Global order and the future of the euro.
Schwartz, Anna J.
The performance of the euro can be assessed in relation to recent
developments in the global economy as well as in relation to the vision
of the architects of the European Monetary Union. I shall consider both
perspectives and ask whether the EMU has lived up to the vision of its
architects to create a new currency to serve as a bulwark for
maintaining price stability over the medium term.
The Euro in the Global Economy
In a study for the National Bureau of Economic Research, Michael
Dooley, David Folkerts-Landau, and Peter Garber (2003) describe recent
developments in the global economy as attributable to the behavior
patterns of countries in three geographical areas. The United States is
one of the geographical areas. It is the center country of the global
economy, and the system's financial intermediary. It does not
manage its exchange rate and does not accumulate foreign reserves. It is
both a trade account country and a capital account country. It seeks
growth through its trade account and finance for its growth. It seeks
investment through its capital account and foreign savings to finance
domestic capital formation. The United States does not worry about its
deteriorating international investment position.
A second geographical area is Asia, comprising China, Taiwan,
Japan, Hong Kong, Singapore, Korea, and Malaysia. Asia is a trade
account region. Exporting to America is Asia's main concern.
Exports mean growth. Their growth-oriented trade surpluses are a source
of finance for the United States, channeled through their central banks as official providers of capital to the United States. The Asian
countries manage their dollar exchange rates, and their central banks
consistently intervene to limit appreciation of their currencies.
Exchange controls and administrative pricing are often resorted to. Some
currencies are explicitly fixed, like the Chinese yuan, the Hong Kong
dollar, and the Malaysian ringit. The Japanese yen and Korean won float
but Japan and Korea accumulate vast official reserves in U.S. dollars.
The Asian country currencies float against the currencies of the third
geographical area.
The third geographical area comprises Europe, Canada, Australia,
and Latin America. This is a capital account region. Private investors
in the capital account region care about the risk/return of their
international investment position, and have recently become worried
about their U.S. exposure. Countries in the capital account region have
floating exchange rates. Their governments do not intervene, and their
official reserves have not increased.
The trade-weighted exchange rate of the German mark and then the
euro and other currencies of the capital account region depreciated
substantially relative to the dollar from 1992 through 2002. The real
exchange rate depreciation was consistent with private investors of the
region helping to finance the U.S. current account deficit.
Over the last five years, however, the U.S. current account deficit
has been financed by official inflows from the trade account region as
well as private inflows from the capital account region. The surge in
the U.S. current account deficit has been the engine for growth in the
rest of the world.
Until early 2003, the tripartite global economy was stable and
sustainable in view of the trade account region's preference for
official investments in the United States and the capital account
region's preference for private financial investments in the United
States. Lately, however, the countries in the capital account region
have become concerned about the rise in U.S. international debts. The
depreciation of the euro and other capital account region currencies was
reversed in 2003. Normally, the solution would be for U.S. yields to
rise and the dollar to depreciate sharply. The dollar has depreciated,
but may not persist, and U.S. yields may not rise.
Instead, Asia may displace Europe in sending exports to the United
States and may be ready to accept even larger inflows of U.S.
securities. If that happens, U.S. yields would not have to rise.
The nub of this view of the global economy is that, if European
investors decide to limit further purchases of U.S. assets unless U.S.
yields rise, the euro will appreciate dramatically. European domestic
savings will remain at home and yields there will fall. Asia's
exports to the United States will displace Europe's, and growth in
Europe will slacken. U.S. yields will not rise even as its current
account deficit rises.
According to this view of the global economy, emerging market
economies must choose between two models. One is the Asian model of
exports as the engine of growth and fixed undervalued currencies. The
other model is the European one of capital mobility and an appreciating
euro.
The euro and the yen have recently strengthened against the dollar
as the result of the reordering of the composition of some portfolios.
Dollar weakness, however, may not last if the U.S. growth rate
accelerates in coming quarters outstripping the growth rate of European
countries.
The Euro in its Own Orbit
Having discussed the relation of the euro to one view of what has
been happening in the global economy, I now turn to the performance of
the euro in relation to the vision of the architects of the EMU.
There can be no doubt that the architects intended the strict
fiscal conditions the Maastricht Treaty imposed before the activation of
the euro and the Stability and Growth Pact thereafter as well as the
narrow mandate of the European Central Bank to hedge the euro against
lax monetary policy and profligate fiscal behavior by the governments of
member states.
Yet despite the architects' efforts to erect barriers to loose
monetary and fiscal policy in the EMU, risks are rising that the
barriers will be circumvented with predictable baleful consequences for
the euro (see Schwartz 2004). There are clear indications of a
disposition among leading members of the EMU to inflate their way out of
circumstances that require unpopular political decisions. Attempts by
national governments to assert their wish for the ECB to modify its
position on curbing inflation have thus far been resisted by the ECB.
The long-run problem for the ECB is that monetary union was something
the political elite of France and Germany sought. It was not a change
that voters demanded. If farmers and organized labor come to believe
monetary union delivers tight monetary and fiscal performance that hurts
their interests, will they oppose policies that erode the purchasing
power of the euro?
I consider first a threatened breach of the ECB's monetary
policy guidelines. I then explore the implications of a likely
modification of the Stability and Growth Pact in response to widespread
belief that it is flawed. Next, I comment on budget deficits that loom
for governments to meet unfunded commitments for social welfare. Leaders
are aware of the need for reform of policies that authorize future
unsustainable outlays for state pensions and other entitlements, but it
is uncertain that reform will eventuate. Finally, I discuss whether new
entrants to the European Union will be able to sustain fiscal
discipline.
The Dispute about Monetary Policy Guidelines
The main complaint by critics of the ECB is that its focus on price
stability has been at the expense of output stability. It has been
charged with ignoring the need to lower interest rates when the euro
area has experienced recession. As a result of its inattention to the
output gap, monetary policy by the ECB has allegedly been
contractionary. To satisfy the critics, the ECB would have to be more
accommodative.
Other complaints center on the ECB's reliance in part on the
money growth indicator in forecasting inflation. The money aggregate M3
has been assigned a reference value of 4.5 percent for annual growth,
but the ECB does not automatically respond to deviations in money growth
over the short term. According to the critics, since the ECB ignores the
indicator, it might as well abandon it. To satisfy the critics, only the
procedure of formulating monetary policy, not necessarily the outcome,
would change.
The ECB has been charged with other failings, but the most serious
is the one whose aim is to weaken its commitment to noninflationary
monetary policy. As stalwart as it may be in defending its commitment,
its performance in a democracy is ultimately determined by the
preferences of voters. Are residents of the countries in the euro area
resolute supporters of price stability? It is commonly believed that the
reason the German public prizes price stability is the imprint of the
historical memory of the destructive experience of two postwar
hyperinflations. But what if their political leaders argue that other
goals are more important? And is the public of other member countries as
keen for stable prices as the German public is reputed to be?
Another uncertainty is the difference in the conduct of the ECB
that the replacement on November 1, 2003, of Wim Duesenberg by
Jean-Claude Trichet may occasion. Monetary policy under a new president
may change. Whether the departure is in the direction of greater ease
remains to be seen.
The one development that might reduce the immediate ongoing
pressure on the ECB to be more accommodating is a robust economic
recovery in Western Europe sooner rather than later. The forecast,
however, is for a modest recovery.
The Assault on the Stability and Growth Pact
The Pact was adopted to prevent profligate government spending that
would undermine the euro. Yet France and Germany have flouted the
Pact's deficit rule in 2002 and 2003. The French budget minister,
moreover, has announced that the deficit is likely to breach the cap
until 2006. The French premier in August defended the country's
violation of the budget deficit criterion. He stated that paring the
deficit was not his priority. It was rather to restore growth and
employment to the economy.
Smaller countries with balanced budgets are demanding fines for the
violators. The Netherlands threatened to sue the European Commission to
enforce the rules the big countries wrote but now contravene. No fines
have as yet been levied. Duesenberg has advocated fines as much as 0.5
percent of GDP for countries that breach EU deficit limits. The fine
that Duesenberg suggests is punitive. Would violators agree to pay such
amounts? Germany and France have been lobbying the Commission to invoke
a clause of the Maastricht Treaty that overrides the deficit rule
because of "special" circumstances and thus absolve them from
the obligation to pay a fine.
In October 2003, the European Commission chided France for taking
no effective action to reduce its budget deficit. On October 21, it
allowed France an extra year to comply with budget rules, but ordered it
to reduce planned spending by 0.4 percent of GDP in 2004, particularly a
cut in its generous health system. European finance ministers, however,
on November 25, rejected the Commission's recommendations. The
decision essentially suspended the Stability and Growth Pact.
A statement by the ECB, which met after the decision, condemned it
as a risk to the credibility of the institutional framework and
confidence in sound public finance. Ironically, in the aftermath, the
euro exchange value appreciated.
The decision marks a divide between small countries and the big
ones. In 2001, Portugal was forced to accept big spending cuts when its
budget ran over the 3 percent ceiling. The resistance to such budget
cutting by France and Germany aroused criticism by the Netherlands,
Austria, Finland, and Spain, which opposed the special treatment of the
two malefactors. Mr. Trichet told a committee of the European Parliament
that there was no need to reform the Pact, as the big countries propose.
Italy responded by urging a change in the ECB's statutes that would
alter the bank's independence. At the end of 2003, monetary
disunion, rather than union, was the situation.
The suspension of the Pact leaves unresolved the extent to which
increased government spending, the objective of not only the big
countries, will be tolerated. Portugal earlier was authorized to use
state-owned companies' pension funds to cut its budget deficit.
France and Germany could use the same means to finance spending.
Leniency in the case of France comes as French finances continue to
deteriorate. France has breached not only the budget rule but is close
to exceeding the 60 percent of GDP public debt ceiling. It has been
negotiating with the European Commission to find some way to permit it
to proceed in rescues of four state companies on the verge of
bankruptcy.
France and Germany can proceed with tax cuts and spending increases
on infrastructure that they have proposed to continue through 2010. They
can ignore the ECB's advice to rely on private resources to finance
the spending plan.
A fudge would permit treatment of new spending as off-balance
sheet, thus not adding to budget deficits. Would residents of the euro
area accept subterfuges as certifying the euro's soundness?
Will Member State Benefit Programs Be Reformed?
The outlook for the euro is clouded by the immense financial
burdens governments will bear during the coming half century if they
honor their future unfunded commitments to pay generous pensions and
health care expenses for aging populations. The pay-as-you-go pension
system is hostage to the ratio of working population to the retired
population. The demographics in the euro area project a declining
proportion of working age people and a rising proportion of older
people. This imbalance means that the contributions of workers will not
suffice to pay benefits to increasing numbers of the retired. Unless the
program is reformed either by reducing promised benefits or raising
taxes, or public revenues are increased, deficits for governments will
loom. Health care costs will also rise as the population ages, further
impacting public finances.
Will EMU countries choose timely reforms or abandon monetary
discipline by increasing the euro money supply to finance the requisite
expenditures? What is in question is whether the commitment to fiscal
and monetary discipline that was made when the euro was launched in 1999
is still credible. What is at stake is the market's confidence in
the euro's suitability to serve as a store of value.
How Will Enlargement of EU Membership Affect the Euro?
In May 2004, the Czech Republic, Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia,
Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia joined the European
Union. To join the EMU and adopt the euro the countries would also need
to become members of the Exchange Rate Mechanism for two years.
Except for Poland, the new entrants have small populations. All of
them have large farm sectors. Their government operations are
inefficient, and corruption is a problem. They will be beneficiaries of
EU economic-development subsidies.
The Maastricht criteria do not include a measure of real rather
than nominal convergence. In 2002, GDP per capita in the current EU
averaged 24,094 euros; only 5,750 euros for residents of the accession
countries. The divergence of average per capita GDP in the accession
countries from the average in the euro area is substantial. Convergence
will not be quickly achieved. In addition, structural reforms, including
the rehabilitation of the banking and financial systems, are urgently
needed. There has been a loss of fiscal control in four of the largest
countries (Poland, Hungary, Czech Republic, and Slovakia), but political
opposition to cuts in public spending or tax increases is strong. Each
of the four accession countries has continued to spend freely on
highways, bridges, and other public works. Budget deficits far in excess
of the Pact's 3 percent of GDP ceiling are reported.
The EMU in its present configuration is not a union of equals. This
condition will only worsen with the inclusion of new members. Is this a
recipe for political disintegration? Would the euro survive political
disintegration?
Conclusion
I have presented two perspectives on the euro. The first treats the
euro in relation to a map of the world economy that recognizes three
geographical areas. One area is that of the United States, the center
country. The two other areas are a group of Asian countries and a group
of countries that Europe dominates. The goal of the Asian countries is
growth through exports, mainly to the United States, achieved by
undervaluing their currencies, and a preference for offsetting their
trade surpluses by official investment in the United States. The area
dominated by Europe until 2003 also sought growth through exports, and
its private investors used their savings to acquire dollar-denominated
assets to offset trade surpluses. In 2003, however, European investors
soured on U.S. assets and substituted euros for dollars in the
composition of their portfolios. That explains the strengthening of
euros and currencies of other countries in the third geographical area.
A projection based on this perspective is that the outcome sought
by Asian countries will persist. The scenario calls for Asian exports to
replace European exports to the United States and for the euro to
appreciate, European savings to stay at home so the yields on them will
decline, and European economic growth to weaken.
Although this perspective is an interesting insight into recent
developments in the global economy, one may eschew the forecast.
The second part of my presentation asks whether the EMU has lived
up to the vision of its architects to create a new currency that would
maintain price stability over the medium term. I find grounds for
immediate and long-range concerns with respect to the prospects for the
stability of the euro's purchasing power. The immediate concerns
arise from the pressures on the ECB to be more accommodative and the
drive to weaken the Stability and Growth Pact that culminated recently
in its suspension. The long-range concerns arise from the spending
obligations the member governments have assumed to provide pensions and
health care to their aging populations for the next half century, and
from the enlargement of the EU to include 10 states that are less
economically and institutionally advanced than the other member states.
The outlook is for greater spending by governments than their projected
resources unless forces not now visible will strengthen the resolve of
political leaders to serve the cause of a sound euro.
References
Dooley, M. P.; Folkerts-Landau, D.; and Garber, P. (2003) "An
Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods System." NBER Working Paper
9971.
Schwartz, A. J. (2004) "Risks to the Long-Term Stability of
the Euro." Atlantic Economic Journal 32 (1): 1-10.
Anna J. Schwartz is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.