Policy change in flat pensions: comparing Canada and the UK.
Beland, Daniel ; Waddan, Alex
Much has been written about pension reform in advanced industrial
countries. A central aspect of this discussion concerns the assessment
of the scope and nature of policy change currently witnessed within the
modern public pension systems created during the postwar era (Marier
2008; Myles and Pierson 2001; Weaver 2010). The following article
explores the issue of policy change in relationship to the flat-rate
pensions created in the UK and Canada in the years following the end of
World War II. Taking a long-term historical perspective on the
development of these flat pensions and drawing on the recent policy
literature on incremental and transformative change (Hacker 2004;
Streeck and Thelen 2005), this article suggests that, over time, the UK
flat pension (Basic State Pension) has witnessed more dramatic changes
than its Canadian counterpart and that the greater mobilization of
beneficiaries defending the flat pension program in Canada helps explain
this key difference between the two countries. Overall, this article
contributes to the ongoing debate on incremental change by exploring how
subtle policy alterations may or may not lead to transformative change
over time. The article also adds to the literature on pensions by
suggesting that contributory pensions such as the UK Basic State Pension
(BSP) are not necessarily more politically resilient than universal,
non-contributory flat pensions like Canada's Old Age Security
(OAS).
The article begins with a brief general discussion about the
relationship between old-age pensions and policy change, before
exploring the UK and Canadian cases and drawing general lessons about
the evolution of flat pensions in these two countries. Of particular
interest are policy changes that affect the eligibility criteria for the
public pension and alterations to the level of benefit. With regard to
the former, relevant changes would include modifications to the
qualifying number of contributory years needed to receive a pension or a
redefinition of what counts as a contributory year. In addition, raising
or lowering the retirement age, either to reflect changing concepts of
gender equality or expectations about life expectancy, could have
important potential implications for eligibility. Alterations to the
level of benefit could be straightforward decisions to raise or lower
payments, but also include moves to index, or re-index, benefits to
alternative measures of increases in the cost-of-living. It is also
important to investigate whether and how benefits are subject to
taxation.
Pension reform and policy change
Public pension policy is replete with demands that compete for
priority. The obvious primary function of a state-organized pension
system is to provide income support for seniors, but this does not in
itself determine how generous pensions should be. For the state,
providing for retirees has to be set against controlling aggregate
costs. Furthermore, governments must decide how to balance the desire to
provide generous benefits against concerns about the incentive effects
of encouraging or discouraging people from saving for their own
retirement through their working lives. A generous universal benefit
might have low disincentive effects but it is likely to be expensive. A
greater reliance on income or means testing will reduce overall cost but
will increase disincentive effects (Bozio, Crawford and Tetlow 2010).
Given these complex issues and the inherent difficulties in
satisfactorily resolving these policy trade-offs, it is unsurprising
that in recent decades UK and Canadian governments, with pension systems
that incorporate both flat and income- or means-tested elements, have
consistently amended their pension policies in attempts to reform
schemes that were initially established in the aftermath of World War
II. In this context, and taking into account the balance between
universality and income or means tests, and the episodes of retrenchment
and expansion, the best manner in which to understand pension policy in
the UK and Canada is to take a historical perspective, which allows for
assessing which of the changes that have been enacted have had the
greatest impact, and which have turned out to be less significant than
first anticipated.
As is outlined below, both the UK and Canada created flat-rate
pension benefits--the BSP in the UK and OAS in Canada--that have
remained at the center of government pension provision since the early
post-war era. Pension policy in these two countries has not been marked
by long periods of institutional stability, but neither have there been
regular and obvious moments of path departing change. Rather,
policymakers have enacted apparently incremental changes, some of which
have nonetheless produced significant policy transformation over time.
Therefore, a thorough understanding of pension policy change requires a
proper examination of changes that may appear to be un-dramatic, and
which may indeed be presented as such by political actors anxious to
avoid controversy, but which can have important long-term impacts
(Hacker 2004; Streeck and Thelen 2005).
Tracking policy development over an extended period also allows
observers to judge which features of the respective systems in the UK
and Canada have proved to be the most durable and resistant to change,
and which features have proved less resilient. Here, the comparison
between our two cases is potentially instructive. Why was the Thatcher
government able to introduce a change to the method of indexation of the
BSP, whereas when Prime Minister Mulroney attempted something similar
with respect to the OAS in Canada, he was forced to retreat in the face
of strong opposition? In this context, we must examine which factors
determine the institutional resilience of particular programs. What
policy legacies have resulted from previous patterns of development and,
importantly, how have these shaped the public's perception of their
stake in the program? Is pension policy closely watched by groups able
to mobilize protest if the beneficiaries of existing arrangements are
threatened (Beland and Marier 2006; Marier 2008)?
As Andrea Campbell (2003) has suggested in her analysis of the
United States, the political mobilization of retirees is a potent
explanation of policy development. Interestingly, however, the Canadian
case concerns mobilization over a non-contributory, universal flat
pension scheme, which is different than the Bismarckian social insurance
model in place in the United States, as well as in continental Europe.
According to scholars like John Myles and Paul Pierson (2001),
contributory pension schemes are especially resilient politically, in
part because they create a sense of entitlement derived from individual
contributions. In this context, since the BSP is a contributory scheme,
one would expect that it would prove less vulnerable to cutbacks than
OAS, which is not "earned" through payroll contributions.
A historical perspective also provides insight into which reforms
have proved to have longevity. In the UK, for example, governments have
at different times made apparently significant reforms aimed at
introducing an earnings-related social insurance style benefit, to sit
alongside the BSP. For all the effort put into establishing those
schemes, however, they have failed to take root. (1)
It is also important to recognize that policy changes sometimes do
not have as big of an impact as might have been expected. For example,
in 1989, a policy of fiscal "clawback" was instituted in
Canada to reclaim some OAS benefits through the tax system from seniors
with high incomes. This was important in principle but did not prevent
the vast majority of eligible Canadians from keeping their full OAS
pension (Beland and Myles 2005).
Finally, taking a long-term perspective also enables us to assess
whether there has been a constant direction to reform efforts. So, for
example, have the universalistic aspects of state pension policy in the
UK and Canada been consistently either expanded or retrenched? Or have
policy initiatives been both pushed and pulled following alternative
agendas, with the consequence that there have been moments of both
retrenchment and expansion?
As illustrated below, the evidence suggests that, in both
countries, pension policy reform efforts have followed contradictory
trajectories, but overall, despite being a non-contributory scheme, OAS
has proved more resilient than BSP, which is a reality that challenges
the above-mentioned assumption that contributory schemes are more
resistant to restructuring than non-contributory ones (Myles and Pierson
2001).
The UK
Over the last 60 years, pension provision in the UK has evolved
into a complex array of state and private arrangements. (2) Underlying
state provision is the BSP, established by the post-war Labour
government, modelled to some extent on the recommendations contained in
the 1942 Beveridge Report (Beveridge 1942). A flat-rate pension, the BSP
is something of a hybrid between a universal and a contributory scheme.
The fact that individuals are only eligible for the full BSP in
retirement if they have an appropriate contributory record through
paying National Insurance (NI) contributions out of their payroll (or
performing activities recognised as a substitute for contributions)
means that it is distinct from the Canadian OAS, which is granted to all
on the basis of residency in the country. Contributions towards the BSP
are measured in years of payment rather than the amount paid, with the
original requirement being 44 years of contribution for men and 40 years
for women. Thus, the BSP is not universal, as many people reach
retirement age without making the requisite contributions to receive the
full BSP. But the scheme is compulsory: individuals cannot opt out of
paying NI, and seniors who have made some contributions throughout their
working age do receive BSP benefits on a sliding scale. Also, although
contributory, the BSP is distinct from a Bismarckian social insurance
scheme; its flat-rate payment means it does not replace past earnings in
a manner reflecting previous differentials in earnings (Barr 2004: 31).
The BSP has been reformed in ways that constitute both retrenchment
and expansion of the program, but since 1948, it has been a constant
feature in the changing landscape of UK pension policy. Another
consistent feature of state pensions has been the reliance on
means-tested top-ups for seniors left with inadequate income by the BSP
and with minimal other sources of income. In addition, the UK has
experimented with social insurance style pension benefits by putting in
place different earnings-related schemes, but none of these has passed
the test of longevity. Further to state pension benefits, the UK
witnessed the growing availability of pensions in the private sector
through occupational schemes and private pension plans.
Implementing Beveridge
William Beveridge (1879-1963) was the intellectual founder of
post-war British social policy, but when examining how far his blueprint
for welfare state development was put in place (Beveridge 1942), we
should remember that many social welfare programs were competing for
scarce funds in an austere post war fiscal environment (Timmins 1996).
In turn, this limited how generous any pension settlement could be and
left a lasting legacy affecting the development of UK pension
arrangements.
In the end, the Labour government (1945-1951) only followed some of
Beveridge's advice. The BSP was established as a contributory
scheme based on NI contributions paid out at a flat rate. But while
Beveridge had called for payment of the full pension to be delayed for
twenty years to build an actuarially sound reserve fund of
contributions, the government deemed that politically impossible and the
BSP was immediately paid out to men aged 65 and over and women aged 60
and over. Yet, reflecting the limited fiscal resources available in the
late 1940s and also that the aim was only ever to offer a parsimonious
benefit, the BSP was paid at a level "below the measly estimated
level of subsistence" (Blackburn 2002: 58). As a consequence, since
the 1940s, non-contributory means-tested payments to supplement the BSP
have played a "key role" in helping low-income seniors in the
UK (Bozio, Crawford and Tetlow 2010: 51).
A significant consideration during the postwar years was the
increasing number of workers with occupational pensions. In 1956, about
a third of workers were enrolled in occupational pension schemes, rising
to over 50% by 1967, partially reflecting a tight labour market that
made employers aware of the need to attract "good" employees
(Pemberton 2006). Nevertheless, many remained reliant solely on the
state for income in retirement. This produced pressure to introduce a
state-run earnings related supplement to the BSP for those not in
occupational or private schemes. A graduated retirement benefit was
introduced in 1961 but this never gained traction (Bozio, Crawford and
Tetlow 2010: 9); in 1975, the State Earnings Related Pensions Scheme
(SERPS), to be implemented in 1978, was established. Also in 1975, a
potentially important change was made to the calculation of the BSP,
when the Labour government formally linked the level of benefits with
the higher of the rate of price inflation or the growth in average
wages. The BSP had remained structurally unchanged prior to this time
with payments raised on an ad hoc basis, although generally these
increases had at least kept up with the growth in average earnings and
had exceeded the rate of inflation. In July 1948, measured in 2011
sterling, the full BSP stood at 38.48 [pounds sterling] per week. This
had reached 85.29 [pounds sterling] by November 1975 (Department of Work
and Pensions 2012: 14). In this context, the significance of the change
made in 1975 was perhaps only properly illustrated when the method of
indexation was again changed by the Thatcher government.
Downsizing the state pension
In 1980, in a move that aroused surprisingly little opposition
given its significance, the indexing of the BSP was altered (Blackburn
2002: 285-6). It was now only to rise in line with inflation rather than
with that measure or earnings; this meant that, without any ad hoc
increases in prospect, its replacement rate value would decline
significantly over time. The BSP's value dropped from 24.6% of
overall average earnings in November 1980 to 16.8% by the time the
Conservatives left office in 1997 (Department of Work and Pensions 2012:
14). Thus, although there had been no change in eligibility for the BSP,
more seniors became reliant on secondary sources of income if they were
to keep up with the working-age population.
Yet, despite the significance of this change in the method of
benefit indexation, the government suffered little political backlash,
certainly if measured in electoral terms, in response to this change.
(3) This response contrasts with events in Canada under Prime Minister
Mulroney and even with the United States, where the Social Security
program's reputation as the "third rail" in political
life (touch it and die) was reinforced when President Reagan was forced
to back down from his plans to retrench benefits in the early 1980s
(Beland and Waddan 2012). For social policy scholars (Myles and Pierson
2001), however, this is a potentially counterintuitive narrative, as the
BSP's status as a contributory benefit and, therefore, as an earned
entitlement, should have provided it extra public support leading to
popular protest when its value was downgraded. Yet this result did not
happen on a large scale. The opposition parties in parliament did vote
against the measure but this was of little significance given the
government's large majority. There was also opposition from
pensioners' groups but again this did not unduly influence the
government, partially because of the fragmented nature of even the
best-organized age advocacy groups in the UK at the time and also
because the most voluble protest came from groups associated with the
labour movement (Pratt, 1993: 124-30), which did not resonate with the
Thatcher government.
In a further move in 1986, the Thatcher government reduced the
future benefits that would be paid out by SERPS - the state-run earnings
related scheme introduced in the 1970s--and implicitly encouraged people
to opt out of SERPS altogether and start their own private pension plan
(Blake 2004: 22-5). Prior to implementing this act, the government had
considered more radical proposals that would have abolished SERPS and
further slowed increases of the BSP with the expectation that the
private sector would step in to dominate the area of pension provision.
If enacted, these plans would have constituted a "radical
transition" with the state reduced "to the role of pension
provider for the poor" (Taylor-Gooby 2005: 121). Interestingly,
however, these plans provoked opposition from the pension industry and
the Confederation of British Industry and raised concerns in the
Treasury about the transitional costs always present when switching from
a pay-as-you-go arrangement to a funded system (Bonoli 2000: 67-72).
Thus, some contemporary commentary depicted the government as
backtracking in 1986, but, importantly, this retreat resulted from
opposition from the government's allies and the Treasury rather
than pressure from pensioners' groups, which remained hostile to
the final legislation. Furthermore, the government's policies still
constituted a case of "layering," which involves "the
grafting of new elements onto an otherwise stable institutional
framework" with the intention of changing that framework (Thelen
2004: 35). In this case, the government had made state provision less
attractive, meaning that pension "expansion would be channelled
into the private sector" (Pierson 1994: 59).
New Labour and pensions
Throughout the 1990s, the Labour party reconsidered much of its
wider social policy outlook, which by the 1997 election included a
retreat from previous promises to re-index the BSP to wages as well as
inflation. But by the time Labour left office in 2010, the
government's position on pension reform had evolved considerably.
The initial strategy was to alleviate poverty amongst seniors through
means-tested additions to the BSP, rather than by increasing the value
of that flat pension. Also, a new Second State Pension (S2P), replacing
SERPS, was introduced to support low paid workers and people unable to
work for reasons such as caring responsibilities. The government also
established regulatory structures that would better enable workers in
jobs with moderate incomes to take up private pensions. These measures,
however, had limited success as take-up of the new schemes remained very
limited (Evandrou and Falkingham 2009; Waine 2009).
The government also established an independent Pensions Commission
to analyze the options for further reform. Importantly, the reports
issued by this Commission (Pensions Commission 2004 and 2005) provided
new pressures for a major overhaul of the existing state pension
arrangements (Brooks and Denham 2005). The Pensions Commission (2005: 2)
also noted that pensioner income from occupational and private pensions
was at an all-time high, but that "voluntary private provision is
not growing: rather it is in serious and probably irreversible
decline." In this context, Labour began its third term in office in
2005 committed to pension reform: "The pensions system we have
today is rooted in the society of the 1940s. Society has moved on and,
unless we act now, women and carers retiring in the next two decades
will continue to suffer the effects of the system of contributions which
applied during their working lives" (Department of Work and
Pensions 2006: 12). The government acknowledged that the increasing
reliance on means-testing, while it had particularly benefited women,
was inappropriate because it acted as a disincentive to saving. In
2005-06, the full BSP for a single person was 82.05 [pounds sterling]
per week, way below the minimum income of 109.45 [pounds sterling] per
single person per week guaranteed to seniors (Brooks and Denham 2005:
23). Yet, closing the gap between the BSP and the income that the
government deemed the minimum acceptable for seniors was daunting
because of the cost implications of a universal increase in the level of
BSP.
On the other hand, the BSP was brought into further disrepute by
the manner it distributed benefits in a highly gender discriminatory
fashion. Whereas over 80% of recently retired men were in receipt of the
full level of BSP, only just over 30% of women were in this position
(Department of Work and Pensions 2006), illustrating that the program
fell short of true universality.
In this context, the Pensions Act of 2007 brought important change.
From some point after 2012, the BSP was to be re-indexed to rises in
average wages as well as inflation. Furthermore, while the government
rejected the Pension Commission's idea that the BSP be based on
residence rather than contributions, there were significant changes to
the criteria by which individuals would be eligible for the full BSP
(Glennerster 2009: 152-3). First, the qualifying number of contributory
years required to receive the full BSP was reduced to 30 for everyone,
both men and women, retiring after 2010. Second, the definition of a
contributory year was changed so that people, primarily women, who had
spent years of their working aged lives in a caring role rather than
doing paid work, would find those "caring" years count as
contributory years towards the BSP (see Bozio, Crawford and Tetlow 2010:
18-22). According to government projections, this would mean that 95% of
men and 75% of women reaching the state pension age in 2010 would
qualify for the full BSP (Pensions Policy Institute 2011: 68). Flence,
while still a contributory benefit, access to the full BSP was
considerably eased. The importance of increasing the amount paid to
seniors through the BSP is exaggerated by the fact that many eligible
households, due to the complexity or stigma involved, do not claim their
full entitlement to means-tested benefit. It is estimated that in
2009-10, the take-up of Pension Credit by eligible households was
somewhere between 62% to 68% (Pensions Policy Institute 2012:
7).Countering these moves, and illustrating how policy can move in
divergent directions simultaneously, there was retrenchment in the form
of a gradual raising of the state pension age to 68. This regressive
move was done in a way to minimize protest as it did not affect current
or near retirees. Soon after taking office in 2010, the Coalition
government reinforced the directions of travel outlined in the 2007 Act.
From April 2012, the BSP was to rise in line with highest of average
wages or inflation, or by 2.5%, but simultaneously the government also
elevated the state pension age for men and women to 66.
Canada
The emergence of, and the debate over, OAS
In Canada, just like in the UK, pension reform became a significant
policy issue in the immediate post-war era (Bryden 1974). (4) The
central aspect of this post-war pension debate concerned the elimination
of the means test created as part of the 1927 Old Age Pensions Act
(Orloff 1993), a law that gradually led to the creation of federally
subsidized old age assistance pensions in each of the nine provinces
(Newfoundland only became a Canadian province in 1949). Due to
provincial resistance especially strong in Quebec and despite the
increase of the level of federal funding in 1931, it took nearly a
decade for all provinces to offer these means-tested pensions (Banting
2005: 119-120). After the war, like in the UK, removing the means test
became a priority, but there was no consensus about how to achieve this
expansion of pension coverage. Two main policy options were discussed:
earnings-related pensions and flat pensions. Inside the federal
government, supporters of the second option came to dominate, which led
to adoption of a universal pension scheme, in which entitlements would
only derive from residency and age, as people aged 70 and older meeting
certain residency criteria became entitled to a federal flat pension.
Consequently, in contrast to the BSP in the UK, what become known as OAS
was not a contributory scheme. Yet, to compensate for the additional
fiscal burden created by the new flat pension, the Liberal government of
Louis St. Laurent asked civil servants in the Department of Finance to
design a new taxation scheme that, as explained below, took a different
form than a traditional social insurance payroll tax (Bryden 1974: 122).
After securing provincial support for a constitutional amendment
that allowed the federal government to directly enter this provincial
jurisdiction (instead of subsidizing provincial pension schemes as it
had done since 1927), parliament passed the Old Age Security Act in
1951, and the law came to effect on January 1 of the following year. In
addition to the OAS program, which offered a $40-a-month pension to all
people aged 70 and older meeting the residency requirement, a second
legislation, the Old Age Assistance Act, also came to effect in January
1952. This law created a federal means-tested pension for people aged 65
to 69. This provision remained in place until 1970, when the age of
eligibility for the OAS flat pension reached 65 (Beland and Myles 2005).
This brief description of the program stresses a crucial difference with
the UK's BSP: the OAS offered a truly universal pension not derived
from one's contribution record. This is a key distinction, as the
existing pension literature stresses the stronger political resilience
of contributory schemes (Myles and Pierson 2001), which our comparison
between the UK and Canada challenges, at least as far as flat pensions
are concerned.
By the late 1950s, despite the creation of voluntary registered
retirement savings plans (RRSPs) in 1957 and increases in OAS benefits
aimed at compensating for the negative effects of inflation, it became
clear that the limited coverage offered by voluntary occupational
pensions and the modest nature of the OAS flat pension could not, on
their own, guarantee the economic security of many older people (Babich
and Beland 2009). To address this problem, in the mid-1960s, with
support from the provinces, the federal government created an
earnings-related pension scheme known as the Canada Pension Plan (or
Quebec Pension Plan, a nearly identical program covering Quebec
workers). To this day, the Canada Pension Plan (CPP) and the Quebec
Pension Plan (QPP) offer a low replacement rate of 25% of covered wages.
The modest nature of this replacement rate is related to the enduring
belief that voluntary occupational pensions should remain a key
source--and even the main source--of income security for large segments
of the population (Babich and Beland 2009).
In addition to CPP and QPP, the mid-1960s also saw the advent of
the Guaranteed Income Supplement (GIS), an income-related program
created in 1967 as a temporary measure originally designed to expire
when CPP/QPP matured as an established pension program (Bryden 1974;
Guest 1997: 144-145). Working in tandem with OAS, this income-tested
program helps explain why Canada has been quite successful in fighting
old age poverty, and its positive impact helps explain why GIS was made
permanent (Beland and Myles 2005). For instance, using the same
definition of poverty, Michael Wiseman and Martynas Yeas (2008) showed
that Canada has been much more successful than the UK and the US in
fighting this type of poverty, a reality they attribute in large part to
the central role of GIS, as it complements OAS and CPP/QPP. According to
these authors, Canada does as well as social-democratic Sweden--and more
than twice as well as the UK--in poverty reduction among older people
(Wiseman and Yeas 2008).
The politics of retrenchment: From the indexation debate to the
fiscal clawback
Like the UK, Canada witnessed a turn to social policy retrenchment
in the 1980s. Although more moderate ideologically than the Thatcher
government, Progressive Conservative Prime Minister Brian Mulroney
(1984-1993) pledged to fight large budget deficits, which put potential
OAS cutbacks on the agenda (Myles 1988). In the spring of 1985, less
than a year after the election of his Progressive Conservative
government, Mulroney pushed for the partial de-indexing of OAS benefits.
More specifically, according to his plan, automatic OAS benefit
increases would only compensate for yearly inflation above the 3% level.
As Ken Battle (1997: 530-531) puts it, if implemented, this measure
would have favoured a gradual decline in the real value of the OAS
pension, in a fashion similar to what happened in the UK after 1980:
"If inflation were 3 per cent or higher a year, then OAS benefits
would automatically lose 3 per cent of their value. Even if inflation
were less than 3 per cent, benefits would decline by the amount of
inflation (e.g. an inflation rate of 2% would reduce the value of OAS by
2%)." In part because it appeared to contradict an electoral pledge
about the need to preserve the integrity of OAS, this policy proposal
was met with the largest wave of elderly protest in Canadian history. A
major turning point was a televised and widely discussed confrontation
between the Prime Minister and a tiny elderly woman from Quebec, who
accused him of having lied to Canadians regarding OAS. With the help of
extensive and typically negative media coverage, the Mulroney government
was forced to withdraw its highly controversial proposal (Beland and
Myles 2005). From this perspective, it failed where the Thatcher
government had (surprisingly quietly) succeeded in slowly reducing the
real value of the flat pension in order to control public spending. In
this context, in Canada, the social and political mobilization of
beneficiaries, who successfully organized mass rallies in Ottawa and
received intense and sympathetic media coverage, played a direct role in
the politics of universal flat pensions.
The 1985 political setback forced the Mulroney government to
control the increase in OAS costs using indirect, and less visible,
means (Pierson and Weaver 1993). In a low-profile 1989 budgetary move
famously described by former federal civil servant Ken Battle (1990) as
"social policy by stealth," the government implemented a
fiscal device known as "clawback," which used the tax system
to recuperate the OAS money paid to high income seniors. As a
consequence of this under-the-radar policy change, benefits for people
earning more than $51,765 per year were reduced by 15 per cent for every
income dollar above such a threshold. Thus, people with an annual income
above about $89,000 had to repay their OAS benefit in its entirety.
Importantly, the cut-off point ($51,765) where the clawback took effect
was only indexed to inflation above a 3% annual rate. This meant that,
over time, more and more people would be negatively affected by the
cut-off. Although this threshold was fully re-indexed in 2000, during
the Liberal era, the 1989 fiscal change ended universality in an
indirect and politically masterful way. Yet, importantly, the clawback
only affects a small fraction of the elderly population, and the vast
majority of seniors keep all the OAS money they receive (Beland and
Myles 2005). From this perspective, the effectiveness of the clawback as
a source of fiscal savings is rather modest, which helps explain why
other OAS retrenchment attempts would take place during the following
decades, in a context of accelerated population aging and enduring
concerns about growth in OAS spending.
Rejecting income testing
The first major attempt to control costs actually involved the
proposed replacement of OAS and GIS by a new income-tested scheme known
as the Seniors Benefit. Put forward in the mid-1990s by Liberal Finance
Minister Paul Martin (Government of Canada 1996), this proposal would
have slightly increased benefits for low-income seniors while penalizing
better-off seniors, including those in the middle class (Battle 1997;
Geddes 1998). For this reason, the scheme would have reduced anticipated
federal pension spending without penalizing the poor, which is probably
why the Liberal Party supported this approach. Yet, the scheme faced
strong criticisms from a variety of sources. On one front, some
economists argued that the new scheme, through the implementation of an
income test, would further reduce the incentives for older people to
save. On another front, feminists like the leader of the New Democratic
Party (NDP) Alexa McDonough described the Seniors Benefit proposal as an
attack against the financial autonomy of Canadian women: "Senior
women currently receive the OAS directly, but the Seniors Benefit
Program will be calculated on a couple's combined income. Older
women may lose their Seniors Benefit based on the income of their
spouse, threatening their financial independence" (McDonough 1997).
As a result of these attacks, as well as the more-rapid-than-expected
advent of federal budget surpluses, in 1998, the Liberal government of
Jean Chretien withdrew the controversial Seniors Benefit proposal
(Beland and Myles 2005; Martin 1998).
This late 1990s episode was the last direct attempt to end the
formal universality of OAS benefits, which remain available to people
aged 65 and older meeting specific residency criteria (the clawback
affecting wealthier seniors is applied after the benefits have been paid
out). This is true because the recent attempt to control the rise in OAS
costs stemming from population aging focuses on retirement age rather
than income testing or even the extension of the fiscal clawback
introduced in 1989. Announced in late March 2012 as part of the federal
budget, these changes to OAS concern the graduate increase of retirement
age, which should climb from 65 to 67 between 2023 and 2029 (Government
of Canada 2012).
Like the gradual increase of Social Security eligibility age
currently taking place in the United States (Light 1995; Pierson 1994),
this decision to simply raise the eligibility age of future retirees
reflects a strategy to reduce the potential political backlash against
government. This is true because, starting in a decade, this increase in
eligibility age will not affect current retirees or people near
retirement, and these were exactly the two constituencies that mobilized
so strongly against the 1985 Mulroney initiative on de-indexation, which
had forced the Progressive Conservative government to withdraw its
controversial proposal. In 2012, the Harper Conservative government went
ahead with the unpopular change without having to face the massive wave
of protest that had led to the humiliating demise of the Mulroney
de-indexation proposal in 1985.
Nonetheless, the lack of protest should not obscure the regressive
nature of a policy change that should penalize low-income workers. This
is because these workers are unlikely to save enough to retire before
they receive their modest OAS pension (maximum monthly benefit of $445,
as of March 2012), something that better-off Canadians can do. The
importance of this reality is exacerbated by the fact that occupational
pensions cover a shrinking minority of the country's working
population (Boychuk and Banting 2008).
Discussion
Several patterns emerge from a direct comparison between our two
cases. First, the extent of cumulative policy change is much more
pronounced in the UK than in Canada. This contrast in policy outcomes
challenges the broad claim that contributory pension schemes are
especially sturdy politically (Myles and Pierson 2001). In fact, the
non-contributory OAS has proven to be much stronger politically than
BSP, suggesting that lacking a contributory basis is not necessarily a
political liability, even in an era of retrenchment and restructuring.
Second, to explain this contrast between BSP and OAS, we can turn
to the power of social mobilization involving current and future
beneficiaries, which was striking in Canada at the beginning of the
Mulroney era but much more subdued during the early Thatcher years. Our
goal here is not to explain why protest was stronger in Canada than in
the UK at the time but to stress its impact on the politics of flat
pensions. In Canada, the 1985 wave of protest forced the Mulroney
government to withdraw its partial de-indexation program and to adopt a
low-profile approach through enacting a fiscal "clawback" in
1989, but this modest change has not resulted in transformative policy
change over time, in part because the Liberal government stopped its
incremental expansion in 2000. In 2012, the Conservative government of
Stephen Harper announced a gradual increase in retirement age that would
not affect current and even near future retirees. Perhaps because of
this decision to not affect current and near retirees, no 1985-style
elderly protest took place in the aftermath of this announcement.
Overall, the Canadian case suggests strongly that social protest on the
part of beneficiaries can shape the politics of social policy change,
which is consistent with some of the recent literature on pension reform
in advanced industrial countries (Beland and Marier 2006; Campbell
2003).
Third, our article suggests that adopting a long-term time frame is
necessary to assess the issue of incremental change. For instance, in
the immediate aftermath of the 1989 creation of the fiscal clawback in
Canada, "social policy by stealth" (that is, enacting
significant changes through less-visible means) seemed to have been a
stunning success in bringing about low-profile but nonetheless
transformative policy change to the field of universal pensions (Battle
1990). Yet, in light of more recent trends, our comparative study
suggests that incremental change has proved more powerful and
sustainable in the UK than in Canada, despite the central role of
obfuscation and incremental tactics in the latter country. These remarks
point to the crucial importance of the time frame we use to analyse,
assess, and even explain incremental policy change and its impact on the
life of beneficiaries as well as on public finance (Campbell 2004).
Finally, our analysis of the two cases suggest that the development
of flat pensions in the UK and Canada is a complex and multifaceted
story that is not about the unilateral decline of universality and the
unstoppable rise of retrenchment. This is particularly the case in the
UK, where efforts have been made since the Blair years to improve the
protection offered by the most basic elements of the UK public pension
systems. This complex story undermines the traditional dichotomy between
expansion and retrenchment, which is supposed to characterize two
distinct historical eras (Pierson 1994). The 2007 Pensions Act in the UK
simultaneously expanded the universality of the BSP, while enacting
retrenchment by increasing the retirement age. Our analysis shows that
contemporary social policy reform is not only about retrenchment,
despite the undeniable fact that cost control has become a key social
policy imperative in both countries during the era of accelerated
demographic aging.
References
Babich, Kristina, and Daniel Beland. 2009. "Policy change and
the politics of ideas: The emergence of the Canada/Quebec pension
plans." Canadian Review of Sociology 46 (3): 253-271.
Banting, Keith G. 2005. "Canada: Nation-building in a federal
welfare state." In Federalism and the Welfare State, edited by
Herbert Obinger, Stephan Leibfried and Frank G. Castles. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 89-137.
Barr, Nicholas. 2004. The Economics of the Welfare State. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Battle, Ken (under the pseudonym of Grattan Gray). 1990.
"Social policy by stealth." Policy Options 11 (2): 17-29.
Battle, Ken. 1997. "Pension reform in Canada." Canadian
Journal of Aging 16 (3): 519-552.
BBC News. 2012. "Pensions auto-enrolment starts for biggest
firms," BBC News online, October 1. Available at
http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-19760421
Beland, Daniel, and Patrik Marier. 2012. "Vieillissement et
politiques de retraite au Canada" in Patrik Marier (ed.), Le
vieillissement de la population et les politiques publiques: enjeux
d'ici et d'ailleurs. Quebec City: Presses de l'Universite
Laval, pp. 109-128.
Beland, Daniel, and Patrik Marier. 2006. "Protest avoidance:
Labor mobilization and social policy reform in France."
Mobilization 11 (3): 297-311.
Beland, Daniel, and John Myles. 2005. "Stasis amidst change:
Canadian pension reform in an age of retrenchment." In Ageing and
Pension Reform around the World, edited by Giuliano Bonoli and
Toshimitsu Shinkawa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 252-272.
Beland, Daniel, and Alex Waddan. 2012. The Politics of Policy
Change: Welfare, Medicare and Social Security Reform in the United
States. Washington DC: Georgetown University Press.
Beveridge, William H. 1942. Social Insurance and Allied Services.
Cmd6404, London: HMSO.
Blackburn, Robin. 2002. Banking on Death Or, Investing in Life: The
History and Future of Pensions. London: Verso.
Blake, David. 2004. "Contracting out of the state pension
system: The British experience of carrots and sticks". Rethinking
the Welfare State: The Political Economy of Pension reform, edited by
Martin Rein and Winfried Schmal. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp.
19-55.
Bonoli, Giuliano. 2000. The Politics of Pension Reform:
Institutions and Policy Change in Western Europe. Cambridge University
Press.
Boychuk, Gerard W., and Keith G. Banting. 2008. "The
public-private divide: Health insurance and pensions in Canada." In
Public and Private Social Policy: Health and Pension Policies in a New
Era, edited by Daniel Beland and Brian Gran. Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan, pp. 92-122.
Bozio, Antoine, Rowena Crawford, and Gemma Tetlow. 2010. The
History of State Pensions in the UK: 1948 to 2010. London: Institute for
Fiscal Studies.
Brooks, Richard, and John Denham. 2005. The Politics of Pension
Reform. London: Fabian Society.
Bryden, Kenneth. 1974. Old Age Pensions and Policy-Making in
Canada. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press.
Campbell, Andrea L. 2003. How Policies Make Citizens: Senior
Political Activism and the American Welfare State. Princeton: Princeton
University Press
Campbell, John L. 2004. Institutional Change and Globalization.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Department of Work and Pensions. 2006. Security in Retirement:
Towards a New Pensions System. London. Available at
http://www.dwp.gov.uk/docs/white-paper-summary.pdf
Department of Work and Pensions. 2012. The Annual Abstract of
Statistics for Benefits, National Insurance Contributions, and Indices
of Prices and Earnings 2011 Edition. London. Available at
http://research.dwp.gov.uk/asd/asdl/abstract/abstract2011.pdf
Evandrou, Maria, and Jane Falkingham. 2009. "Pensions and
income security in later life." In Towards a More Equal Society?
Poverty, Inequality and Policy since 1997, edited by John Hills, Tom
Sefton and Kitty Stewart. Bristol, Policy Press, pp. 157-76.
Geddes, John. 1998. "Citizen's Revolt,"
Maclean's, 111 (20 April): 12-13.
Glennerster, Howard. 2009. Understanding the Finance of Welfare:
What welfare costs and how to pay for it. Bristol: The Policy Press
Government of Canada. 2012. Budget 2012. Available at
http://www.budget.gc.ca/2012/ themes/theme3-fra.html
Government of Canada. 1996. Government Proposes New Seniors
Benefit. Ottawa: Government of Canada (March 6).
Guest, Dennis. 1997 The Emergence of Social Security in Canada
(third edition). Vancouver: UBC Press.
Hacker, Jacob. 2004. "Privatizing risk without privatizing the
welfare state: The hidden politics of welfare state retrenchment in the
United States." American Political Science Review 98: 243-260.
Light, Paul C. 1995. Still Artful Work: The Continuing Politics of
Social Security Reform. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Marier, Patrik. 2008. Pension Politics: Consensus and Social
Conflict in Ageing Societies. London: Routledge.
Martin, Paul. 1998. Finance Minister's Statement on the
Seniors Benefit. Ottawa: Government of Canada (July 28).
McDonough, Alexa. 1997. "McDonough defends pensioners,"
The New Ontario Democrat. December.
Myles, John. 1988. "Social policies for the elderly in
Canada." In North American Elders: U.S. and Canadian Comparisons,
edited by Betty Havens and Eloise Rathbone-McCuan. New York: Greenwood
Press, pp. 37-54.
Myles, John, and Paul Pierson. 2001. "The comparative
political economy of pension reform. In The New Politics of the Welfare
State, edited by Paul Pierson. New York: Oxford University Press, pp.
305-333.
Orloff, Ann Shola 1993. The Politics of Pensions: A Comparative
Analysis of Canada, Great Britain and the United States, 1880-1940.
Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Pemberton, Hugh. 2006. "Politics and pensions in post war
Britain," History and Policy. Available at
http://www.historyandpolicy.org/papers/policy-paper-41.html
Pensions Commission. 2004. Pensions: Challenges and Choices.
London: Pensions Commission.
Pensions Commission. 2005. A New Pensions Settlement for the
Twenty-First Century. London: Pensions Commission.
Pensions Policy Institute. 2011. An assessment of the
government's options for state pension reform,
pensionspolicyinstitute.org.uk
Pensions Policy Institute. 2012. Pensions Facts, September 2012.
Available at http:// www.pensionspolicyinstitute.org.uk
Pierson, Paul. 1994. Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan,
Thatcher and the Politics of Retrenchment. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Pierson, Paul, and R. Kent Weaver. 1993. "Imposing Losses in
Pension Policy." Do Institutions Matter?: Government Capabilities
in the United States and Abroad, edited by R. Kent Weaver and Rockman,
Bert A. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, pp. 110-150.
Pratt, Henry J. 1993. Gray Agendas: Interest Groups and Public
Pensions in Canada, Britain and the United States. Ann Arbor: The
University of Michigan Press.
Taylor-Gooby, Peter. 2005. "UK pension reform: A test case for
the liberal welfare state?" In Ageing and Pension Reform Around the
World: Evidence from Eleven Countries, edited by Giuliano Bonoli and
Toshimitsu Shinkawa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Kathleen Thelen, eds. 2005. Beyond
Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Thelen, Kathleen. 2004. How Institutions Evolve: The Political
Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Timmins, Nicholas. 1996. The Five Giants: A Biography of the
Welfare State, London: Fontana Press.
Waine, Barbara. 2009. "New Labour and pension reform: Security
in retirement." Social Policy and Administration 43 (7): 754-771.
Weaver, R. Kent. 2010. "Paths and forks or chutes and ladders?
Negative feedbacks and policy regime change." Journal of Public
Policy 30 (2): 137-162.
Wiseman, Michael, and Martynas Yeas. 2008. "The Canadian
Safety Net for the Elderly," Social Security Bulletin, 68 (2):
53-67.
Notes
(1) In October 2012, a new workplace pension scheme was introduced
in the UK, with employees automatically enrolled in a pension plan
unless they explicitly opt out. Starting with larger employers, this
scheme will be expanded to cover all workers earning over [pounds
sterling] 8,105 a year by 2018 (BBC News 2012).
(2) In the UK, the distinction between state pensions and public
sector pensions is essential. Public sector pensions in the UK are
occupational pensions for workers employed by central or local
governments, such as teachers or doctors. The Coalition government
implemented reforms to public sector pensions in 2010 that resulted in a
number of strikes, but these reforms are not the subject of this paper.
(3) The Conservatives won a plurality of votes amongst voters aged
over 65 in all of their general election triumphs from 1979 to 1992
(Blackburn 2002: 291).
(4) For a recent, historically-informed overview of the Canadian
pension system, see Beland and Marier 2012.
Daniel Beland is Professor and Canada Research Chair in Public
Policy (Tier 1), Johnson-Shoyama Graduate School of Public Policy. Alex
Waddan is Senior Lecturer in American Politics in the Department of
Politics and International Relations, University of Leicester. A
previous draft of this article was presented at the annual Social
Security History Conference in Vancouver (November 2012). The authors
thank the participants at that conference as well as Greg Marchildon and
the anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions. They also
thank Tanya Andrusieczko for her help in preparing the article. Daniel
Beland also acknowledges support from the Canada Research Chairs
program.