Do sovereign debtors need a bankruptcy law?
Schwartz, Anna J.
The idea that there is a "gaping hole" in the
architecture of the international financial system that should be filled
by a universal bankruptcy tribunal is not credible. For centuries,
sovereign debt defaults have been resolved without the benefit of
bankruptcy laws. When a financial crisis exposes a sovereign
debtor's bankruptcy, it seems wrongheaded to focus on resolving its
dishonored obligations rather than expanding efforts on preventing
debtors from accumulating excessive obligations.
Implicit in the bankruptcy approach is an assumption that the
financial crises that have taken place in emerging markets have been
made worse by the difficulties debtor governments have faced when trying
to attenuate the commitments they had made to their creditors. But in
each of the crises following the Mexican devaluation of 1994, the
International Monetary Fund has bailed out creditors, and, to the extent
that debt restructuring was involved, that restructuring was not
stymied. There has been so much criticism of the moral hazard created by
that policy that in the future the IMF may restrain its penchant for
bailouts. But even if it does so, its continued sponsorship of a
universal bankruptcy law should be questioned. Why would such a law be a
higher priority for the IMF than more effective oversight of the
economic policies of emerging markets?
The case for setting up an elaborate mechanism for sovereign debt
restructuring is weakened to begin with by the IMF's acknowledgment
that such an instrument would not be activated often because many
countries do not need debt restructuring. Moreover, it is not clear that
the absence of a bankruptcy law has produced chaotic conditions in the
few countries that have had to settle differences with their creditors.
Finally, it is not at all obvious how a sovereign debt bankruptcy law,
for which there is no precedent, would work or whose benefit it would
serve. If the legislation was intended to serve both debtor nations and
their creditors, it is remarkable that the IMF did not consult with
representatives of either of the parties to learn their wishes before
issuing its proposals. (1)
In this paper, I begin by discussing two recent versions of the
proposal for bankruptcy arrangements for sovereign debtors, and the
status of the proposal in 2003. I then ask if there is extensive demand
for such arrangements from debtor countries, private investors, and
disinterested observers and find it lacking. Next, I review the
alternatives proposed by various opponents of sovereign bankruptcy
legislation, the majority of whom prefer a market solution to
bureaucratic management of debt-related problems. I conclude with some
observations about the IMF's role in the elusive quest for the
development of emerging market countries by means of indebtedness.
Proposals for a Bankruptcy Law for Sovereign Debtors
In an address to a Washington audience in November 2001, Anne
Krueger--the first deputy managing director of the IMF--presented a
proposal for bankruptcy procedures for sovereign debtors to facilitate
the orderly restructuring of their debt as if that were the holy grail
long sought for the salvation of emerging market countries (Krueger
2001a). The proposal would enable governments to seek legal protection
from their creditors by declaring bankruptcy, similar to the way in
which Chapter 11 works for companies and Chapter 9 for municipalities
under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code. (2)
The objectives of sovereign bankruptcy proceedings would be to (1)
prevent creditors from disrupting negotiations by seeking repayment
through domestic courts, (3) (2) require debtors to negotiate with
creditors in good faith and to reform the policies that led to their
bankruptcy, (3) encourage lenders to provide new money (known as
debtor-in-possession financing) by guaranteeing that their claims would
come before the claims of existing private creditors, and (4) persuade
minority creditors to participate in restructuring arrangements. (4)
Krueger outlined the proposal again in a speech in Delhi, India, on
December 20, 2001, and responded to objections that had been raised
(Krueger 2001b). The IMF's executive board gave preliminary
approval to the proposal, but at a two-day meeting in March 2002 there
was no unanimity among the directors on how to proceed (Krueger 2002a).
The subject was not formally on the agenda at the spring meeting. On
April 1, 2002, Krueger answered questions at a press conference before
giving another speech modifying the proposal (Krueger 2002b).
The November 2001 Proposal
The November proposal would have authorized the IMF to grant a
government, in response to its application for a temporary standstill on
the repayment of its debt, the right to declare bankruptcy. The
government would then negotiate a restructuring of its debt with its
creditors, a majority of whom would decide the terms for all of them (a
feature modeled on British bankruptcy laws). To prevent an outflow of
private funds during the negotiations, the IMF would allow governments
to impose temporary foreign exchange controls.
To restrict the ability of creditors to enforce their claims in
national courts, it would be necessary to establish bankruptcy laws for
sovereign debtors in each of the 183 member countries of the IMF.
Otherwise creditors could attempt to enforce their claims in
jurisdictions without such laws. Alternatively, an amendment to the
Fund's articles--which requires the consent of 85 percent of the
shareholders--could create an international law binding all nations and
altering terms of all existing and future financial instruments. The IMF
would then become the international bankruptcy tribunal, whose job would
be to mimic bankruptcy proceedings in domestic corporate workouts. It
would give sovereign debtors the benefit of a freeze on creditor
lawsuits and the "cram-down" features (meaning compulsory
acceptance of a restructuring plan by dissident creditors) of a domestic
bankruptcy proceeding. Disputes between a debtor government and its
creditors would be adjudicated by an independent tribunal. A majority
vote by creditors would bind dissident creditors just as if their bonds
included collective action clauses.
The April 2002 Proposal
In April 2002, Krueger modified the original proposal, mainly in
response to criticism that the original version aggrandized the
IMF's authority to resolve a debtor's negotiations with its
creditors. The revised proposal removed the Fund from the restructuring
process, leaving decisions on the matter to the debtor and a
supermajority of the creditors. As before, an amendment to the
IMF's articles would be required, this time to achieve a uniform
legal arrangement for collective action. The definition of a
supermajority was to be determined at a later date.
A second change from the original proposal was that the validation
of the need for a stay or a standstill would be declared by the IMF only
at the start of the process but would then be revalidated by a
creditors' committee on its formation. A third change required a
single supermajority for different creditor claims (bank loans, bonds,
trade credits, interbank loans, and other claims), rather than each
creditor class, to approve prolonging a stay beyond three months and a
final restructuring agreement. If that agreement did not accord with the
Fund's view of how much the debt burden needed to be reduced to be
sustainable, the IMF could withhold further financing and additional
restructuring would be expected.
Current Status of the Proposal
As of spring 2003, no final version of the proposal existed. A
75-page staff memorandum (International Monetary Fund 2002) detailing
the status of the proposal addressed unsettled questions for the
directors to consider. One such issue is the activation of the
mechanism. Is it necessary to provide an independent confirmation of
file member's representation of unsustainability of its debt as a
condition for activation and, if so, who should perform the function?
Another unsettled issue is whether creditors should have the
opportunity to terminate the mechanism after completion of the
verification of the claims of creditors. In the history of the IMF,
previous amendments to its Articles of Agreement deall with major
changes to the structure of the Fund with respect to the rights and
obligations of its members. What distinguishes the proposed new
amendment from earlier ones is that it would affect the contractual
rights of private parties.
The process of amending the Articles is cumbersome. First, a final
version of the bankruptcy mechanism's design would have to be in
hand. The Executive Board would then have to decide by a majority vote
to propose a draft text for adoption by the Board of Governors. The
Board of Governors in turn would have to approve the proposed amendment
by a majority vote. Finally, only after acceptance of the amendment by
three-fifths of the members possessing 85 percent of the voting power,
would the mechanism enter into force. Adoption of the mechanism would
probably also require changes in domestic laws of the members.
In view of the adverse political climate the bankruptcy proposal
faced, it is no wonder that the IMF did not pursue the subject further
at its April 2003 meeting in Washington. (5)
Who Favors Sovereign Bankruptcy Proceedings?
Neither sovereign countries nor private-sector investors have been
clamoring for a sovereign country bankruptcy law. If anything, sovereign
debtors have shunned previous plans--such as preapproved credit lines
and contingency clauses in bonds stipulating steps to be taken in case
of default--to signal to markets that their countries had responsible
policies. Countries with emerging markets have regarded such devices as
an indication of financial weakness and feared that adopting them would
induce creditors to exact an interest premium on loans. Sovereign
debtors might well have a similar reaction to the IMF's proposal.
Nonetheless, the proposal has some support among academies.
Jeffrey Sachs, now at Columbia University, has long advocated a
universal bankruptcy law (Sachs 1995). In 1995 he made the ease for
giving insolvent countries the same protection from creditors as
insolvent firms. His sympathies were with the sovereign debtors, not the
creditors. Sachs's views were rejected in the report of an official
working group issued after the Mexican crisis of 1994-95. That report,
which received the endorsement of the major industrialized countries,
favored debt workouts rather than massive official bailouts and stressed
the importance of market discipline (Group of 10 1996).
In a paper that Sachs prepared for a Brookings conference in 2001
on debt restructuring, he relegated the bankruptcy court proposal to the
periphery of his argument. He was more concerned with using grants and
debt forgiveness to facilitate a greater flow of resources from richer
countries to heavily indebted poorer countries (Sachs 2002).
Initially, Kenneth Rogoff (1999) offered a skeptical perspective on
sovereign bankruptcy proceedings. He differentiated between a domestic
bankruptcy court, which can seize physical assets and fire a
company's board of directors, and an international bankruptey
court, which is unlikely to enter a debtor country and seize physical
assets, much less fire the country's government. For Rogoff,
municipal government bankruptcies, in which outside boards run the
city's day-today finances, are no more convincing examples for
sovereign government bankruptcies. Federal governments, in his view,
would not tolerate a comparable level of outside interference. Rogoff
concluded that the main problem with an international bankruptcy court
is that it could not enforce its decrees in debtor countries. Moreover,
in the event of a default, if lenders could not turn to national courts,
which would be superseded by an international court, the volume of
lending would diminish.
When Rogoff was appointed director of research at the IMF, his
position on a bankruptcy law for sovereign debtors changed. In his June
28, 2002, remarks on the Joseph Stiglitz book, Globalization and Its
Discontents, Rogoff reversed himself. He stated, "there is a need
for a dramatic change in how we handle situations where countries go
bankrupt." He saluted Krneger for having "forcefully advocated
a far-reaching IMF proposal." He taunted Stiglitz for having first
sharply "criticized the whole idea" at a Davos panel in
February and later taken credit "as having been the one to strongly
advance it first" (Rogoff 2002).
Michelle White of the University of California at San Diego believes that a bankruptcy court or some equivalent may be needed to
rein in rogue creditors, provide private-sector financing that has
seniority over earlier claims against countries during debt
restructuring, and compel dissenting groups of creditors to accept a
restructuring plan. She cautions, however, that such a procedure may
"dry up the sovereign bond market completely" (White 2002:
316).
Who Opposes Sovereign Bankruptcy Procedures?
The opponents of the IMF's proposal include former as well as
present government officials and academics. Their criticisms and
alternative recommendations vary. In the concluding section, I note the
opposition of spokesmen for international investors and debtor
countries.
Edwin Truman, a former Federal Reserve and Treasury Department
official, is entirely opposed to bankruptcy proceedings, as he made
clear in a speech in New York on December 10, 2001 (Crooks 2001). He
believes that there is no consensus among policymakers and commentators
to make a sovereign bankruptcy proceeding politically feasible. (6) He
faults payments standstills, which, in his view, are likely to worsen
crises. Instead of focusing on debtor insolvency, as does a sovereign
bankruptcy procedure, he favors the provision of adequate liquidity to
the world financial system. He proposes a new fund for the IMF to be
raised by an annual fee of 0.1 percent on international investment until
it reaches a value of, say, $300 billion. Countries in financial
difficulties could draw on the fund. In effect, Truman's approach
is a better financed continuation of the IMF's previous response to
financial crises, possibly including bailouts.
In opposition to the tax that Truman advocates, Charles Dallara,
managing director of the Institute of International Finance, which
represents international banks and other investors, disputes the need to
raise more resources for the IMF (Crooks 2001).
The U.S. Treasury Department's response to the IMF proposal
was negative. John Taylor, under secretary of the Treasury for
international affairs, told the congressional Joint Economic Committee
that a decentralized approach that relies on collective action clauses
would be superior to the proposal (Taylor 2002a). He elaborated on that
approach in a subsequent speech (Taylor 2002b). It would involve
adoption by sovereign debtors and their creditors of a majority-action
clause to bind all creditors to an agreement between the country and the
creditor representatives. A second clause on procedures would stipulate
that each class of creditors would have its own representative and would
require the debtor to provide the creditor representatives with
necessary data. Each creditor representative on instruction by a
specified fraction of creditors would have the exclusive right to
initiate litigation. A third clause would allow deferral of debt
payments and bar litigation for long enough to permit creditors to
choose their representative. The three clauses would be included in bank
and bond debt instruments. Any country seeking an IMF loan would have to
include those clauses in its debt instruments. (7) The IMF could also
promote use of the clauses by lowering the charge for its loans for
countries that did so. (8)
The Joint Economic Committee of the U.S. Congress also rejected a
new role for the IMF in supervising sovereign bankruptcies. One
explanation for the launch of the bankruptcy court proposal has been
offered by Chairman Jim Saxton (R-N.J.) who said, "I can't
help thinking that its default supervision proposal would have the
effect of compensating the IMF for the reduction in its influence
arising from a more restricted policy toward international
bailouts" (Joint Economic Committee 2002). The JEC instead
supported Tailor's decentralized approach. It also released a study
by Adam Lerrick and Allan Meltzer (2002) of Carnegie Mellon University further documenting how the private sector can resolve bankruptcy
without a formal court.
The study shows how the absence of majority action clauses in
outstanding debt can easily be remedied. Exchange offers containing
majority action clauses could be swapped for old debt. To execute those
offers, Lerrick and Meltzer advocate a series of auctions. To encourage
participation in the exchange offers, exit consent amendments could be
used. Those amendments added to the terms of old instruments destroy the
value of any instruments held by holdouts. When a bond issue includes
the amendment, voted by a supermajority of holders, it becomes binding
on the remaining holders.
As Lerrick and Meltzer note, the market is familiar with exchange
offers. In the period before Argentina defaulted in December 2001, it
made extensive use of exchange offers to fulfill a condition the IMF
attached to the $40 billion loan Argentina obtained in 2000 from a
consortium of donors, including the IMF. The condition was to implement
a voluntary, market-based operation to improve the country's debt
profile. The technique Argentina adopted was an exchange offer of debt
instruments for existing maturing bonds, without the use of exit consent
agreements. The new debt instruments provided for longer maturities and
higher interest rates than did the original bonds. In 2000 and 2001,
Argentina made exchange offers to foreign bondholders, presumably after
consultation with investment advisers on what the market would accept.
However reluctantly, Argentina's bondholders accepted the exchange.
Nominally the exchange offer improved the terms of existing bonds, but
the market rating of the bonds imposed substantial losses on the
bondholders. (9)
Lerrick and Meltzer show how debt contracts can replicate the
protections of a sovereign bankruptcy court. A trust indenture, for
example, provides for a trustee to control all action against the
sovereign on behalf of all bondholders. In order to continue debt
service in a liquidity crisis, the equivalent of debtor-in-possession
financing can be arranged by subordinating outstanding claims to interim
lenders. The authors dispute the IMF's contentions that it is
difficult to coordinate increasing numbers of anonymous creditors
holding a great variety of debt instruments and that holdout creditors
are likely to sue a country. (10) As they note, a creditors'
committee was formed in November 2001 before Argentina defaulted, which
indicates that it is not so difficult to access a broad spectrum of
investors in such situations. Lerrick and Meltzer also argue that their
proposal for exchange offers and exit consent agreements preclude the
ability to sue and extract preferential treatment by holdouts. (11)
Peter Kenen of Princeton University dissents from the IMF proposals
and the Taylor position on the ground that they
fall short of resolving the problem encountered during the Asian
crisis, which involved the liquidation of short-term foreign claims
on Asian banks and firms, rather than claims on Asian
governments.... Suspension of payments and stays of litigation may
be required by all debt-related crises, not merely those requiring
restructurings of sovereign debt [Kenen 2002: 38-39].
Kenen would reinforce Taylor's proposals by two further
measures: he would include collective action clauses in all standardized
debt contracts of both the private sector and governments and a 90-day
rollover option in all standardized debt contracts. He would require
debtors to exercise that option if a country's government made a
formal finding that the country faced a financial emergency. Coverage of
private sector debt would be limited to debts denominated in foreign
currency.
The advantage of including private debt, according to Kenen, is
that it might obviate the need to impose exchange controls. Under the
IMF plan, if a government imposed exchange controls, the private sector
might have to suspend debt payments, but the IMF would sanction a stay
of litigation against private sector debtors only if a country faced a
sovereign debt problem. Kenen believes that his plan avoids this problem
but admits that private sector suspension of debt payments, not backed
by exchange controls, might motivate debtors to buy foreign currency
before the end of the 90-day rollover period to provide the means to
resume debt payments after the end of the period.
Because it will take years to amend the Fund's Articles of
Agreement and the proposal is apt to provoke opposition from the private
sector, lacks Treasury support, and may be opposed by some emerging
market countries, Kenen (2002: 42) favors his own comprehensive
contractual approach as "the most expeditions second-best way to
go."
Jeremy Bulow (2002) of Stanford University sets the right
priorities for dealing with the problem of sovereign debt: first,
control the extent of borrowing by sovereigns, and, second, downgrade
the need for bankruptcy procedures. Bulow regards emerging market
economies as being prone to create budget deficits owing to corruption
by many of their policymakers and their willingness to borrow for
socially inefficient projects. The sovereign has an incentive to default
not because of inability to pay but unwillingness to pay. Bulow would
limit borrowing by sovereigns to their own legal jurisdictions rather
than allow them to issue debt in major foreign centers. The problem with
a bankruptcy court, Bulow contends, is that it would facilitate default
and debt restructuring. However, the capital market for loans to
emerging market economies would shrink as a result. In Bulow's
view, that is a desirable outcome.
Andrei Schleifer (2003) shares Bulow's doubts that the debt
market will survive under the IMF's bankruptcy arrangement for
sovereigns. Unlike domestic bankruptcy laws, he notes, which are
required to operate "in the best interests of the creditors,"
the IMF fails this test. Unlike Bulow, however, Schleifer would deplore the demise of the sovereign debt market.
Changing the Culture of Debt-Based Development
The opposition to the IMF's original and modified proposals is
varied and substantive. Even apart from the chorus of dissent, there is
reason to believe that the IMF will not succeed in enacting its unwieldy
and overly complex program. It would take years for the membership to
adopt the changes set forth in the program or for the Fund to be in a
position to amend its articles. It is doubtful that the Fund will be
able to convince the U.S. Treasury to vote for an amendment, which
requires the consent of 85 percent of the Fund's shareholders. The
U.S. vote is more than 17 percent of the total.
There are serious challenges to at least three of the premises on
which the proposal for a bankruptcy court is based:
1. It is difficult to assemble committees of creditors who hold
bearer bonds of various maturities. Today, all bonds are registered so
there is no problem in identifying holders and organizing committees of
homogeneous claimants.
2. A rogue creditor poses a threat to the successful conclusion of
a restructuring. As Nouriel Roubini (2002: 329) has remarked:
"Rogue creditors do not jeopardize file completion of an exchange
offer; their incentive to start litigation is triggered by a successful
offer, not a tailed one. Only after a majority of creditors have
accepted a deal does a rogue have the incentive to obtain a full
claim." (12)
3. Official intervention is needed to facilitate restructuring.
Market solutions already exist and have been used to renegotiate the
outstanding debt of troubled emerging sovereign debtors. IMF
intervention is a solution to a problem that does not exist.
At stake if the IMF proposal for a sovereign bankruptcy procedure
or any of its variants is implemented is that investors will view the
new conditions with a jaundiced eye and retreat from lending to emerging
market countries. Indeed, the borrowers are well aware of this pitfall.
That is the message that both creditors and debtors have expressed in
response. Charles Dallara, a spokesman for international banks and other
investors, contends that various types of contractual provisions for
international bonds will enable orderly restructuring to proceed without
the need for the IMF to oversee a country's debt restructuring.
At recent IMF-World Bank meetings, former Brazilian finance
minister Pedro Malan said that he was unconvinced that the benefits of
statutory debt restructuring would be greater than the potential costs.
Mexico has expressed similar doubts. The costs to which Malan referred
are higher interest rates that lenders will require if either the
contractual or file statutory approaches ever materialized (Phillips
2002a, 2002b, 2002c; Andrews 2002).
That might not be such a deplorable result. Lenders have not
exercised due diligence in extending loans to those countries, and the
IMF has fostered a culture that encourages borrowing not only from
creditors in the world capital market but also from the international
financial institutions. Although the objective of such institutions has
been to promote development, looking back on what that culture has
achieved over the past 50 years, one has to conclude that their record
is unimpressive. Perhaps the time has arrived to abandon debt-based
development; to encourage the conversion of debt to equity; to set
countries on a different path than one that leads to unsustainable debt,
crises, and debt restructuring; and to rely on equity investment for
development.
(1) It is noteworthy that the first reference to consultation with
market participants in an International Monetary Fund document on
sovereign debt restructuring appears in the November 27, 2002, paper for
a meeting in April 2003 to consider an initial draft of the text of the
amendment to the Fund's Articles of Agreement (IMF 2002: 3).
(2) Chapter 11 allows companies to continue operating and to repay
creditors' claims from future earnings rather than from the
proceeds of liquidating their assets. There is a stay on litigation
against the company that was initiated before bankruptcy filing and on
litigation after the filing. Companies may obtain new
loans--debtor-in-possession financing that are senior to all claims that
existed before the filing, For four months after the filing, managers
have an exclusive right to propose a reorganization plan that specifies
how the claims of each class of creditors will be settled. If the
bankruptcy judge ends the period for the managers' proposal,
creditors may then offer their own reorganization plan. Each class of
creditors must approve the final plan by two-thirds of the amount
involved and a majority of the number of claims. When no reorganization
plan is adopted, the judge may order liquidation of the company under
Chapter 7. Otherwise. the judge may adopt the failed reorganization plan
under the procedure known as "cram down," Chapter 9 applies
only to cities and other entities that are state creations. A city may
file for bankruptcy only after obtaining permission from the state. It
must be insolvent and unable to pay ongoing debts. Public officials may
not be replaced, as managers may be under Chapter 11. The former have
the exclusive right to offer a reorganization plan but a committee of
creditors may negotiate with public officials. In theory the judge may
offer his own restructuring plan but it has never happened. The voting
procedure on a plan is similar to that in Chapter 11 (White 2002:
293-97), Chapter 7 permits consumers and businesses to be freed of most
of their unsecured debts. Chapter 13 requires debtors to propose a plan
to pay off at least some debt over three to five years.
(3) Litigation has been a feature of sovereign defaults for
centuries, but there is no evidence that restructuring has been delayed
or disrupted as a result.
(4) A voluntary market-based way of achieving this end is described
below.
(5) In late March 2003, at a closed-door meeting at the Harvard
Business School, Krueger conceded that the IMF proposal, although not
dead. had little political support to move forward (Blustein 2003).
(6) In discussing the three papers presented at the Brookings 2001
conference on an international bankruptcy court, Truman (2002: 342)
reiterates his view that it is not now feasible "because the
intellectual and political foundations have not yet been laid." The
reasons are (1) no consensus exists on whether such an institution
should seek to maximize the return to creditors or to give debtors a
fresh start and (2) the world is not ready to give a supranational body
the right to make such judgments.
(7) The legal framework outlined by Taylor Was endorsed by the
finance ministers of the Group of Seven industrial countries at a
meeting in Washington at the end of September 2002 (Andrews 2002).
Earlier that month the Treasury presented the plan to a gathering of
senior economic officials from the Group of Seven, large private
investors, and representatives from several nonindustrial countries
(Phillips 2002c).
(8) An observer might have concluded that Treasury opposition to
the Krueger proposal effectively ended its prospects. Such a conclusion
was spiked by a statement made by U.S. Secretary Paul O'Neill at
the International Monetary and Financial Committee meeting of the IMF on
September 28, 2002: "The United States strongly welcomes the
significant progress being made on the contractual approach to sovereign
debtor restructuring. We are particularly encouraged by the broad
support expressed by both borrowers and creditors for the implementation
of this approach." However, he also said, "We strongly support
the continued pursuit of the statutory approach." Does the Treasury
favor both approaches? More dubious is O'Neill's claim that
both borrowers and creditors have given broad support for these
approaches. See contrary statements by these parties in the conclusion.
(9) Before the default, further exchange offers were expected in
2002 but were never made. Two suits have been filed against
Argentina--one by German investors, the other by Americans seeking class
action certification. Four other suits have been filed for small
amounts. Argentina is defending all.
(10) The reason that there is no obstacle to organizing creditors
is that these days all bonds are registered. The debtor or fiscal agent
who distributes interest can distribute a note to creditors stating that
they are all invited to a meeting that will be held on a designated
date. In the same way, creditors can organize themselves whether in a
corporate or a sovereign context.
(11) In a 2001 paper, Lerrick and Meltzer proposed an approach to
debt restructuring quite different from their 2002 proposal. The earlier
approach required a debtor to declare default that would prompt the IMF
to provide a stand-by line of credit. The line of credit would allow any
creditor to sell its defaulted claim for a fixed cash price that the IMF
would set--an official floor of support-significantly below the
debt's anticipated restructured value during a brief period. During
this period, the country would offer to restructure its debt through an
exchange for new bonds, fixing a maximum write-down. Negotations between
the debtor and creditors during the restructuring period would
presumably set the final restructured value above the official floor of
support (see Lerrick and Meltzer 2001). The authors promote this
approach as a way of minimizing the IMF's outlays for rescuing a
troubled sovereign debtor. The approach is objectionable, however, for
IMF intrusion into a matter that the market is fully competent to solve,
as the authors' 2002 proposal demonstrates.
(12) I fail to see why rogue creditors who, after all, demand only
fulfillment of the terms of a contract, are excoriated in the
literature.
References
Andrews, E. L. (2002) "World Financial Officials Back New Debt
Framework." New York Times, 29 September: A6.
--(2002) "Big Banks Step Up Efforts Against IMF Debt Relief
Plan." New York Times, 19 December.
Blustein, P. (2003) "'Bankruptcy' System for Nations
Fails to Draw Support." Washington Post, 2 April: A14.
Bulow, J. (2002) "First World Governments and Third World
Debt." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 229-55.
Crooks, E. (2001) "IMF 'Needs a Cash Fund' for
Rescuing Crisis-hit Countries." Financial Times, 12 December: 11.
Group of 10 (1996) "The Resolution of Sovereign Liquidity
Crises: A Report to the Ministers and Governors." Washington:
International Monetary Fund.
International Monetary Fund (2002) "The Design of the
Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism-Further Considerations."
Prepared by the Legal and Policy Development and Review Departments.
Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States (2002)
"IMF Sovereign Bankruptcy Supervision Is Unnecessary: New Analysis
Rejects More IMF Mission Creep." Press Release, Washington, 19
April.
Kenen, P. B. (2002) "The International Financial Architecture:
Old Issues and New Initiatives." International Finance 5 (1)
(Spring) 23-15.
Krueger, A. (2001a) "International Financial Architecture for
2002: A New Approach to Sovereign Debt Restructuring." Address at
the American Enterprise Institute, 26 November
(www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/112601.htm).
--(2001b) "A New Approach to Sovereign Debt
Restructuring." Address at the Indian Council for Ressearch on
International Economic Relations. Delhi, India, 20 December
(www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/122001.htm).
--(2002a) "Transcript of a Teleconference on Sovereign Debt
Restructuring Mechanism with Washington-based Journalists and First
Deputy Managing Director, Anne Krneger." International Monetary
Fund, 1 April (www.imf.org/external/np/tr/200/tr020401.htm).
--(2002b) "New Approaches to Sovereign Debt Restructuring: An
Update on Our Thinking." Address to the Institute for International
Economics, 1 April (www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2002/040102.htm).
Lerrick, A., and Meltzer, A. H. (2001) "Beyond IMF Bailouts:
Default without Disruption." Carnegie Mellon Gailliot Center for
Public Policy (May).
--(2002) "Sovereign Default: The Private Sector Can Resolve
Bankruptcy without a Formal Court." Quarterly International
Economics Report, Carnegie Mellon Gailliot Center for Public Policy
(April).
Phillips, M. M. (2002a) "Developing Nations Are Reading the
Fine Print." New York Times, 29 April.
--(2002b) "Support Builds for Plan to Ease Debt Loads of
Developing Nations." New York Times, 17 September.
--(2002c) "U.S. Presses Bid for Escape Clause in Some
Bonds." Wall Street Journal, 26 September.
Rogoff, K. (1999) "International Institutions for Reducing
Financial Instability." National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 7265 (July).
--(2002) "Introductory Remarks to Discussion with Joseph
Stiglitz on Globalization and its Discontents," International
Monetary Fund, 28 June. Roubini, N. (2002) "Do We Need a New
Bankruptcy Regime?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:
321-33.
Sachs, J. (1995) "Do We Need an International Leader of the
Last Resort?" The Frank D. Graham Lecture delivered at Princeton
University.
--(2002) "Resolving the Debt Crisis of Low-Income
Countries." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 257-86.
Schleifer, A. (2003) "Will the Government Debt Market
Survive?" NBER Working Paper 9493.
Taylor, J. B. (2002a) "Grants and Sovereign Debt
Restructuring: Two Key Elements of a Reform Agenda for the International
Financial Institutions." Testimony before the Joint Economic
Committee of Congress, 14 February
(www.house.gov/jec/hearings/taylor.pdf).
--(2002b) "Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A U.S.
Perspective." Address to the Institute for International Economics,
2 April (www.treas.gov/press/releases/po2056.htm).
Truman, E. M. (2002) "Debt Restructuring: Evolution or
Revolution." Brookings Papers" on Economic Activity 1: 341-16.
White, M. J, (2002) "Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need
Bankruptcy?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 287-316.
Anna J. Schwartz is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.