A Monetary History as a model for historians.
Meltzer, Allan H.
In 1963, the American Bankers Association invited the late James
Tobin and me to review A Monetary History of the United States at a
conference held at Princeton. At the time, I wrote and subsequently
published a review article that began this way:
This volume is a delight to the economist. The book is clearly
destined to be a classic, perhaps one of the few emerging in that
role rather than growing into it. The reader cannot fail to be
impressed by the size of the task to which the authors committed
themselves, by the authors' ability to treat the broad sweep of a
century of monetary history without being overcome by the mass of
detail that they carefully examine, by the originality of the
scholarship that is everywhere displayed, and by a host of other
considerations, most of which are conveyed by the word "classic"
[Meltzer 1965: 404].
Some of those words have greater resonance now that I am well along
in the second volume of A History of the Federal Reserve. I do not know
whether Anna Schwartz and Milton Friedman anticipated the size of the
task and the amount of detail. I certainly did not. I have available
most of the correspondence, minutes, and internal records that they were
not permitted to access. That made their task very different from mine.
To write their history, they had to find substitutes for the internal
records.
One of the curious facts about their work is that the Federal
Reserve discussed releasing internal documents during much of the period
when they were working, but it would not release old minutes to Anna and
Milton with a lag to protect confidentiality of current or recent
discussions.
There was a strong precedent for releasing materials. Seymour
Harris wrote a Federal Reserve history about 1930 using internal
records. A Committee on the History of the Federal Reserve System worked
in the 1950s. Allan Sproul, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, was an active participant in the Committee's work. Aside from
some unpublished interviews stored at the Brookings Institution, the
only completed work was Lester Chandler's biography of Benjamin
Strong Jr., the first governor of the New York Fed and the dominant
personality in the early years.
Chandler had access to all of Strong's papers, including
minutes of the committee that, under different names, made decisions
about open market operations. Strong's papers were stored at
Columbia University as well as at the New York Fed. Anna and Milton
therefore had access to the papers but not to the minutes of weekly
board meetings at the New York bank.
The directors had a more powerful role in the 1920s. Their
discussions determined whether a Reserve bank would participate in open
market operations. The Reserve banks were still semi-autonomous, and
directors could--and at critical times did--refuse to take a pro rata
share of purchases. On issues such as the failure of the Bank of the
United States or the Federal Reserve System's actions and inactions
in the winter of 1933, the New York directors meetings help us to
understand the considerations that led to the decisions taken.
I stray from my task. I want to discuss Anna's profound
influence on me. Her work is a model for historians and would-be
historians. Any historian has to decide what is relevant detail and what
might be called interesting facts that have no apparent relevance for
events. Does it matter that William McChesney Martin Jr. did not like
economics and did not find it useful for policymaking? Does it matter
that Marriner Eccles was a frequent White House adviser during his term
as chairman of the Board of Governors? Does it matter that he was able
to serve as the chairman of various Eccles' enterprises while
serving as a Governor of the Federal Reserve? Questions of this kind
arise regularly. Historians must decide from the mass of detail what is
worth reporting and relating to events and what is not. Anna's work
is a model.
How much importance should be given to personalities? Martin was
collegial. He rarely forced his views on the Board or the Open Market
Committee. Often, he would wait for events to persuade other members
even if he believed that action was called for at the time.
Arthur Burns was very different. He had what I call the arrogance
of the distinguished academic. He thought he knew what was right and
wrong. He did not have Martin's patience with those who differed
with him, unless they could make a persuasive argument to show that he
was wrong. That was not an easy task, because he believed he knew more
than others about business cycles and much else.
Anna's work has been a model for me in deciding what to
explore and what to avoid, what to include and what to omit. Her work,
like that of any great historian, is more than a collection of
interesting facts. The facts are part of an analysis. There must be a
hypothesis, explicit or perhaps implicit, by which the historian decides
questions of this kind. Reading Anna's work, in A Monetary History
and elsewhere, helped me to think about and decide issues of this kind.
Anna has been, and continues to be, an excellent critic of my
chapters. To say that she reads the material carefully is an
understatement. Her criticisms go to detail, organization, and
omissions. But they do not miss the larger issues.
Anna and I see our work on monetary history as complementary. More
than any other friend or colleague, Anna has encouraged me to write the
history. I am proud to say that we are good enough friends that she felt
able to tell me that she thought I was wasting my time when I agreed to
chair the so-called Meltzer Commission on international financial
institutions. She thought my primary task, and more lasting
contribution, was to complete A History of the Federal Reserve.
Having undertaken a task that has continued for nine years, with no
end in sight, I am grateful for a friend that reminds me that the work
is valuable and valued. I tried to express some of my debt in the
preface to volume 1. After thanking the many people who commented on the
manuscript, I said, "I owe a special debt to Anna Schwartz, who
encouraged and prodded me. Anna commented fully and helpfully on each
chapter from her vast store of knowledge" (Meltzer 2003: xiii).
I then went on to discuss briefly the importance to me of the
Friedman and Schwartz book. "'Several readers have asked why I
included the years covered in Friedman and Schwartz's now classic
monetary history. In one respect this is a strange question: in the
physical sciences, replication of experiments is the norm. No one
appreciates their work more than I, but its quality and importance
should encourage, not deter, replication." I should add that
replication is not limited to the physical sciences. There must be an
infinity of histories of the American Civil War, the Kennedy
assassination, and many other topics.
Anna has never held a permanent appointment as professor but she
has been an inspiring teacher for a generation of historians. I am but
one of them, happy to join in the acclaim on this anniversary as on
other occasions.
References
Meltzer, A. H. (1965) "Monetary Theory and Monetary
History." Schweizerische Zeitschfrit fur Volkswirtschaft und
Statistik 101: 404-22.
--(2003) A History of the Federal Reserve. Vol. 1: 1913-1951.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Allan H. Meltzer is Chairman of the Gailliot Center for Public
Policy at Carnegie Mellon University and a Visiting Scholar at the
American Enterprise Institute.