Do Think Tanks Matter? Assessing the Impact of Public Policy Institutes.
Steelman, Aaron
Donald E. Abelson Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press,
2002, 246 pp.
According to a recent estimate, there are more than 3,000
public-policy institutes--or "think tanks"--around the globe.
Yet the literature on these organizations is relatively sparse. One
reason, perhaps, is the youth of most think tanks. In 1970, for
instance, the American Enterprise Institute (AEI), the Brookings
Institution, and the Hoover Institution were doing important work. But
the second and third generations of American think tanks--for instance,
the Cato Institute, the Heritage Foundation, the Manhattan Institute,
the Progressive Policy Institute, and countless state-based groups--have
been formed in just the past few decades. One would expect, then, a lag
in scholarship. After all, one can't write about the think tank
"phenomenon" until that phenomenon has actually taken place.
In Do Think Tanks Matter? Assessing the Impact of Public Policy
Institutes., Donald Abelson, a political scientist at the University of
Western Ontario, attempts to measure the influence of American and
Canadian think tanks. This is a more difficult undertaking than it might
sound. Indeed, in his 1993 book The Transformation of American Politics:
The New Washington and the Rise of Think Tanks, David Ricci deemed such
a project nearly impossible: "When institutes like Brookings and
AEI promote ideas, they can never be sure what effect those intangible
entities will have on other Washingtonians, no matter how suggestible.
While investigating the subject, I looked closely at what think tanks
are doing, from books to seminars to briefings to breakfast meetings. I
also asked fellows and managers to tell me what results they thought
their activities would produce. The more I saw and heard, the more I
understood that no one can know precisely what is happening in this
drama." Ultimately, Abelson comes to much the same conclusion.
While that may be depressing to scholars interested in the topic--and to
Abelson himself--this book still yields many interesting observations
about the nature of think tanks and the policymaking process more
generally.
Abelson attempts to distinguish his own conceptual framework from
two classic theories of how political power is wielded: elite theory and
pluralist theory. Elite theory, advanced by William Domhoff, Thomas Dye,
and others, posits that the political system is dominated by a select
group of individuals and organizations with common goals. Usually, elite
theorists consider those goals to include the maintenance of capitalism
tempered by a moderate level of government regulation and an
intermittently interventionist foreign policy, driven not by principle
but self-interest. Elite theory "allows scholars to identify the
close ties between those who fund think tanks and the individuals who
operate them," Abelson writes. But it is based on the faulty
assumption "that with the right connections think tanks can and
will be able to influence public policy." How this is achieved is
not adequately explained by elite theory, Abelson argues.
Pluralist theory, which is perhaps most closely identified with the
work of David Truman and Robert Dahl, comes closer to the mark,
according to Abelson, but it is still found wanting. Think tanks may
indeed compete for influence, alongside trade unions, environmental
groups, and other nongovernmental organizations, as pluralist theorists
argue. But this fails to take into account think tanks' privileged
status. Think tanks, Abelson argues, "possess unique attributes
that allow them to stand out," among which are "expertise and
close ties to policymakers."
Instead, he calls for an "institutionalist" approach. It
holds that "not only do think tanks vary enormously in terms of the
resources they have at their disposal, but they assign different
priorities to participating at various stages of the policy cycle,"
Abelson writes. "This becomes particularly clear in comparing how
think tanks function in different political systems. It also becomes
important in interpreting data such as media citations and testimony
before legislative committees that can be used to evaluate think tank
performance."
Abelson is clearly building on the work of John Kingdon, who has
written much about the importance of agenda setting in American
politics. According to Kingdon, think tanks may often be unable to
influence the final choice made by policymakers, but they can do much to
set--and perhaps expand the limits of respectable debate. This, in turn,
leads to the consideration of various alternatives that may not have
been on the agenda previously.
Consider, for instance, one of the most popular ways of determining
the relative influence of think tanks: the amount of media citations
they garner. Many think tanks that advance limited-government views do
well on this measure. Does this mean, then, that the state is about to
whither? Far from it. The federal government continues to play an
extensive role in the economic and social lives of Americans. But it
does show that free-market ideas are now on the agenda. Proposals that
once seemed radical or even fanciful--such as school vouchers and
pension reform--have become viable policy alternatives.
One might take Abelson to task for not considering more fully a
third framework that is often mentioned in the same breath as elite
theory and pluralist theory--state theory. It's true that state
theory was unfashionable for many years, an idea that seemed applicable
only" to totalitarian regimes, not Western democratic governments.
But in the past 20 years, due largely to the work of Theda Skocpol,
state theory has experienced somewhat of a renaissance. The basic
argument is that while the public can indeed impose some restraint on
the actions of the bureaucracy and elected officials, the state retains
a degree of autonomy and works according to its own logic. State theory
can help explain the seeming anomalous eases of former think-tank
staffers who enter government pledging to work for a certain set of
ideas and then enacting policies that are quite different. In some
eases, these individuals have been co-opted by the system; in others,
they are genuinely doing their best to reach their goal, however slowly
or circuitously. But either way, the state itself is an important actor.
Abelson's explanation of why U.S. think tanks seem to be more
influential than Canadian think tanks is twofold. First, there are
differences in political structures. "With a government based on
separate branches sharing power, a party system in which members of
Congress are free to vote as they wish, and a growing number of
presidential candidates trying to develop new ideas, [American] think
tanks have multiple opportunities to shape public opinion and public
policy," Abelson writes. Canada's parliamentary system, in
contrast, provides fewer such opportunities. Second, and more important,
Abelson contends, is that Canadian think tanks have fewer
resources--both financial and human--than America's top policy
institutes. He says that cultural differences may explain why Canadian
philanthropic organizations and corporations are less likely to support
public-policy research than are similar groups in the United States. But
this argument is vague and not compelling.
As noted earlier, Abelson concludes on a somewhat pessimistic note.
He does not really have an answer to the question posed in the title of
his book. "We cannot, for instance, conclude that think tanks have
influence 20 percent or 50 percent of the time. We cannot even say for
certain how much impact specific think tanks have had at particular
stages of policy debates or whom exactly they have influenced. At best,
by assessing their involvement in specific policy areas, we can obtain a
better sense of how relevant or irrelevant they were," Abelson
writes. He may know the reader will find this statement unsatisfying and
anti-climactic. If so, he is right. But what is even more disappointing
is that such a cautious conclusion may be the best that we can expect.
Policymaking, as has been noted so often before, is a messy process--one
that social scientists have done much to explain but will probably never
fully understand.
(1) The views expressed are the author's and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
Aaron Steelman
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond (1)