Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth.
Gwartney, James D. ; Holcombe, Randall G. ; Lawson, Robert A. 等
In the past few decades, the issues in the literature on economic
growth have broadened from the development of general theories of
growth, largely based on Solow (1956), toward an examination of why
there are differences in growth rates across countries, and why some
countries continue to grow while others stagnate at low levels of
income. This study takes an institutional approach and uses a recently
developed measure of institutional quality, the Economic Freedom of the
World (EFW) index (Gwartney and Lawson 2003) to examine the issue of
cross-country differences in income levels and growth rates. The
emphasis on the importance of institutions to economic prosperity goes
back at least to Adam Smith (1776), and has been found in the more
recent work of Olson (1982), Scully (1988), North (1990), Barro (1996),
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), Landes (1998), Hall and Jones (1999),
and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001). Despite this interest in
institutions, much work on economic growth treats institutions
peripherally if at all.
One challenge to the institutional approach is to find a way to
quantify the quality of institutions. The EFW index used here is a
measure of institutional quality and, to the extent that higher EFW
ratings lead to more rapid growth and higher income levels, it provides
insight into the characteristics of an environment conducive to
prosperity. The results show that better institutions lead to higher
income, and that institutional improvements result in higher rates of
economic growth.
Three Explanations of Cross-Country Differences in Economic
Performance
Over the past decade, the economics literature has offered three
different types of explanations for the differences in income levels and
growth rates across countries. The most well-established explanation in
the literature takes a production function approach based on the work of
Solow (1956). The second approach explains differences in income and
growth across countries as a function of institutions, and is
represented by the work of North (1990) and Landes (1998). A third type
of explanation, promoted by Sachs (2003), points to the effects of
geography and location as determinants of growth and income.
The production function approach views output (Q) as a function of
capital (K) and labor (L), such that Q = f(K,L). Within this framework,
output is increased by increasing the amount of inputs (K and L), and by
technological improvements that alter the production function so that
more output can be produced with the same amount of inputs. This
approach focuses on increasing human and physical capital, and on
technological progress through, for example, research and development.
This explanation suggests that higher growth rates can be generated by
increasing inputs into the production function, and by discovering ways
to employ those inputs more productively.
The institutional approach to growth is based on the idea that both
the availability and productivity of resources will be influenced by the
institutional and policy environment. While there is some debate about
the exact characteristics of the institutions that are most appropriate
for economic growth and prosperity, there is considerable agreement that
secure property rights are crucial, and that the impediments to exchange
must be minimal. Institutions and policies are reflective of government
actions. To promote economic growth, governments must not only follow
actions that are supportive of secure property rights and freedom of
exchange, they must "also make a convincing and credible commitment
that the policies will be maintained in the future. Public policy must
be designed to implement what Mancur Olson (2000) has referred to as
"market-augmenting government." (1)
A third approach to identifying factors that lead to prosperity
looks at geographical factors. During the last several years, Jeffrey
Sachs has promoted the idea that geography and location are major
determinants of cross-country differences in income levels and growth.
Sachs has stressed the importance of three major geographic-locational
factors: a tropical climate, access to an ocean port, and distance of
country from the world's major trading centers (Rotterdam, New
York, and Tokyo). According to this view, a tropical climate inhibits
economic growth because of the increased threat posed by diseases such
as malaria, and because of the negative impact of a hot and humid climate on the energy level and productivity of labor. The lack of
access to an ocean port will mean higher transactions costs and less
trade with a sizable portion of the world's population. A distant
location from the major markets of the world will also retard trade. In
turn, less trade will reduce the gains from division of labor,
specialization, and economies of scale. Furthermore, each of these
geographic-locational factors will reduce the attractiveness of a
country as a base for production, and thereby retard its ability to
attract investment.
These three alternative theories of cross-country differences in
income levels and growth are not necessarily inconsistent with each
other, and may even be mutually reinforcing. For example, if the
institutional and geographic-locational factors influence capital
formation and the productivity of capital and other inputs, this has
implications for the production function approach to growth. However,
the policy implications of the three models have substantial
differences. The production function approach naturally focuses on
policies that will increase the quantity and improve the productivity of
capital and labor. The institutional approach focuses on economic,
legal, and political institutions, reasoning that if appropriate
institutions are in place, the market system provides an incentive for
market participants to invest in human and physical capital, and to
improve their methods of production through innovation. The
geographic-locational approach suggests that greater attention should be
paid to the control of tropical diseases and an analysis of how
technology can be applied to affect the productivity of resources in
tropical regions.
Measurement of Cross-Country Differences in Institutional Quality
Institutional quality will be measured using the Economic Freedom
of the World index published in Gwartney and Lawson (2003). (2) The EFW
index has been used in a number of previous studies, and a review of
both the index and other studies in which it has been used is found in
Berggren (2003). The EFW index measures institutional quality in five
major areas: (1) size of government, (2) legal structure and security of
property rights, (3) access to sound money, (4) exchange with
foreigners, and (5) regulation of capital, labor, and business. The
index provides current ratings for 123 countries, but data are available
for only about 100 countries continuously (at five-year intervals)
throughout 1980-2000. These countries make up the data set for the
empirical analysis that follows.
The EFW index reflects the key elements of the new institutional
economics. For many years, Douglass C. North (1990), Friedrich Hayek (1945, 1960), Peter Bauer (1957, 1972), Hernando de Soto (1989), Gerald Scully (1988, 1992), and Scully and Slottje 1991) have stressed the
importance of institutions and related policy variables. Following this
same path, the new growth theory argues that sound institutions and
policies are the keys to economic progress (e.g., see Torstensson 1994;
Knack and Keefer 1995; Barro 1995, 1996; Olson 2000; Knack 2003; and
Azfar and Cadwell 2003). The EFW index is also closely related to what
Hall and Jones (1999) call "social infrastructure." Using the
language of Hall and Jones, a quality infrastructure is present when the
institutions and government policies of a country encourage productive
behavior (e.g., accumulation of skills or the development of new goods
and production techniques) and discourage predatory activities (e.g.,
rent seeking, corruption, and theft.)
The EFW measure is available for a large number of countries over a
lengthy period of time. This is a major advantage because it allows the
study of how changes in institutional quality affect economic growth.
(3) While there are advantages to using proxies for institutional
quality, such as is done by Hall and Jones (1999) and Acemoglu, Johnson,
and Robinson (2001), that approach precludes looking at the effect of
decade-by-decade changes in institutional quality. In contrast, the
approach employed here makes it possible to investigate directly the
impact of changes in institutional quality on economic performance.
Measurement of Geographic and Locational Factors
Jeffery Sachs has popularized the view that a country's level
of economic activity will be adversely affected by a tropical climate
and a location that is distant from the world's major market
centers while access to an ocean coastline will exert a favorable impact. We measure these factors in the same manner as Sachs and his
fellow researchers. The proportion of a country's geographic area
located in a tropical region (Tropics) will be used to measure the
tropical location variable. (4) The distance from core markets (Air
Distance) variable is the minimum air distance (in kilometers) of a
country from any one of the world's major trading centers
(Rotterdam, New York, or Tokyo). Finally, the coastal variable is a
percentage of a country's population living within 100 kilometers
of an ocean coastline. (5)
Measurement of Physical and Human Capital
The data for physical capital per worker (Kpw) and human capital
per worker (Hpw) are from Baier, Dwyer, and Tamura (2003). The physical
capital stock was derived from annual investment data in the usual
manner. A 7 percent depreciation rate was used to convert the annual
investment data into capital stock estimates. The human capital
estimates reflect cross-country differences in both years of schooling
and demographic (age) factors that can be expected to influence the
years of work experience. The years of schooling were also adjusted for
differences in returns across schooling categories (elementary,
secondary, and higher education). We believe that these data are the
most comprehensive cross-country human capital estimates currently
available. The physical and human capital data are available for 91 of
the 99 countries in our core data set. All of the eight omitted
countries have a population of less than one million.
Cross-Country Differences in Income Levels and Growth Rates:
Empirical Results
Because the economic performance of an economy will generally
reflect the quality of its institutional arrangements and policies over
a substantial time period, empirical analysis should also employ a
measure that reflects institutional quality over a substantial time
period. The core database for this study comprises 99 countries for
which the Economic Freedom of the World data are available in 1980,
1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000. (6) The EFW rating used throughout this
paper is the mean summary rating for these five years during the
1980-2000 period, which reflects the quality of a nation's
institutions and policies over a period of two decades.
The Determinants of Cross-Country Differences in per Capita GDP
Earlier, the study identified three different explanations in the
recent economics literature for cross-country differences in economic
performance. Table 1 looks at each of these explanations separately to
see how much of the cross-country differences in per capita GDP in the
year 2000 each can explain. Because the level of income is the dependent
variable, this analysis will reflect the cumulative long-run
income-enhancing effects of the independent variables. The first
regression takes the EFW index as the sole measure of institutional
quality, and using that variable alone finds that differences in
institutions explain 63.2 percent of the cross-country variation in per
capita GDP. The square of EFW rather than the linear form is used here
because it gives a slightly better fit. This reflects the fact that a
one-unit increase in EFW has a larger impact on per capita GDP for
countries with higher EFW ratings than for those with lower ratings. (7)
The three key variables suggested by Sachs are incorporated into the
geographic-locational model of Equation 2. This model explains slightly
more than half of the variation in per capita income. The production
function approach, using measures of human and physical capital in the
third regression, explains 92.8 percent of the cross-country variation
in income.
Clearly, each of the three explanations of cross-country
differences in per capita GDP has considerable explanatory power. The
t-statistics on the coefficients show that all of the independent
variables in all three regressions are statistically significant as
well, providing empirical support for all three explanations. The
R-squares indicate that the production function approach explains the
greatest percentage of the variation in incomes across countries, but
while this shows the importance of human and physical capital to the
generation of income, it does not explain why the stock of human and
physical capital varies across countries.
The regressions in Table 2 examine the impact of institutions and
geography on the 1999 levels of physical and human capital. The first
three regressions use the stock of physical capital as the dependent
variable while the stock of human capital is the dependent variable in
the last three equations. Because both of the dependent variables are
"stock" measures, the coefficients for the independent
variables will reflect their estimated cumulative effects over lengthy
time periods. Regressions 1 and 4 show that the 1980-2000 mean EFW
rating by itself explains a substantial amount of the variation across
countries in the levels of both physical and human capital. Regression 1
shows that a one-unit increase in the square of the EFW rating is
associated with an increase of $1,897 in the 1999 stock of physical
capital per worker, and regression 4 shows that a one-unit increase in
the EFW rating increases the stock of human capital per worker by 0.112
years. (8)
Equations 2 and 3 add the tropical location and share of population
near a coastline variables to the physical capital model, while
Equations 5 and 6 add them to the human capital model. The addition of
these variables reduces the size of the EFW coefficient somewhat, but it
remains sizable and statistically significant. The tropical location
variable is negative and significant, and it adds substantially to the
explanatory power. This is consistent with the view articulated by Sachs
that a tropical location adversely affects capital formation. The
coastal variable is positive and significant in the human capital
equation, but insignificant in the physical capital equation. The size
of the t-ratio for the coastal variable and its additional contribution
to [R.sup.2] indicate that it is substantially less potent than the
institutional environment (EFW) and tropical location as a determinant of both physical and human capital. The distance from the major markets
variable was omitted from Table 2 because it was insignificant in both
the physical and human capital stock regressions. The findings of Table
2 indicate that the institutional (EFW) and tropical variables are
important determinants of cross-country differences in the stock of both
physical and human capital. The impact of the coastal variable is
smaller, particularly as a determinant of the physical capital stock.
The impact of institutional factors on the levels of physical and
human capital across countries shows that the production function
approach to economic growth leaves out an important factor if it does
not account for institutional differences across countries. Levels of
physical and human capital do have a substantial impact on a
country's income, but a country's institutional quality has a
major effect on a country's level of human and physical capital.
Better institutions provide a greater incentive for individuals to
invest in their human and physical resources. The regressions show that
the tropical and coastal locational variables also have an impact on the
levels of physical and human capital.
Table 3 looks at the impact of institutional and geographical
factors along with levels of human and physical capital as determinants
of per capita GDP. The first regression shows that institutional
differences along with location in the tropics explain 75 percent of the
cross-country differences in the 2000 per capita GDP. Equation 2
illustrates that once the effects of EFW and tropical location are taken
into account, the coastal variable is insignificant and fails to add to
the explanatory power of the model. Equation 3 adds the levels of both
physical and human capital per worker (Kpw and Hpw) to the model. The
four independent variables of Equation 3 together explain about 94
percent of the cross-country variation in per capita GDP.
Because the EFW rating and the tropics variable exert a major
impact on the levels of both human and physical capital, as shown in
Table 2, those variables have both a direct and an indirect impact on
per capita GDP. The direct effect reflects their impact on per capita
GDP via the productivity of human and physical capital. The indirect
effect reflects their impact through the level of capital formation--the
fact that the levels of human and physical capital per worker are a
function of the EFW rating and tropical location.
Because the levels of physical and human capital are included in
regression 3, the indirect effect of those variables on per capita GDP
is concealed. In order to measure the indirect effects--through capital
formation--as well as the direct effects of EFW and tropical location on
per capita GDP, only the portion of the human and physical capital
variables that is independent of EFW and tropics should be included in
these measures. The residuals from Equations 2 and 4 of Table 2 provide
this information. The residuals measure the amount of physical and human
capital that are not explained by EFW and Tropics. When these residuals
are substituted for the physical and human capital variables, the
coefficients for the EFW and tropical variables will register both their
direct and indirect effects. Equation 4 of Table 3 presents these
results.
Note how the inclusion of the indirect effects through Kpw and Hpw
substantially increase the coefficients and t-ratios of both the
institutional quality and tropical variables. Once the indirect effects
are included, a one-unit increase in the square of EFW enhances per
capita GDP by slightly more than $500. This implies, for example, that
an increase in the mean 1980-2000 EFW rating from 5.0 (approximately the
levels of Argentina and Columbia) to 6.0 (approximately the level of
South Korea) enhances 2000 per capita GDP by about $5,500. Similarly, an
EFW increase from 6.0 to 7.0 enhances 2000 per capita GDP by
approximately $6,500 ($500 multiplied by the square of 7 minus the
square of 6). Equation 4 of Table 3 also highlights the importance of
tropical location. The coefficient for this variable indicates that,
other things constant, a tropical location adversely impacted 2000 per
capita GDP by almost $8,000 once the indirect as well as the direct
effects were taken into account.
Equation 5 of Table 3 adds the coastal variable to the model of
Equation 3. When only the direct effects are taken into account, the
coastal variable is insignificant. Equation 6 of Table 3 incorporates
the methodology of Equation 4; the residuals from regressions 3 and 6 in
Table 2 are substituted for the Kpw and Hpw variables, respectively.
Thus, Equation 6 will capture the indirect, as well as the direct,
effects of the institutional and geographic-locational variables. When
the indirect effects are taken into consideration, the coastal variable
exerts a positive and significant impact on 2000 per capita GDP. The
coefficients and t-statistics on the EFW and tropical variables are
approximately the same size in Equation 6 as in Equation 4.
Tables 1 through 3 show that institutional differences across
countries, as measured by differences in their EFW ratings, have a major
impact on cross-country differences in income levels. This is especially
true when one considers the impact that institutional differences have
on the levels of physical and human capital across countries.
The Determinants of Cross-Country Differences in the Growth of GDP
Higher income levels are the result of higher past rates of growth.
If there is a causal relationship between institutional quality (or any
other independent variable) and per capita GDP, differences in growth
rates should also reflect this relationship. This section will examine
the importance of cross-country differences in the quality of
institutions, as measured by countries' EFW ratings, and other
variables as determinants of differences in long-term growth rates among
countries. In order to measure long-term growth more accurately and
minimize the impact of business cycles and other factors that will
temporarily influence growth rates, the analysis will focus on
differential growth rates over the entire 1980 to 2000 time period.
Table 4 analyzes the separate contributions of institutions,
geography, and physical and human capital as determinants of growth in
per capita GDP during 1980-2000. The first regression shows that
cross-country differences in the EFW rating explain 23.6 percent of the
variation in the annual rates of growth during the two decades, and the
coefficient on EFW has a t-statistic of 5.59. A one-unit change in the
EFW rating is associated with an increase in long-term annual growth of
a little more than nine-tenths of a percent. The mean growth rate of per
capita GDP for the 99 countries of our basic database was only 1.3
percent during 1980-2000, so a 0.9 percentage point increase in growth
is a substantial impact.
Equations 2 and 3 of Table 4 examine the impact of the
geographic-locational and production function models as sources of
growth. As Equation 2 shows, the three variables of the geographic model
explain approximately 22 percent of the cross-country variation in per
capita growth. The tropical location and coastal population variables of
the geographic model are statistically significant, but the distance
from major markets does not appear to have a significant impact on a
country's growth rate. The growth rate of physical and human
capital taken together explain slightly more than 42 percent of the
cross-country variation in the growth of per capita real GDP, with the
growth rate of physical capital significant and the growth rate of human
capital insignificant at generally accepted confidence levels.
As with the regressions in Table 1 that looked at determinants of
the levels of income across countries, there is statistical evidence
supportive of each of the three major explanations for differences in
economic growth across countries. Once again, the production function
explanation using physical and human capital as explanatory variables
produces the highest [R.sup.2], but all three of the models have some
explanatory power.
As illustrated in Table 2, institutions and geography have an
effect on the stock of both human and physical capital. They also exert
an impact on the rate of capital formation. Using several alternative
measures of capital formation, Table 5 addresses this issue. In Equation
1 of Table 5, real annual investment per worker (measured in 1995 U.S.
dollars) during 1980-2000 is the dependent variable. As the equation
indicates, EFW exerted a strong impact of $1,281 on average annual rate
of investment per worker during the two decades. This was true even
after the effects of the initial (1980) per capita income level and the
tropical and coastal variables were taken into account. In contrast,
neither the tropical nor coastal variables exerted a significant impact
on cross-country differences in real investment per worker.
The investment per worker figures of Equation 1 include both
private-sector and public-sector investment. Foreign direct investment
(FDI) per worker provides an alternative measure that will be almost
entirely reflective of private investment flows. Furthermore, the FDI
figures will reflect the attractiveness of a country's investment
climate to those residing outside of the country. As Equation 2
illustrates, the EFW measure of institutional quality also exerted a
strong impact on FDI per worker during 1980-2000. The impact of the
other variables in Equation 2 was similar to that of Equation 1. A
higher initial income level was associated with more foreign investment
per worker, but neither tropical location nor coastal population share
exerted a significant impact on FDI.
In Equation 3 of Table 5, investment as a share of GDP (I/GDP) is
the dependent variable. Once again, the EFW rating is positive and
statistically significant, indicating that the quality of a
country's institutions exert a strong impact on the rate of
investment. Even though countries with a lower initial GDP invested a
smaller dollar amount per worker (Equations 1 and 2), the negative sign
on the 1980 per capita GDP variable in Equation 3 indicates these
countries actually invested a larger share of their GDP during the two
subsequent decades. A tropical location exerts a negative and
significant impact on investment as a share of GDP, while a larger
coastal population enhances the I/GDP ratio. Thus, Equation 3 indicates
that both institutional and geographical factors have an impact on
investment as a share of GDP.
The last two regressions of Table 5 focus on the growth of physical
and human capital per worker. The fourth regression shows that better
institutions enhance the growth rate of physical capital per worker.
Again, the level of GDP in 1980 has a negative impact on the growth rate
of physical capital, so countries that are poorer initially tend to have
higher investment growth. The growth of physical capital for countries
in the tropics tends to be slower, but the coastal variable fails to
exert a statistically significant impact on the growth of Kpw. In the
final regression with the growth rate of human capital as the dependent
variable, none of the independent variables are statistically
significant.
Taken as a group, the regressions in Table 5, like those of Table
3, indicate that a country's institutional environment exerts a
strong impact on capital formation. Investment tends to flow toward
countries with institutions and policies that are more consistent with
economic freedom. While the results are mixed for the geographic and
locational variables, there is some evidence that a tropical location
adversely affects the investment rate of physical capital.
As Tables 2 and 5 have shown, institutional quality affects both
the stock of capital and rate of investment. Institutional factors may
also influence the productivity of investment. Table 6 analyzes this
issue. The dependent variable in Table 6 is the annual growth rate of
per capita GDP from 1980 to 2000. The first regression uses investment
as a fraction of GDP for 1980-2000 as the independent variable, measured
as the average of each year's ratio of investment to GDP, and shows
that the level of investment explains a substantial share (43.5 percent)
of the variation in GDP growth across countries. Equation 2 of Table 6
partitions the 99 countries in the database into three groups based on
their EFW ratings. The first independent variable multiplies I/GDP by
one if a nation's EFW rating is 7 or above, and zero otherwise. The
second independent variable does the same for nations with an EFW rating
between 5 and 6.99, and the third independent variable separates out
countries with an EFW rating below 5. All of the independent variables
are significant, and together explain nearly half of the variation in
GDP growth across countries.
The key feature of this regression is the magnitude of the
coefficients. For countries with EFW ratings of 7 or above, the
coefficient is .275, which is greater than the .236 coefficient for the
countries with ratings from 5 to 6.99, which in turn is greater than the
.197 coefficient for the countries with ratings below 5. Equation 3 of
Table 6 adds the tropical and coastal variables to the model. The
tropics variable is negative and statistically significant, but the
coastal variable is insignificant. The magnitudes of the coefficients
for the I/GDP variables all fall by a small amount, but changes in
investment still exert a larger positive impact on the growth of GDP in
those countries with higher EFW ratings.
This shows that for any given level of investment, investment is
more productive in countries with a better institutional environment, as
measured by the mean 1980-2000 EFW. Holding the tropical and coastal
variables constant, a given amount of investment results in a higher
rate of economic growth in countries with higher long-term EFW ratings.
The coefficient of .242 on the group with the highest EFW rating is 13.6
percent higher than the coefficient of .212 on the middle group of
countries. Thus, holding the tropical and coastal conditions constant, a
unit increase in investment as a share of GDP enhances the long-term
growth of per capita GDP by 13.6 percent more in the group with the
higher EFW ratings. Similarly, investment in the highest-rated group of
countries is 31.7 percent more productive than in the lowest-rated group
of countries.
The fourth regression divides the 99 countries into two groups:
those that have EFW ratings in the top half of all countries and those
that have ratings in the bottom half, and the fifth regression adds the
tropics and coastal variables to the model of Equation 4. As Equation 5
shows, the coefficient of .217 on the top half is 14.2 percent larger
than the coefficient of .190 on the bottom half, again showing that the
productivity of investment is higher in countries with higher long-term
EFW ratings. (9)
A higher EFW rating was associated with a higher level of
investment, as Table 5 showed, and Table 6 shows that given the level of
investment, investment is more productive in countries with a higher EFW
rating. Thus, higher institutional quality, as measured by the EFW
rating, has two reinforcing effects on the relationship between
investment and GDP growth: better institutions both increase the level
of investment, and enhance its productivity.
Table 7 incorporates the key institutional, geographic-locational,
and capital formation variables into combined models and uses them to
analyze the growth of per capita GDP during 1980-2000. It also
incorporates a methodology capable of capturing both the direct (through
improvements in efficiency and productivity) and indirect (through
capital formation) effects of institutional quality on the long-term
growth of per capita GDP.
As Equation 1 of Table 7 shows, the mean EFW rating (1980-2000)
along with the change in physical capital per worker and human capital
per worker during the two decades explain 54.8 percent of the
cross-country differences in the growth of per capita GDP over this time
period. All three of the independent variables are positive and
statistically significant. Equation 2 adds the geographic-locational
variables. (10) While the tropical variable has the expected negative
sign and is statistically significant, the coastal variable is
insignificant. The addition of these two variables increases the
[R.sup.2] to 57.0, Equation 3 adds per capita GDP in 1980 as an
independent variable to incorporate the idea that countries with higher
initial income levels may grow less rapidly. Indeed, the sign of the
initial per capita income variable is negative and statistically
significant. The explanatory power of the model represented by Equation
3 is almost 60 percent.
In the specification of Equation 3, the EFW variable will reflect
the impact of a one-unit change in institutional quality after the
effects of the other variables, including Kpw, have been registered.
Thus, the EFW coefficient of Equation 3 reflects only its direct impact
on growth as a result of its impact on the efficiency of resource use.
But this is only part of its impact on growth. As was illustrated in
Table 5, EFW also influences investment and the growth of the capital
stock (Kpw). The EFW coefficient in Equation 3 of Table 7 will not
reflect this indirect impact.
In order to capture both the direct effect and indirect effect of
EFW through capital formation, the methodology used in Table 3 is again
employed. The residuals from Equation 4 of Table 5 measure the
cross-country variation in Kpw that is unrelated to EFW and the other
independent variables of Equation 3 in Table 7. When these residuals are
substituted for the change in Kpw variable, the coefficients for EFW and
the other variables in the model will reflect both their direct impact
and their indirect impact, through changes in Kpw, on the growth of per
capita GDP. Equation 4 of Table 7 presents these results. Note that the
coefficients and t-ratios for both the institutional and
geographic-locational variables are higher in Equation 4 than Equation
3. This is because their coefficients in Equation 4 now incorporate
their indirect effects through changes in Kpw.
Once both the direct and indirect effects are taken into account, a
one-unit change in EFW increases long-term growth by an estimated 1.24
percentage points. Because this is a change in a growth rate, it will
have a large cumulative effect. Over a 30-year period, for example, a
one-unit increase in a country's EFW index would increase the
country's per capita GDP by approximately 43 percent.
Changes in Institutional Quality and Growth
The results reported above have focused on how variations in the
level of economic freedom influence per capita GDP and its growth rate.
If institutional quality as measured by the EFW index is a important
factor underlying economic growth, changes in EFW should also exert an
observable impact on the growth of per capita GDP. However, the
immediate effects of an institutional change may be relatively small and
the response to the change may continue to evolve over a lengthy time
period. Initially, there may be uncertainty with regard to whether the
change is temporary or permanent. If a country has a history of
institutions that inhibit economic activity, people may be suspicious
that improvements in institutions may be reversed, either because
political leaders support the old institutions or because institutional
improvements prove difficult to enforce. Furthermore, it will take time
for decisionmakers to identify new opportunities and for markets to
adjust fully to the new environment. All of this makes it more difficult
to measure the effects of institutional change and highlights the
importance of analyzing the impact of such changes over a fairly long
time period.
Table 8 analyzes the impact of changes in the EFW rating during
both the 1980s and the 1990s on the growth of per capita GDP during
1980-2000. In addition to the mean EFW rating (1980-2000), the changes
in EFW during each of the two decades are introduced as independent
variables. In Equation 1, the three economic freedom variables are
considered along with the changes in Kpw and Hpw during the two decades.
All of the variables have the expected sign and, except for the change
in EFW during the 1990s, all are significant at the 95 percent
confidence level. A one-unit increase in EFW during the 1980s was
associated with a 0.71 percentage point increase in growth during the
two decades. The Equation 1 model explains 58.5 percent of the
cross-country variation in growth during 1980-2000. The insignificance of the change in the EFW variable during the 1990s is not surprising
given the expected time lag accompanying an institutional change and the
fact that a change during the 1990s would potentially impact growth for
only a fraction of the two decades.
Equations 2 and 3 add two additional variables, tropical location
and initial income level, that prior analysis suggests exert a
significant impact on the growth of per capita GDP. The addition of
these two variables increases the explanatory power of the model to 62.4
percent. Both the tropical and initial income variables are significant
and have the expected sign, but they exert little impact on either the
pattern or the significance of the other variables in the model. The
change in EFW during the 1980s is significant in both Equations 2 and 3
and its estimated impact on the growth rate of per capita GDP remains
near seven-tenths of a percentage point. The change in EFW during the
1990s continues to be positive, but it falls just short of significance
at the 90 percent confidence level.
As we have previously discussed, the model of Equation 3 will fail
to register the effects of EFW that are transmitted through its impact
on the growth of capital formation. In order to better measure the total
impact of EFW, once again we estimate the impact of the independent
variables of Equation 3 on Kpw and then insert the residuals from this
equation into the model instead of Kpw. Equation 4 of Table 8 presents
these results. Except for the change in EFW during the 1990s, all of the
variables in this model have the expected sign and are statistically
significant. A one-unit increase in the level of EFW enhances long-term
growth by an estimated 1.33 percentage points and the t-ratio for this
variable is very high (7.09). Further, a one-unit increase in EFW during
the first of the two decades increases overall growth during the period
by an additional 0.68 of a percentage point. In this specification,
location in the tropics reduces long-term growth by an estimated 1.92
percentage points.
The pattern of these results sheds light on the impact of
institutional change. The size and robustness of the change in EFW
during the 1980s suggests that changes in institutional factors make a
difference and that they will continue to exert an impact on economic
growth over a long period of time. Correspondingly, the size and
insignificance of the change in EFW during the 1990s indicates that the
full impact of an institutional change will take time and that the
immediate effects may be relatively small.
Table 9 divides the data set into two decades in order to
facilitate a more detailed examination of the timing issue. The
dependent variable in Table 9 is the growth rate of per capita income
during the decade of either the 1980s or the 1990s, so each country has
two observations. The model of Equation 1 comprises the EFW rating at
the beginning of the decade (either 1980 or 1990), the change in EFW
during the first half of the decade, the change during the last half of
the decade, and a dummy variable (1 if 1990s). Equation 2 adds the
change in Kpw and Hpw and the tropical location variable to the model.
The results of the first two regressions show that changes in the EFW
rating in the first five years of the decade have strong effects on GDP
growth. A one-unit increase in EFW during the first five years of the
decade is estimated to increase growth during the 10-year period by more
than 1 percentage point. In contrast, changes in the last five years of
a decade were statistically insignificant in both equations. Again, this
pattern suggests that institutional changes affect growth, but their
immediate effects are often small.
Equations 3 and 4 integrate the change in EFW during the five years
before each of the decades into the model. Thus, the economic freedom
variables are the EFW rating five years before the beginning of the
decade (1975 for the decade of the 1980s and 1985 for the decade of the
1990s) and the changes in the EFW rating for the five years before the
decade, the first five years of the decade, and the last five years of
the decade. Equation 3 includes only the economic freedom variables and
the decade dummy variable. Equation 4 adds the input (change in Kpw and
Hpw) and tropical location control variables to the model.
Both Equations 3 and 4 indicate that a change in EFW during the
first half of a decade exerts a strong (more than one percentage point)
and statistically significant (t-statistics of 5.90 and 4.74) positive
impact on growth of per capita GDP during the decade. The impact of the
change in EFW during the five years before the decade is positive and
only slightly smaller (0.91 compared with 1.04 for the first five years
of the decade) in Equation 4. This indicates that (a) institutional
changes continue to influence economic growth long after they are
initiated and (b) a time lag of 5 to 10 years will often occur before
the full effects of an institutional change are observed. Once again,
the change in EFW during the last half of a decade failed to exert a
significant impact on growth during the decade. This illustrates that it
takes time for institutional changes to work and implies that their
immediate effects are often small.
Taken together, Tables 8 and 9 show that changes in the level of
institutional quality exert an impact on economic growth. (11) However,
the immediate effects of institutional changes are often weak. For this
reason, empirical work trying to identify the impact of institutions
must look at longer time periods to identify the effects. This also
indicates that from a policy perspective, credibility is important, and
countries making institutional changes with the hope of increasing
economic growth must be prepared to keep them in place long enough for
their effects to appear.
Conclusion
The results presented here indicate that cross-country differences
in institutional quality, as measured by the EFW index, exert a major
impact on both income differences and long-term growth rates. Countries
with institutions and policies more consistent with economic freedom
both grow more rapidly and achieve higher income levels. Our findings go
beyond the existing literature in that they show that institutional
quality influences economic growth by affecting the rate of investment
as well as through the productivity of resource use. Furthermore, we
show that changes in institutional quality influence the future growth
of per capita GDP.
Our estimates indicate that a one-unit increase in the long-term
EFW rating is associated with a 2.16 percentage point increase in
investment as a share of GDP and a 1.24 percentage point increase in the
annual growth of capital per worker (Table 5, Equations 3 and 4). Not
only do better institutions increase the amount of investment, they also
increase its productivity. Measured by its impact on GDP growth, the
productivity of investment in countries with EFW ratings of 7.0 or more
was 13.6 percent higher than for countries with EFW ratings between 5.0
and 6.99 and 31.7 percent higher than for countries with EFW ratings of
less than 5.0 (Table 6, Equation 3).
Holding constant geographic factors and changes in human and
physical capital, a one-unit increase in a country's EFW rating
increases the growth of per capita GDP by about 1.24 percentage points
(Table 7, Equation 4). This suggests that if countries like Egypt,
India, or Pakistan with mean EFW ratings of approximately 5 during
1980-2000, increased and maintained their long-term EFW rating by one
unit, they could increase their long-run annual growth rate of per
capita GDP by more than one percentage point. The average annual growth
of per capita GDP during 1980-2000 for the 99 countries of this study
was only 1.32 percent, so a 1.24 percentage point increase in long-term
growth would be substantial. (12)
The increases would not come overnight, however. Analysis of the
lag between institutional changes and changes in income suggests that a
time period of 5 to 10 years is necessary for the effects of an
improvement in the quality of a country's institutions to be
registered fully (Tables 7, 8, and 9). Initially, the observable
positive effects on growth may be minimal. Given the short time horizon
of many political decisionmakers, these time lags may well create
conflict between short-run political expediency and sound economics.
Historically, the growth literature has placed much emphasis on the
importance of inputs into the production process. However, both the
quantity and productivity of inputs will be influenced by the
institutional environment. Future analysis of the growth process must
take this point into consideration.
TABLE 1
THE DETERMINANTS OF CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN
GDP PER CAPITA: THREE ALTERNATIVE MODELS
Dependent Variable: GDP Per Capita, 2000
(t-ratio in parentheses)
I-P G-L P-F
Model Model Model
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)
EFW [Rating.sup.2], 651.00
1980-2000 (13.00)
Tropics -10,590.00
(9.33)
Coastal 4,554.00
(2.20)
Air Distance (1,000s km.) -1.22
(3.51)
Kpw, 1999 0.25
(15.93)
Hpw, 1999 954.00
(4.27)
Intercept -11,183.00 18,831.00 -3,900.00
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 63.20 50.80 92.80
Number of Countries 99 99 91
TABLE 2 ECONOMIC FREEDOM, GEOGRAPHY, AND THE STOCK OF PHYSICAL AND
HUMAN CAPITAL PER WORKER
Dependent Variable: Kpw, 1999 (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)
EFW [Rating.sup.2], 1980-2000 1,897.00 1,610.00 1,527.00
(13.41) (12.52) (11.11)
Tropics -21,502.00 -22,203.00
(6.06) (6.27)
Coastal 7,275.00
(1.62)
Intercept -32.704.00 -11,543.00 -12,243.00
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 66.50 76.10 76.50
Number of Countries 91 91 91
Dependent Variable:
Dependent Variable: Kpw, 1999 Hpw, 1999
(t-ratio in parentheses) (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (4) (5) (6)
EFW [Rating.sup.2], 1980-2000 0.11 0.09 0.07
(8.75) (7.38) (6.00)
Tropics -1.90 -2.02
(5.82) (6.47)
Coastal 1.27
(3.20)
Intercept 2.66 4.52 4.40
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 45.70 60.30 64.10
Number of Countries 91 91 91
NOTE: When Air Distance was added to Equations (3) and (6),
it exerted an insignificant impact on the dependent variable.
TABLE 3
ECONOMIC FREEDOM, GEOGRAPHY, AND PHYSICAL AND HUMAN CAPITAL AS
DETERMINANTS OF GDP PER CAPITA
Dependent Variable: GDP Per Capita, 2000 (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)
EFW [Rating.sup.2], 1980-2000 529.42 516.73 107.55
(11.91) (10.91) (2.99)
Tropics -8,472.00 -8,566.00 -2,061.00
(7.03) (7.06) (2.81)
Coastal 1,170.00
-0.79
Kpw, 1999 0.21
(10.31)
Hpw, 1999 762.90
(3.47)
Kpw, 1999 (residuals)
Hpw, 1999 (residuals)
Intercept -2,575.00 -2,733.00 -3,758.00
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 75.10 75.30 93.70
Number of Countries 99 99 91
Independent Variables (4) (5) (6)
EFW [Rating.sup.2], 1980-2000 508.94 109.41 485.86
(23.75) (3.03) (20.96)
Tropics -7,982.00 -1,927.00 -8,176.00
(13.50) (2.52) (13.68)
Coastal -516.90 2,021.00
(0.64) (2.66)
Kpw, 1999 0.21
(10.28)
Hpw, 1999 804.50
(3.50)
Kpw, 1999 (residuals) 0.21 0.21
(10.31) (10.28)
Hpw, 1999 (residuals) 762.90 804.50
(3.47) (3.50)
Intercept -2,709.00 -3,893.00 -2,904.00
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 93.70 93.60 93.60
Number of Countries 91 91 91
NOTE: The values for Kpw (residuals) and Hpw (residuals) of
Equation 4 were derived from Table 2, Equations 2 and 5,
respectively. The Kpw (residuals) and Hpw (residuals) of Equation
6 were derived from Table 2, Equations 3 and 6, respectively.
TABLE 4
THE DETERMINANTS OF CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN
GROWTH OF GDP PER CAPITA: THREE ALTERNATIVE MODELS
Dependent Variable: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP
Per Capita, 1980-2000 (t-ratio in parentheses)
I-P G-L P-F
Model Model Model
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)
EFW Rating, 1980-2000 0.94
(5.59)
Tropics -1.78
(3.97)
Coastal 1.48
(2.91)
Air Distance (1000s km.) 0.02
(0.19)
Growth of Kpw, 1980-1999 0.49
(7.85)
Growth of Hpw, 1980-1999 0.34
(1.42)
Intercept -3.99 1.40 -0.15
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 23.60 21.90 42.20
Number of Countries 99 99 91
TABLE 5
ECONOMIC FREEDOM, GEOGRAPHY, AND LOCATION
AS DETERMINANTS OF INVESTMENT
Dependent Variable
(t-ratio in parentheses)
Investment Per FDI Per
Worker (US$), Worker (US$), I/GDP,
1980-2000 1980-2000 1980-2000
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3)
EFW Rating, 1980-2000 1,281.20 545.70 2.16
(4.12) (4.00) (3.09)
GDP Per Capita, 1980 837.59 121.80 -0.60
(in 1,000s US$) (8.46) (2.92) (2.70)
Tropics -562.80 -15.70 -3.76
(0.92) (0.06) (2.74)
Coastal -535.40 -42.50 3.00
(0.83) (0.16) (2.06)
Intercept -6,457.00 -2,883.00 12.28
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 79.20 51.20 18.50
Number of Countries 99 97 99
Dependent Variable
(t-ratio in parentheses)
Growth of Growth of
Kpw, 1980- Hpw, 1980-
1999 1999
Independent Variables (4) (5)
EFW Rating, 1980-2000 1.24 -0.08
(3.76) (0.75)
GDP Per Capita, 1980 -0.51 -0.00
(in 1,000s US$) (4.76) (0.09)
Tropics -2.36 -0.14
(3.69) (0.73)
Coastal 0.53 0.16
(0.77) (0.75)
Intercept -2.04 2.03
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 22.00 0.00
Number of Countries 91 91
NOTE: Hong Kong and Taiwan were omitted from Equation
2 because the FDI data were unavailable.
TABLE 6
ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND THE PRODUCTIVITY OF INVESTMENT
Dependent Variable: Average Annual Growth Rate
of GDP Per Capita, 1980-2000 (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 0.244
(8.74)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 x EFW 0.275 0.242
> 7.0 (9.40) (7.81)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 x 5.0 0.236 0.212
< EFW < 7.0 (8.76) (7.56)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 x EFW 0.197 0.183
< 5.0 (6.52) (6.21)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 x EFW 0.245 0.217
(top half) (9.11) (7.72)
I/GDP, 1980-2000 x EFW 0.203 0.190
(bottom half) (6.72) (6.47)
Tropics -0.937 -1.003
(2.93) (3.08)
Coastal 0.344 0.347
(0.83) (0.81)
Intercept -3.96 -3.72 -2.91 -3.54 -2.75
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 43.50 49.70 53.10 47.90 51.70
Number of Countries 99 99 99 99 99
TABLE 7
ECONOMIC FREEDOM, INVESTMENT, GEOGRAPHY, AND
LOCATION AS DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH
Dependent Variable: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP Per
Capita, 1980-2000 (t-ratios in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
EFW Rating, 1980-2000 0.66 0.48 0.81 1.24
(5.04) (3.23) (4.00) (6.67)
Growth of Kpw, 1980-1999 0.43 0.41 0.35
(7.65) (7.43) (5.70)
Growth of Kpw, 1980-1999 0.35
(residuals) (5.70)
Growth of Hpw, 1980-1999 0.44 0.39 0.42 0.42
(2.07) (1.90) (2.08) (2.08)
Tropics -0.76 -1.30 -2.12
(2.41) (3.37) (5.90)
Coastal 0.48 0.49 0.68
(1.18) (1.25) (1.73)
GDP Per Capita, 1980 -0.16 -0.33
(in 1,000s US$) (2.33) (5.58)
Intercept -3.94 -2.66 -3.51 -4.21
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 54.80 57.00 59.10 59.10
Number of Countries 91 91 91 91
NOTE: The residuals for Growth of Kpw in Equation 4 are
from Table 6, Equation 4.
TABLE 8
CHANGES IN ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
Dependent Variable: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP Per
Capita, Average 1980-2000 (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
EFW Rating, 1980-2000 0.59 0.50 0.89 1.33
(4.17) (3.38) (4.35) (7.09)
Change in EFW Rating, 0.71 0.65 0.68 0.68
1980-1990 (3.09) (2.84) (3.08) (3.08)
Change in EFW Rating, 0.23 0.19 0.27 0.27
1990-2000 (1.34) (1.13) (1.62) (1.62)
Growth of Kpw, 1980-1999 0.42 0.41 0.33
(7.67) (7.54) (5.69)
Growth of Kpw, 1980-1999 0.33
(residuals) (5.69)
Growth of Hpw, 1980-1999 0.47 0.45 0.49 0.49
(2.33) (2.23) (2.51) (2.51)
Tropics -0.57 -1.15 -1.92
(1.86) (3.12) (5.56)
GDP Per Capita, 1980 -0.17 -0.35
(in 1,000s US$) (2.66) (5.93)
Intercept -4.15 -3.19 -4.40 -5.14
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 58.50 59.70 62.40 62.40
Number of Countries 91 91 91 91
NOTE: The residuals for Growth of Kpw in Equation 4 are from
the following equation:
Change in Kpw = -2.23 + 1.32 EFW Rating -0.51 GDP Per Capita
-2.31 Tropics.
All variables were significant and the adjusted [R.sup.2]
was 22.4.
TABLE 9
CHANGES IN ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE 1980S AND 1990s
Dependent Variable: Average Annual Growth Rate of GDP Per Capita
during the 1980s and 1990s (t-ratio in parentheses)
Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
EFW Rating, beginning of 0.85 0.56
decade (7.02) (4.64)
EFW Rating, 5 years before 0.77 0.52
decade (5.85) (4.10)
Change in EFW Rating, 1.26 0.91
5 years before decade (4.93) (3.72)
Change in EFW Rating, 1.45 1.11 1.41 1.04
first 5 years of decade (6.37) (5.21) (5.90) (4.74)
Change in EFW Rating, 0.24 -0.07 0.19 -0.11
second 5 years of decade (0.85) (0.27) (0.65) (0.39)
Growth of Kpw, during decade 0.21 0.20
(5.51) (5.23)
Growth of Hpw, during decade 0.24 0.26
(1.51) (1.48)
Tropics -0.69 -0.52
(2.41) (1.79)
Dummy for Decade (1 if 1990s) -0.74 -0.52 -0.92 -0.63
(2.47) (1.49) (2.97) (2.08)
Intercept -3.63 -2.35 -3.19 -2.25
[R.sup.2] (adjusted) 26.50 40.10 29.80 41.20
Number of Countries 198 180 169 156
NOTES: The number of observations in Equation 3 is reduced because the
EFW Rating was available for only 70 countries in 1975; the number of
observations in Equations 2 and 4 were lower than 1 and 3 because the
Kpw and Hpw data were unavailable for some countries; when the
equations here were run separately by decade, the pattern of results
was the same. A Chow test confirmed the validity of combining the two
decades into a single regression.
(1) Olson's ideas are further developed in Azfar and Cadwell
(2003) and Knack (2003).
(2) Strictly speaking, the EFW index measures both longer term
institutional variables such as the quality of the legal system and
shorter term public policies such as marginal tax rates. Throughout this
study we used the term "institutional quality" to refer to
both.
(3) Hanson (2003) criticizes the empirical literature using various
economic freedom indexes, arguing that different indexes measure
different things even though they come up with similar results. Because
this study uses only the EFW index, Hanson's criticisms of the
broader literature are only peripherally related to the work undertaken
here.
(4) Tropical regions are defined as areas located between 23.5
degrees of latitude North (Tropic of Cancer) and 23.5 degrees of
latitude South (Tropic of Capricorn).
(5) See Gallup, Sachs, and Mellinger (1999) for additional details
on these data.
(6) These data were available for 103 countries. Because their per
capita GDP figures and growth rates were dominated by conditions in the
world market for crude oil, four of the countries (Bahrain, Kuwait,
Oman, and the United Arab Emirates) were omitted from the core database.
(7) The $651 coefficient for the square of EFW in Equation 1
indicates, for example, that a typical country with a long-term EFW
rating of 6.0 had an income level in 2000 that was $7,161 ($651 times
11, the difference between the square of 6 and the square of 5) higher
than one with a long-term EFW rating of 5.0.
(8) These coefficients indicate that, measured in 1995 U.S.
dollars, the capital stock per worker of countries with long-time EFW
ratings of 6.0, for example, were more than $20,000 greater in 1999 than
those with long-time EFW ratings of 5.0. Correspondingly, the EFW
coefficient in the human capital equation indicates that countries with
long-term ratings of 6.0 had approximately 1.2 additional years of human
capital than those with long-term ratings of 5.0. Basically, the human
capital variable is a country's mean years of schooling adjusted
for its age composition and the diminishing returns associated with
additional schooling.
(9) F-tests on the joint equality of the three EFW coefficients in
regressions 2 and 3 yield values of 7.06 and 3.71, with associated p
values of .001 and .03, indicating that the coefficients are
statistically different. F-tests on the joint equality of the two EFW
coefficients in regressions 4 and 5 produce values of 4.57 and 3.91 and
p values of .035 and .051 again indicating that the coefficients are
statistically different.
(10) When the growth of per capita GDP is the dependent variable,
the distance from major markets variable was .always insignificant.
Thus, it has been omitted from the growth tables.
(11) There is the possibility that the strong relationship between
EFW and growth reflects, at least partially, a cause and effect
relationship that runs in the opposite direction: from growth to
institutional improvements (higher EFW ratings). In order to examine
this possibility, we considered the following models:
(1) change in per capita GDP in [t.sub.2] = f(change in EFW in
[t.sub.1]),
(2) change in EFW in [t.sub.2] = f(change in per capita GDP in
[t.sub.1]).
The subscripts [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2] indicate successive time
periods. The two models were run for time periods of both 5 and 10
years. Various control variables including initial per capita GDP and
initial EFW ratings were also incorporated into the models. In every
case, the change in EFW exerted a positive and significant impact on the
growth of per capita GDP during the subsequent period. In contrast, the
change in per capita GDP during [t.sub.1] never exerted a significant
positive impact on EFW during to. In a few cases the relationship
between the change in per capita GDP in [t.sub.1] and the change in EFW
in [t.sub.2] was negative and significant, suggesting that poor economic
performance might actually enhance the likelihood of constructive
economic reform. Clearly, there was no evidence of a causal relationship
running from higher growth rates to subsequent increases in EFW.
(12) Looking at the underlying data, countries in the bottom half
ranked by EFW index had an average per capita GDP growth rate of 0.446
percent while those in the top half averaged a 2.218 percent rate of
growth, so without controlling for other factors, the GDP growth rate in
the top half of countries by EFW rating was nearly five times higher
than for countries in the bottom half.
References
Acemoglu, D.; Johnson, S.; and Robinson, J. A. (2001) "The
Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical
Investigation." American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369-1401.
Azfar, O., and Cadwell, C. A., eds. (2003) Market-Augmenting
Government: The Institutional Foundations for Prosperity. Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press.
Baier, S. L.; Dwyer, G. P.; and Tamura, R. (2003) "How
Important Are Capital and Total Factor Productivity for Economic
Growth?" Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Research
Department.
Barro, R. J. (1996) "Democracy and Growth." Journal of
Economic Growth 1: 1-27.
Barro, R. J., and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth. New
York: McGraw Hill.
Bauer, P. T. (1957) Economic Analysis and Policy in Underdeveloped Countries. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
--(1972) Dissent on Development: Studies and Debates in Development
Economics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Berggren, N. (2003) "The Benefits of Economic Freedom: A
Survey." Independent Review 8 (2): 193-211.
de Soto, H. (1989) The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the
Third World. New York: Harper and Row.
Gallup, J. L.; Sachs, J. D.; and Mellinger, A. D. (1998) Geography
and Economic Development. Washington: World Bank.
Gwartney, J. D., and Lawson, R. A. (2003) Economic Freedom of the
World: 2003 Annual Report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.
Gwartney, J. D.; Lawson, R. A.; and Holcombe, R. G. (1999)
"Economic Freedom and the Environment for Economic Growth."
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155 (4): 643-63.
Hall, R. E., and Jones, C. I. (1999) "Why Do Some Countries
Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?" Quarterly
Journal of Economics 114 (1): 83-116.
Hanson II, J. R. (2003) "Proxies in the New Political Economy:
Caveat Emptor." Economic Inquiry 41 (4): 639-46.
Hayek, F. A. (1945) "The Use of Knowledge in Society."
American Economic Review 35 (4): 519-30.
--(1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Knack, S. (1996) "Institutions and the Convergence Hypothesis:
The Cross-National Evidence." Public Choice 87: 207-28.
--, ed. (2003) Democracy, Governance, and Growth. Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press.
Knack, S., and Keefer, P. (1995) "Institutions and Economic
Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional
Measures." Economics and Politics 7: 207-27.
Landes, D. S. (1998) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some
Are So Rich, and Some So Poor. New York: W. W. Norton.
North, D. C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and
Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Olson, M. (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
--(2000) Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist
Dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.
Pritchett, L. (1997)"Divergence, Big Time." Journal of
Economic Perspectives 11 (3): 3-17.
The PRS Group (2000) International Country Risk Guide. Syracuse,
N.Y.: The PRS Group, Inc.
Sachs, J. D. (2003) "Institutions Don't Rule: Direct
Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income." NBER Working Paper No.
9490.
Sachs, J. D., and Warner, A. M. (1997) "Fundamental Sources of
Long-Run Growth." American Economic Review 87 (2): 184-88.
Scully, G. W. (1988) "The Institutional Framework and Economic
Development." Journal of Political Economy 96 (3): 652-62.
--(1992) Constitutional Environments and Economic Growth.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Scully, G. W., and Slottje, D. J. (1991) "Ranking Economic
Liberty Across Countries." Public Choice 69: 121-52.
Smith, A. ([1776] 1937) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations. New York: Random House, Modern Library.
Solow, R. M. (1956) "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1): 65-94.
Torstensson, J. (1994) "Property Rights and Economic Growth:
An Empirical Study." Kyklos 47: 231-47.
World Bank (2003) 2003 World Development Indicators CD Rom.
Washington: World Bank.
World Economic Forum (2001) World Competitiveness Report 2001.
Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
James Gwartney is Professor of Economics and Gus A. Stavros Eminent Scholar Chair at Florida State University. Randall Holcombe is DeVoe L.
Moore Professor of Economics at Florida State University. Robert Lawson is Professor of Economics and George H. Moor Chair at Capital
University.