challenge the lifting of all trade quotas on textiles and apparel
on January 1, 2005, enabling goods to move freely around the world.
The retail apparel industry, which endorses the lifting of the
quotas, charges that the manufacturers ignore the savings for consumers
in lower cost clothing and household goods like sheets and towels that
open access to Chinese factories will make possible.
The unions and manufacturers contend that China uses unfair trading
practices to keep costs low, like manipulating its currency and
subsidizing the industry. The Ministry of Commerce responded by filing a
protest on the possible imposition of quotas in the United States on
given categories of garment imports.
The National Council of Textile Organization seeks limitation of
Chinese imports to a 7 percent increase over 2004 imports. A U.S.
interagency task force (the Committee for the Implementation of Textile
Agreements) was appointed to consider the petition. (4)
The immediate political problem for the United States, however, is
how to respond to the plight of manufacturers in general and the textile
industry and its workers in particular that Chinese exports have
produced. Protectionist measures and government subsidies will not
prolong the life of an industry facing low-cost competitors. U.S.
moderate priced textiles may be doomed by developing country
proficiency. The U.S. industry would have to restructure itself as
specializing in the production of expensive high-fashion goods. Younger
displaced workers should be offered compensation and retraining under
the federal Trade Adjustment Assistance program for manufacturing.
Retraining is probably not a solution for older workers, but they should
be given financial aid for a transitional period. Regions in North and
South Carolina where textiles are concentrated will need to attract new
industries to replace the losers.
A further U.S. concern is the size of its current account deficit,
to which the bilateral trade deficit with China contributes. Some
observers believe the current account deficit is unsustainable, and for
many years have been predicting an imminent catastrophic disruption of
the American and then the world economy. Dissenters regard the current
account deficit as sustainable for the next decade at least.
Economists at the Washington, D.C., Institute of International
Economies have been prominent among those who find the current account
deficit unsustainable. The depreciation in the exchange value of the
dollar since 2002 is an indication to them that investors are beginning
to balk at adding more dollars to their portfolios. For investors to
retain dollar assets, higher yields would have to be offered them, which
would result in a reduction in economic activity. An uncontrolled fall
of the dollar exchange rate would ensue. At least one member of the
Institute, Catherine Mann, is reported to have revised her view. She now
regards the current account defter as likely to persist for many years.
Obstfeld and Rogoff (2004) do not concur. They contend that the U.S.
current account deficit, now more than 5 percent of GNP, is not likely
to be sustainable, and that a sharp depreciation of the dollar could be
a problem for the world economy.
Protectionism has not served to narrow the current account deficit.
The United States on its own could do so by conducting inflationary
monetary policy. That would induce foreigners to shun dollar assets in
their portfolios. This is hardly likely. Otherwise, so long as
foreigners choose to export their goods and services to the United
States and accept payment in dollar assets, the current account can
continue at its present or a higher level, The scenario that predicts
withdrawal of European exporters from the U.S. market and their shift
from dollar to euro assets envisages Asian exporters as inheriting the
European share of exports to the United States and acquiring the
European share of dollar assets. The U.S. current account defter would
remain undisturbed despite the displacement of European by Asian
investors.
What is unclear at this date is whether Asian central banks have
decided to reduce their dollar buying. Dollar weakness as far as it has
occurred is helpful in correcting the trade deficit. Even if the Asian
central banks no longer buy enough Treasury bills or notes to fully
cover the U.S. current account deficit, and the dollar continues to
weaken at a moderate pace, the path of adjustment for the United States
and the world will be positive.
An Exit Strategy for China
China's problem is complex. On one level, it involves freeing
the economy from the control of the communist party. Reform of many
institutions must precede changing the exchange rate regime. In
particular, China must decide how to reform its financial industry,
including privatizing state-owned banks, eliminating NPLs,
recapitalizing them, and permitting market allocation of loans free of
government dictate; how to privatize state-owned enterprises; how to
guarantee independence to the central bank in the conduct of monetary
policy; and how to reform fiscal policy. Then China can plan an exit
strategy from a fixed exchange rate to a floating rate and ending
capital controls. It is up to China to undertake this awesome program of
transforming itself. Neither the IMF nor the United States should act as
China's overseers.
(1) Lardy (2005) gives an account starting in 1978 of the changes
in the peg of the yuan to the dollar before mid-1995.
(2) The modifications in mid-October 2004 allow Chinese companies
to invest overseas, thus encouraging outward flows of capital. The
Ministry of Commerce ruled that it would accept applications to invest
overseas and issue approvals without reviewing the feasibility of each
project. Local insurers can also invest some hard currency holdings
abroad. So far state-owned oil companies and mining companies have been
ones that were allowed to invest abroad. The new regulation would extend
approval to smaller firms to make such investments. Overseas direct
investment abroad by Chinese firms, however, is miniscule compared with
foreign direct investment in China. In addition, the new regulations
allow Chinese tourists to take more hard currency when traveling.
Chinese exporters are also permitted to retain more of their foreign
exchange earnings. The State Administration of Foreign Exchange, which
is in charge of cross-border capital controls, must grant approval along
with the Ministry of Commerce, for offshore money transfers.
China's National Development and Reform Commission announced new
guidelines for soft-loan-funding overseas projects of some domestic
firms, another move to encourage outward flows of capital.
(3) Raising the upper band on bank lending rates to allow banks to
charge about 14 percent for funds was another measure the central bank
introduced. It was regarded by observers as ineffective in curbing
lending because the banks are loaded with cash. Therefore, they will
lend at the band's lower limit. Nevertheless, John Taylor of the
U.S. Treasury spoke approvingly of the rate increase as a step to
control inflationary pressures in China, to improve the sustainability
of the ongoing economic expansion there, and to help move China toward a
flexible exchange rate.
(4) It accepted a similar petition earlier for quotas on
China's exports of cotton trousers. Six U.S. apparel, textile, and
fiber-producing trade associations and a union expect to file petitions
on 13 categories of imports.
References
Anderson, J. (2004) "The Asian Liquidity Primer." UBS Investment Research. Hong Kong (March).
Becker, E. (2004a) "Industry and Labor Step Up Fight over
China's Currency." New York Times (9 September): Business Day.
--(2004b) "Record Deficit for a Crucial Trade Figure."
New York Times (15 September): Business Day.
--(2004c) "I.M.F. Chief Sees Potential Hazard in U.S. Fiscal
Policies." New York Times (21 September): Business Day.
--(2004d) "Guess Who's Invited to Dinner: Group of 7
Nations to Meet with China." New York Times (22 September):
Business Day.
--(2004e) "Bush Agrees to Consider Textile Limits." New
York Times (30 October): C1, 3.
--(2004f) "U.S. Weights Putting Limits on Textiles from
China." New York Times (13 October): C1.
--(2004g) "China Promises Currency Shift but Gives No
Date." New York Times (2 October): C1.
Bradsher, K. (2004) "China Poised for Decision on Raising
Interest Rates." New York Times (9 September): Business Day.
Brown, O., and Browne, A. (2004) "China Open's Door for
Its Companies to Invest Overseas." Wall Street Journal (13
October): A2.
Buckman, R. (2004) "Navigating China's Textile
Trade." Wall Street Journal (10 September).
Chen, K., and Pottinger, M. (2004) "China Doesn't Plan to
Remove Economic Brakes." Wall Street Journal (17 September).
Dooley, M. P.; Folkerts-Landau, D.; and Gerber, P. M. (2004)
"The U.S. Current Account Deficit and Economic Development:
Collateral for a Total Return Swap." NBER Working Paper No. 10727
(August).
Dorn, J. A. (2003) "Capital Freedom for China." Asian
Wall Street Journal (9 September).
Goldstein, M. (2004) "Adjusting China's Exchange Rate
Policies." Washington: Institute for International Economics (May).
Ikenson, D. (2004) "This Byrd Won't Fly." Wall
Street Journal (13 September).
Lardy, N. R. (2005) "Exchange Rate and Monetary Policy in
China." Cato Journal 25 (1): 41-47.
Makin, J. H. (2004) "For a Few Dollars More." Wall Street
Journal (15 November): A22.
McCallum, B. T. (2004) "China's Exchange Rate and
Monetary Policy." Carnegie Mellon University (May).
Miller, S., and Hutzler, C. (2004) "Poor Nations Seek WTO
Textile Aid." Wall Street Journal (1 October).
Mundell, R. (2004) "China's Exchange Rate: The Case for
the Status Quo." Columbia University. Processed.
Norris, F. (2004) "Campaign Tactic: Blaine Foreigners and
Ignore the Trade Deficit." New York Times (20 August): Business
Day.
Obstfeld, M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2004) "Current Account
Adjustment and Overshooting." NBER pre-conference on G-7 Current
Account Imbalances (July). Processed.
Schroeder, M., and King Jr., N. (2004) "Groups Pressure White
House over China Trade." Wall Street Journal (9 September).
Wall Street Journal (2004a) "Quota Move on Garments Riles
China." 5 November.
--(2004b) "Beijing Eases Loans for Investing Overseas." 2
November.
--(2004c) "China Is Urged to Keep Reins on Hot Economy."
9 September.
--(2004d) "China Posts Its First Agricultural Trade
Deficit." 23 August.
Anna J. Schwartz is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.