The Evolution of Resource Property Rights.
Trebilcock, Michael J.
The Evolution of Resource Property Rights
By ANTHONY SCOTT. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press,
2008. Pp. 497, bibliographical references, index.
This book is the culmination of much of a life's scholarship
by one of Canada's most distinguished political economists,
Professor Anthony Scott, of the University of British Columbia. The book
is panoramic in the scope of its subject matter, exemplary in the
facility with which the author moves effortlessly across the
disciplinary boundaries of economics, law, and political science in
explaining the emergence of rights to natural resources, and a model of
scholarly erudition in the rigour of the research, the subtlety of
interpretations offered of key evolutionary moments, and the lucidity
and elegance of exposition.
As the author states in his introductory chapter,
Looking at the sheer volume of the historical and development
literatures, one would think that scholars of property rights and
institutions must also have looked in depth at the emergence of
individuals' rights to natural resources, including minerals,
water, forests, and fish. Yet, when I embarked on this project, it was
largely because nobody seems yet to have assembled a unified body of
knowledge that can familiarize the non-specialist with changes in the
rights held by owners and users of natural resources.... My purpose in
this book is to provide such a unified body (p. 3).
In this goal, Professor Scott succeeds spectacularly.
Apart from the introductory chapter, the book is divided into three
parts. The first part deals with rights over fugacious (fluid) resources
and deals with the evolution of rights over flowing water and rights
over fisheries and fish. The second part deals with rights over mineral
resources, with an initial focus on gold-mining and then alluvial and
hard-rock mining, followed by the evolution of rights over coal, oil and
gas. The final part deals with rights over wood-based resources.
Professor Scott's strategy for integrating his analysis of
these very disparate natural resources is to focus on six core
characteristics of property rights: exclusivity, duration, flexibility,
quality of title, transferability, and divisibility, and, in the case of
each class of natural resource, to seek to learn how and why the
characteristics of property rights have changed in one or more of these
dimensions over time. He emphasizes that he is not principally concerned
with whether the changes were a good or bad thing or were more or less
efficient. As Professor Scott notes in his introductory chapter, he is
"not primarily interested in deriving solutions to an optimal
property holding problem" (p. 6). Moreover, he rejects any
evolutionary thesis that the changes he describes entail an exorable
move towards perfection; rather, his research shows that while the
amounts of each attribute in a standard right over some resource did
increase in some periods, those over other resources, or in other
periods, declined. While there is a body of recent law and economic
scholarship that claims that the common law evinces a tendency towards
the evolution of efficient rules over time (a thesis that is strongly
contested by other scholars), the author implicitly rejects this thesis
(without explicitly joining issue with this literature) in arguing that
"it cannot be assumed that the regimes of property rights created
by their responses were more efficient than what came before" (p.
44). Further, the author describes examples of property-right
characteristic trend lines that could be said to bend back on
themselves, producing cycles of increasing and decreasing levels of the
given characteristics.
Having identified these six characteristics of property rights in
natural resources, Professor Scott then categorizes the forces that
induce change and shape property rights as demand-side forces and
supply-side forces. With respect to every class of natural resource, he
asks why demanders requested a change in some characteristic of the
property rights in question, noting that demanders' private goals
mainly fall into two categories, one purely distributional (or
redistributional) and the second allocational (entailing some change in
the use of the resource in question). In some cases, changes in the
demand for property rights reflected exogenous changes in the value of
the resources in question (for example, a dramatic increase in the
demand for coal and subsequently oil and gas during and following the
Industrial Revolution); in other cases, shifts in demand reflected
technological innovations that facilitated new forms of utilization of
given resources (e.g., hard rock or underground mining), which in turn
often required scales of capital investment beyond the reach of
individual miners or prospectors, presaging the emergence of large-scale
corporate mining interests.
On the supply-side, Professor Scott focuses on government in the
form of the Crown, the Executive, or, in later periods, the legislature,
the courts, long-established custom, or the spontaneous emergence of
some new regimes of informal ordering such as the gold-mining
associations that emerged during the California Gold Rush in 1850, where
"miners showed great originality in hammering out what amounted to
nothing less than a social contract" (p. 218) for defining claims
and adjudicating disputes.
Utilizing this framework of analysis, with its focus on the six
core characteristics of property rights and shifts in influence among
configurations of demanders or suppliers of changes to existing property
rights, the author then explores the emergence of property rights
regimes to each of the classes of natural resources addressed in the
book, often beginning with Roman law, moving then to early and later
medieval English law (much of it common law case law), which he analyses
with exquisite care and subtlety (and which would put many lawyers to
shame), and then moves on to more recent developments where legislative
initiatives have played a more prominent role. Not only is the
historical sweep of the analysis breathtaking but even more so is its
comparative focus. While in every case Professor Scott's initial
focus is English law, he then moves on to compare the evolution of
English law with the evolution of parallel bodies of law in the United
States, Canada, and Australia, with selective references to other
jurisdictions.
Given the superb body of scholarship that this book represents it
seems churlish to note any criticisms. I note but two. In his discussion
of rights to wood-based resources and the different evolution of these
rights in Canada and the U.S. (retention of Crown land and sale of
harvesting rights versus sale of state land as freehold interests), he
fails to note that these differences lie at the heart of the
long-running softwood lumber trade dispute between the two countries. On
a more general note, he nowhere explicitly discusses a current
preoccupation of many development scholars--the so-called "natural
resource curse" whereby developing countries more richly endowed
with natural resources appear often to be poorer than developing
countries that lack these resources and have evolved dysfunctional
policies and institutions as a result of rent-seeking and corruption by
both private- and public-sector actors. Whether an abundance of natural
resources ever similarly afflicted, at any points in their history, the
now-developed countries that are the focus of Professor Scott's
analysis and, if so, how they escaped the natural resource curse might
well have yielded important sources of illumination of an important
contemporary development concern.
Such quibbles aside, no serious scholar of natural resource
property rights, and for that matter no serious policy-maker
contemplating reforms to existing natural resource property rights
regimes, should commit the folly of treating this book as providing
anything less than the essential building blocks for serious analysis.
It will surely become the standard reference book in this field, at
least across the common law world and probably beyond.
Michael J. Trebilcock is University Professor of Law and Economics
in the Faculty of Law at the University of Toronto.