Global governance to the rescue: saving international relations?
Weiss, Thomas G. ; Wilkinson, Rorden
OUR PURPOSE IN THIS ARTICLE IS TO PROVOKE AND PROPOSE. WE AIM TO
PROVOKE a reaction from our colleagues who, at worst, have not yet
awakened to the fact that international relations (IR) teeters on the
edge of an abyss of irrelevance or, at best, have yet to be spurred to
refresh a field much in need of revitalization. IR as an academic
pursuit has become disparate and fragmented. Those of us in the field
have ceased to pursue greater clarity in the way that we understand the
world around us. Furthermore, we have failed as agents of change; that
is, as purveyors of opinion and proposals about a better and fairer
world order. As such, we no longer serve our students and those
practitioners who seek our advice--or for those of us who take on policy
jobs, we no longer push out the envelope of what is considered
acceptable. We too seldom offer a set of tools for understanding how the
world works, a grounding on which socially beneficial policy can be
created, and a framework for thinking about change.
How we have arrived at this point is easier to explain than moving
beyond it. We nonetheless have a proposal: to move back toward the
future--to the table of grand disciplinary debate--by applying the not
yet fully utilized concept of global governance.
Our argument unfolds in three parts. In the first part, we outline
why and how IR teeters on the edge of an abyss. Here, we show that the
field's precariousness is theoretical, methodological, pedagogical,
and linguistic. In the second part, we offer a proposal for moving
beyond the fragmentation and atomization that afflicts international
relations. We suggest here that one way of encouraging reengagement is
to return to debating grand questions that used to be the sustenance of
IR. Questions come no grander than asking how the world is governed, how
we have ended up with the global governance that we currently have, and
what kind of order we ought to put in place to correct the myriad ills
that afflict humanity and the planet that we so willfully neglect.
Indeed, understanding the precise shape of the current world order is
perhaps the fundamental question of international relations, but one on
which we have tended to turn our backs in recent years. (1) Shunning big
questions of world order has certainly not resulted because we have
solved the riddle of how the world is governed or the concomitant
puzzles of how power and authority are exercised, what the consequences
of particular formations of organization and governance are, and how we
might best engage in meaningful reform.
In the third part of this article, we argue that global
governance--appro-priately and specifically framed to make it fit for
purpose--offers an opportunity to return to these as well as other
questions and, in so doing, to reinvigorate our fragmented and atomized
field. We are, of course, not blind to the problems that global
governance itself brings. It has rightly been criticized as a catchall
term. Lawrence Finkelstein asked in the first volume of this journal,
"what is global governance?" He provocatively replied,
"virtually anything." (2) What we suggest, however, is that
questions of global governance can be a catalyst for a rejuvenated field
as long as we resist the temptation to fall back into our old habits of
asking and answering questions within the intellectual silos that we now
inhabit. We conclude by showing how we can move fruitfully beyond this
to reclaim global governance's potential as a critical scholarly
endeavor and--in our role as provocateurs--as the savior of IR.
The Edge of the Abyss
The field of IR--and those of us within it--should be proud of its
success. Barely thirty years ago, "international relations"
was a vague appellation that referred to those areas of political
science that dealt with politics "beyond the border," or
"over there," or "in foreign climes." Those who
practiced it became members of our faculties, but they were somehow
different--they did African and Asian politics; the communist world;
and, in North America at least, European integration. Larger departments
also had faculty members who studied forms of international
organization--almost exclusively, the United Nations--and international
law. However, with a few notable exceptions, the bulk of political
science (and the areas that carried professional prestige) remained more
squarely focused on the core executive, representation, and
enfranchisement; national and local bureaucracy; comparative politics;
and classical and neoclassical political theory.
The technological advances and economic forces that have propelled
disparate peoples and places together, along with the rise of new forms
of insecurity, have underpinned a growing and serious student demand for
IR, resulting in a fundamental change in the complexion of political
science departments worldwide. Not only is it now common that IR
faculty--along with applicants for limited numbers of PhD
positions--outnumber their more traditional counterparts, but also that
students clamor to find internships and eventually work for one global
institution or another and have careers with an international
orientation. This demand has fundamentally altered the content of course
offerings. Whereas once it was the Cinderella attracting the attention
of the mainstream only when international applications spoke to core
political science endeavors, research in IR attracts at least as much
attention and prestige as its older siblings and its professional
associations have grown as a result. For instance, the International
Studies Association (ISA) has seen its membership grow from
approximately 200 just after its establishment in 1959 to 1,000 by 1970,
1,900 by 1973, 3,000 by the mid-1990s, and over 6,000 by 2013, with
participation at its annual meetings also having increased similarly.
(3)
The Way We Think
However, we are victims of our own success. The burgeoning growth
in ER as an intellectual pursuit has encouraged the community not to
focus on overlaps and interactions, but instead on showing how different
we are from one another, illustrating how our novel value-added
distinguishes us from an all too often imagined orthodoxy. Perhaps we
should not be surprised. We teach our students to be critical of
conventional wisdom. In their graduate work we demand that they develop
frameworks and pursue empirical enquiries that show how what we thought
we knew to be true is not actually quite so. In a less frenetic field of
study (i.e., one that has not grown so quickly and struggled for
recognition), the result would be a steady advance of knowledge; the
development, refinement, and critique of a canon; and a constant
reflection on big and important questions.
That has not been the case for ER. The number of new entrants,
along with the necessity to be different or to get a job or to secure
tenure, requires making a name for oneself. The result has been
fragmentation. As such, we have lost sight of the need (and, indeed,
perhaps the capacity) to interact more productively with one another,
more often than not finding ourselves conversing with fellow converts
and eschewing dialogue. Our intellectual splits are legendary--the
British and US schools in international political economy (IPE) and the
divide between rationalists versus reflectivists are just two of the
more notable (4)--but so are the intellectual silos that we now inhabit:
poststructuralist, structural realist, constructivist, neo-Gramscian,
feminist, solidarist, communitarian, cosmopolitan, pluralist,
postmodemist, behavioralist, postcolonialist, and institutionalist,
among many others. We do not interact in our journals (indeed, we seldom
publish in the same places), we do not mix well at our conferences, and
we are disparaging of what it is that we imagine others do.
This unhealthy intellectual state of affairs infects our students.
We teach them our favored ways of looking at the world, deriding the
wisdom of those whom we view as "the Other." We encourage
them--and in growing numbers as the demand for IR shows no sign of
flagging--to seek out new ways of thinking about the world by combing
other disciplines for novel approaches and harvesting the wisdom found
therein as the new next best way of understanding the world around us.
Ironically, this incentive makes us even less likely to talk with one
another; it reinforces our intellectual silos; and it ensures that we
are less, rather than more, able to think through how we could make the
world a better place. Indeed, many of us have become more able to talk
with colleagues in other disciplines than those within ER.
The Way We Research
Our problems are not, however, just theoretical. They are
methodological too. IR has always had an unusual problem when it comes
to how we conduct research. It has never been practical to expect that
we or our graduate students can easily gain access to a war cabinet to
study decisionmaking; hang out with trade delegates expecting that they
will share their negotiating secrets; or spend time with combatants,
victims of rape and torture, and perpetrators of crimes against humanity
and acts of terrorism. So, we have pursued other research methods. For
some, IR had to become more scientific; we needed to have formal
theories and to count what we could to make sense of the world. For
others, archives, interviews, and secondary sources became standard
operating procedures.
The methodological divides are well known, and we have talked about
them since at least the 1950s. Yet we have continually failed to bridge
the qualitative-quantitative divide, let alone learn from a blend of
methodological insights. Our rush to harvest approaches from other
disciplines has compounded rather than attenuated this problem. We have
imported, adapted, and adopted the methods from other disciplines; but
in so doing we have reinforced the walls between us. In IPE, for
instance, there is almost no bridging the quantitative and qualitative
divide. The same can be said of the absence of a conversation between
historical materialist and poststructural IPE. These methodological
differences, and absence of a dialogue that they tend to justify, are
replicated across the entire field of IR--to which formal and
constructivist approaches to the problems of war and peace provide ample
testimony. Thus, our methodological and theoretical tools make us less
inclined and less able to scale these barricades, let alone
constructively engage in grand debates about big topics.
The Way We Teach
It is no surprise that IR's theoretical and methodological
fragmentation should be reflected not only in what we teach, but also in
the rvay that we teach. The classroom instruction of IR has moved away
from a common canon toward an approach to the international that
typically starts from a favored theoretical and methodological position.
Of course, exceptions exist; but it is not uncommon for North American universities to eschew teaching poststructural and postcolonial
approaches, especially at the undergraduate level, for a focus on
broadly realist and liberal institutionalist approaches, with an
emphasis on rationalist and reflectivist methodologies. The converse can
also be said of the way that IR is taught in British and Australian
universities, where critical and postmodern approaches are likely to be
taught to students at all levels while ignoring more traditional
mainstream theories or formal methods.
Yet pedagogy is one place where interesting cross-disciplinary
efforts exist. Daniel Drezner's Theories of International Relations
and Zombies5--mirroring a general trend in political science, sociology,
and philosophy to use popular culture and television programs in
particular as vehicles for exploring specific questions6--is a brave and
welcome move. Its problem so far, however, is that rather than genuinely
facilitating a broad-based conversation, it has illustrated what one
approach or another might have to say about an outbreak of the
"undead--the point of Drezner's book. This is akin to asking
students to adopt certain stylized theoretical approaches. For instance,
we should not be teaching our students about the workings of the UN and
world diplomacy through caricatured activities (e.g., replicating en
masse UN committees or simply concentrating on the General Assembly in
model UN simulations). Rather we should be asking them to use their
knowledge of what passes for debate in and around the world organization
as a platform for thinking about new, alternative, and better ways of
organizing relations among whatever collectives that we imagine are the
primary political units of analysis. So--and to rather unfairly return
to Drezner's brave experiment--what Zombie IR should be teaching us
is how to use global threats as the basis for constructing new world
orders rather than as a medium for trotting out and regurgitating
hackneyed theories and playing predetermined roles.
The Language We Speak
The problems that we face are not merely theoretical,
methodological, or pedagogical. Our divisions, and with them our
capacity and desire to scale the walls that divide us, are further
reinforced by the very way we talk among ourselves. Each approach favors
a language that reflects particular theoretical and methodological
preferences, which needs to be learned for us to be able to understand,
engage, and be heard. The dominant discourse within other silos is as
foreign as romance languages are to Arabic or Chinese speakers. Few take
the time to learn "foreign" languages or even dialects within
disciplinary or field mother-tongues, which are prerequisites to
building bridges across vast and growing divides, or to understand the
cultures and practices to which they are organically connected. Carol
Cohn recognized the incommensurability of the languages that we speak in
1R almost three decades ago. (7) Michael Barnett did likewise with his
focus on UN-ese within humanitarian catastrophes a decade and a half
ago. (8) These are among the most poignant attacks on contemporary IR
but we too seldom assign them to our students, let alone act on the
important lessons that they convey.
In combination, our theoretical, methodological, pedagogical, and
linguistic divides have brought us close to the edge of an abyss into
which we can easily totter. We risk irrelevance and student
dissatisfaction. We should not be mistaken in thinking that this threat
is either overstated or distant. It is neither. As a community of
scholars, we seldom try to understand the world in ways that identify
common ground. We rarely teach students ways of exploring how to make
the world a better place. We not only talk past one other, if we stopped
to listen to ourselves, we would realize that we are occupying different
stories in the Tower of Babel. In many ways, we have regressed, rather
than progressed.
Returning to Grand Debate?
What passes for grand debate in IR has tended to be more about
refining opposing approaches or theoretical traditions than engaging in
genuine dialogue or advancing knowledge. As Steve Smith puts it,
Despite the discipline's fondness for so-called great debates, there
have been few; in the main, the differing positions have simply
ignored one another. This does not mean that there have not been
strong opposing positions within the discipline ... there has
indeed been a rivalry between competing theoretical frameworks; what
there have not been are debates in the strong sense of the word
(whereby contrasting positions indicate their superiority over rival
positions through explicit debates). (9)
We are not harking back to the imagined days of a bygone golden
age--they were far from that. We are simply pointing out that, no matter
how badly these debates were conducted (and we could and should have
conducted them much better), we had a sense of ourselves; we had a
common lexicon; we shared an appreciation for contested terrain; and we
actively engaged. Yet as IR grew and our community increased
dramatically and as we prioritized innovation, we moved away from the
grand debates of realism versus idealism (with the occasional nod to
some form of structuralism) and interpre-tivism versus behavioralism,
the interparadigm debate, (10) and the brief moment when a synthesis of
sorts occurred in the form of the neo-neo debate. (11) Subsequent turns
in the field--postpositivist, cultural, and constructivist, among others
(12)--have tended to orient us along different and seldom converging
paths, despite some notable attempts to do otherwise. (13)
Such is our fragmentation that the regard in which we hold the
field varies dramatically across our membership. For some the moniker "international relations" perfectly describes what it is that
we do, but for others it represents all that is wrong with the way that
we look at the world. We need look no further for ample evidence than
the debates within departments that sit beneath the apparent semantics
of naming graduate programs in "international relations,"
"international politics," "international studies,"
"global politics," "global studies," and so on. This
atomization and the resulting hostility toward and caricatures of the
denizens of other silos means that we avoid doing precisely what IR
should do; that is, generate knowledge about the world around us.
Instead, we pursue incremental movements forward in sub-fields that
continue to move farther away from other subfields and that speak even
more quietly to the field's core concerns.
We do, of course, need to do more than return to an era when
debates merely solidified what we already knew about our epistemological
positions; and we need to recognize that we have never been very good at
having grand debates about issues that are fundamental to our field.
If IR is to move away from the abyss of irrelevance, we should
begin discussions that involve everyone: about how the world is
governed; about how we have ended up with the kind of governance
arrangements that we have; and, most importantly, about what kind of
global governance we ought to have (and how we should get there).
Moreover, we should engage in this debate mindful that we must fully
explain the value-added of what we bring to the table, and that we must
express and defend our approaches in a common language that
everyone--even those from other fields and disciplines--can understand.
To repeat, the reasons for overcoming our atomization are
compelling--IR risks losing its capacity to understand the world around
us, excite our students, and contribute relevant global public policy
formulation. A turn toward a grand global governance debate offers a
clear opportunity. Yet a fieldwide debate is important not just to
refresh IR, but also to make it relevant. We have yet to get a grip on
precisely how the world is organized, how power and authority are
exercised by a host of actors through a range of mechanisms, and how
forms of governance have changed within and across historical epochs (an
essential task that few have even realized that we need to undertake),
(14) And these are analytical prerequisites so that we can set about
designing a better world order--an activity that has fallen out of
fashion, but is urgently required.
Consider the following: We have yet to work out satisfactory
explanations for the relations that exist among actors of various sorts.
Principal-agent theory, for instance, gets us only so far in
understanding relations between the executive branch in Washington, DC,
or London and the governing bodies of the World Bank or UN Development
Programme (UNDP), or between chains of command in relations among a
range of such actors as state legislatures, international organizations,
and subcontracted delivery agents. It does not tell us nearly enough
about differences in relationships between numerous agents and numerous
principals over time and across contexts. Thus, it explains one small
slice of what all of us might agree is international relations.
Likewise, we know a great deal about the power of financial
markets. (15) But we do not know nearly enough about how precisely
global financial deci-sionmaking affects daily life other than to say
that global financial crises make the everyday lives of ordinary people
more precarious (and none more so than in the Global South) and to show
this by associating various phenomena. The turn toward an "IPE of
the everyday" (16) is a good start, but not yet wholly
satisfactory. What are the transmission belts, the role of regulation
and regulators, the relationship between global commodity markets and
local spot markets, and between traders and speculators? Similarly, we
claim to have clear indicators that suggest that such states as China.
India, and Brazil are rising in power and prestige, but the means by
which we measure this rise are pure guesstimate, argument, and proxy
(e.g., crude income statistics and human development indices, and so
on).
We are learning a lot about how international norms arise, the
processes of their transmission, and their subsequent success, mutation,
and demise. But do we actually know how much of a difference they make?
Can we really say that the Responsibility to Protect (R2P) and the norm
of global poverty reduction that underpins the Millennium Development
Goals (MDGs) have made a difference beyond crude speculation about
counterfactuals? We know a great deal about international negotiations
and decisionmaking. Yet how often has such knowledge been the basis for
outside-the-box thinking about the reform of international institutions
rather than a platform for tinkering at the margins (with the debate
about expansion of the UN Security Council being perhaps the best and
most circular as well as most unlikely to occur example)?
Perhaps the starkest illustration of why we need a serious debate
about how the world is organized and governed is because we have not
been good at accounting for, or indeed spotting, change and continuity.
The end of the Cold War has been endlessly picked over, but a humbling
bottomline is that no scholarly or policy community saw it coming. This
momentous change escaped prediction, but so too did the unintended
consequences of what might happen if UN involvement in complex
emergencies were to cease suddenly--as in the wake of US withdrawal from
Somalia in 1992. In so doing--and despite many warnings of what was
about to ensue--we helped the policy world sit back while genocide raged
in Rwanda.
Equally, we have been slow to understand the role that new actors
have come to play in the global economy. The call for market
deregulation and rolling back state intervention in the 1980s and 1990s
opened up more space for private involvement in the governance of global
affairs. Some of the more notorious actors have been subjected to
sustained analysis by IR scholars--credit-rating agencies and private
military companies being perhaps the two most obvious' 7--butwe
still do not have a good handle on the role of markets, the power and
influence of transnational corporations, or the costs of such nefarious
actors as organized criminal networks. Even more basically, we have
little appreciation of the significance of public-private partnerships
in shaping the world in which we live; for instance, the precise role of
private firms in setting standards for food and health.18 Crucially, we
have not explained sufficiently how power and authority in the current
world order changed from those that we took for granted when scholars
such as Hans J. Morgenthau were interested in questions of global
arrangement. (19)
If we have been blind to, or at the very least distracted from,
changes in the nature of power and authority within and across the world
in the post World War II era, we have been even less sensitive to the
drivers of change and their significance as we have moved from one world
order to another. We use the language of Pax Britannica and Pax
Americana, yet seldom offer a compelling account not only of what
changed but why and how that change took place. Organizing principles
are a key, but not the only part of explaining this puzzle. What Craig
Murphy calls the "Inter-Imperial World" of the nineteenth
centwy (20)--in which European empires competed with one another over
land, resources, power, and influence--was not organized simply by a
compact among France, Austria, Prussia, Russia, and the United Kingdom
to secure coexistence. The Concert of Europe explained how the
interimperial world was governed only to the extent that it managed to
mitigate, but not eradicate, war among the European empires. There is no
explanation about the principles by which the rest of the world was
organized--the ideas of racial segregation, les missions civilatrices as
proxies for subjugation, the tutelage of "races yet unable to stand
on their own two feet" as justifications for colonization, and the
use of terra nullius and other cartographic inscriptions as reasons for
conquest and acquisition.
Clearly, somewhere in the grand ideas that informed the
interimperial system of global governance--we have been using this term
only since the 1990s, but the reality of governance for the world
existed long before--were both good and reprehensible interests. We have
yet to grasp, however, the exact forms of organintion that became
concrete on the basis of these principles; the sources of power and
forms of authority that they established, generated, and entrenched; and
the consequences that they produced.
We are just as far, however, from understanding the forms of
governing the world that result from the new ordering principles of US
hegemony. These principles--self-determination and economic
liberalization to name the two most prominent--also blended progress and
self-interest. Self-determination was a genuine means of enabling
colonized peoples to govern themselves, but also a way of opening
colonial systems formerly more closed to US business; economic
liberalization was both a commitment to a free flow of goods across the
globe and a selectively applied policy that fell short of opening up key
sectors to external competition (of which agriculture is perhaps the
most significant). These principles gave rise to forms of formal and
informal organization that have shaped the world around us, and they
have changed and mutated over time.
A key missing element is the how and why of moving from the inter
imperial world to Pax Americana. The Quaker economist Kenneth Bouldin.g
often quipped with great wisdom, "We are where we are because we
got there."2I Yet to truly comprehend how we have arrived at
contemporary forms of order and organization--as many are continuations
of, or responses to, prior incarnations--we need to understand how
global governance avant le mot was manifested and altered over time as
well as how competing forms coexisted. This lacuna is not only important
when considering the competing forms of global governance that the Cold
War facilitated, or the harrowing counterfactuals that a Nazi system
would have generated, but also how much older forms of world order
coexisted over the centuries. Only then can we understand how and why we
got to where we are. And only then can we go to where we want to go by
getting there.
Thus, how the world is organized is a perquisite foundation for
where we should and could be going. A plan for a better world is
conspicuous by its absence. Instead of a grand debate about how to make
the world fairer and more habitable, at best we formulate policies to
muddle through and at worst justify ingenious ways to argue that
dramatic change is unfeasible and beyond the pale. We do ourselves, the
field, and the planet no service by removing from our job descriptions
the need to put forward or actively debate alternative visions of more
desirable future world orders.
Consider for a moment another academic field that allows us to
embroider these points further. Economics is the discipline that
encouraged many of us in IR to be more scientific about the way that we
do our work. Yet what we call "mainstream" or
"orthodox" economics is as normative as many of the heterodox approaches that challenge it. It has clear ideas about what forms of
organization and governance should prevail, how scarce resources should
be allocated, and what kinds of policy ought to be put in place to bring
about their realization--albeit they are presented as "fact"
and "law."We are not suggesting that we mimic the values and
imagined futures held by mainstream economists, but rather we are
recommending that IR make more room for clearer visions of what the
world should look like, how it should be ordered, and how we should get
there. This space should be a, if not the, staple of IR. And to be
clear, we are not arguing here for a single vision of the future.
Rather, in letting the proverbial hundred flowers blossom, we as a
scholarly community can at least debate how the world ought to be
organized rather than passively accept how it is.
The comparison with economics is worth pursuing further. Our lack
of appreciation for what drives change in the way that our world is
organized renders IR as a broad intellectual undertaking ahistorical.
(22) "History" might be something that we introduce to
students in the opening lectures of an introductory IR class, but we
tend to carefully circumscribe it: either treating history as an
empirical treasure trove wherein we can find examples that fit or can be
made to fit the way that we choose to explain the world, or else
concentrating so narrowly on concepts or particular issues that the
lessons from studying historical developments are obscured. IR, properly
framed, has a great deal to offer in seeking answers to such broad
social science questions as to why some countries are rich and others
are poor. While economic historians, for instance, approach this
question by looking for the drivers of growth, a concern with how the
world is governed and how this governance has changed over time could
help those of us in IR to better understand the forms of organization
that have contributed to the prosperity enjoyed by some states and the
poverty suffered by the vast majority of others.
For instance, Murphy's International Organization and
Industrial Change illuminates the role played by international
organizations as modes of governance in advancing forms of economic
accumulation. (23) His work with JoAnne Yates on what we have called
"creeping global governance" (24) shows how minute,
functionalist developments that standardize economic behavior and social
norms lock in place systems of command and control that give rise to
particular economic outcomes and social goods (some beneficial, some
not). Murphy and Yates are notable exceptions in a field that has
consistently failed to account for change, particularly in systems of
governance.25 Even this ray of light, however, is obscured and only
enables us to peer back into the relatively recent past and not into
epochs of global governance gone by. If global governance is a
legitimate analytical tool, it has to explain change not just today or
in the post--Cold War era, but in other times and under other
circumstances.
It thus is clear that IR must have something to offer if we turn
our attention back to big questions--at least if we engage in exploring
global governance. The data clearly show that those countries that were
the richest in 1820 are almost invariably those that have prospered the
most since (more often than not, dramatically), not just in crude
measures like per capita income (26) but also in health and other social
indicators. (27) We also know that it is from this period that the forms
of global organization that we recognize today as international
institutions were nascent and in the ascendancy, taking off with gusto
from the 1850s--though we should be careful not to confuse
"international institutions" with "global
governance" as they are merely one specific, historically
contingent element. European and later US power was consolidated through
complex forms of command and control, and the opportunities enabled by
these systems partially explain the dramatic and growing prosperity of
those countries that were already doing well at the outset of the
nineteenth century. Yet almost no one has sought to demonstrate how
global governance and order have contributed to the accumulation of
wealth for and improved morbidity of some and the relative and absolute
impoverishment of others.
We should be extending such questions backward as well as forward.
By so doing, we might realize how earlier forms of organization
contributed to the success and demise of particular regimes and
civilizations, which in turn could contribute to our knowledge about how
best, and best not, to govern the contemporary world. The examination of
how some orders mutated--such as the morphing of the Roman Empire into
the Holy Roman Empire or, via a slightly "bumpy" route, the
Holy See and Papacy today (28)--could shed light on the forms of
governance and principles of organization that generated greater
propensities to peace, war, growth, or atrophy. Rome and ancient China
are useful examples here in terms of both the perceived differences
between the empires and the similarities in their internal and external
forms of governance. (29) Moreover, there are interesting questions of
transitions between, mergers of, and interrelationships among imperial
systems that help us better understand the governance of the ancient and
not so ancient worlds that are part of the alloy that has helped forge
our own world order.
Equally, the mechanisms by which empires were governed--the forms
of administration, organization, and arrangement--could tell us much
about elements of contemporary political contestation as well as about
the forms of order that we almost had and should seek to avoid. The
British use of islands as prisons, as places of forced exile, and as
spaces to be emptied for colonial need is an example of a form of
imperial governance that continues to have reverberations. (30) The
fascist economic tributary systems attempted by Nazi Germany and
Imperial Japan during the 1930s were unequal forms of interstate
organization that stand as examples of precisely the kind of global
governance that we should avoid. (31) As British social historian Ralph
Fox put it in the 1930s, "the existence of the Empire exercises a
decisive influence on the life, and very often also the death, of every
British-born man or woman." (32) Clearly, it also exercised a
dramatic influence on the lives of colonial subjects. And investigating
how this and other forms of organization--the worthy as well as the to
be avoided--affect and have affected ordinary lives is a key motivation
for better understanding the kind of global governance that we have and
have had.
Making Global Governance Fit for
Purpose in the Twenty-first Century
There is a structural problem with implementing our recommendation
to begin an lR fieldwide debate about how the world is organized; why we
have the forms of governance that we currently have; what forms of
organization and order existed in other epochs worldwide; and how we
ought to construct better planetary (or otherwise) systems of command
and control. That underlying problem is the feeble intellectual traction
of global governance itself. If it is to be made fit for purpose in this
century, the term needs serious attention.
At its simplest, global governance should encourage us to ask
questions about how the world is organized, how power and authority are
exercised, and how adjustments (incremental, wholesale, or otherwise)
can be made to make the world a better place. To date, however, the term
has been so intimately wedded to a specific and contemporary moment--the
postCold War era--that its analytical purchase is feebler than it should
be. That moment saw the world as increasingly pluralistic, which
encouraged analysts of all stripes to exploit the energy and resources
of the growing number of nonstate actors to help solve problems that
were (and continue to be) global in scale. Yet some used "global
governance" almost interchangeably with "international
organization." Some worried that it was a proxy for world
government--which, as Robert Cox so aptly points out, is just one
conceivable form among many. (33) Some were disparaging and too narrowly
wedded to the notion that governance is the action of government and,
thus, global governance must be what states as principals and their
agents--intergovernmental organizations, especially the United Nations
(34)--do in the absence of a central authority. It is no wonder that
Finkelstein pointed to the kitchen sink in the first volume of this
journal. (35)
The genius of coining the term global governance lay in James
Rosenau and Ernst Czempiel's original 1992 formulation as
"governance" without "government"--the idea that
myriad forms of authority and formal as well as informal processes
could--singularly, or in tandem or concert--exercise governance (i.e.,
shaping and, to varying degrees, steering aspects of global life)
without necessarily being connected to formal govemment. (36) Moreover,
they pointed out that these forms of authority, and the mechanisms
through which they operated as well as their guiding principles and
overarching ideas and ideologies, existed at all levels of world
politics. They interacted with one another in specific ways in given
contexts, and they often produced contradictory outcomes and
countervailing tendencies. However, the bottom line was clear: the sum
was a discernible form of governance that was better ordered than we
might have expected.
It is working out the total sum as well as what constitutes it,
along with the contradictions and countervailing forces that exist
therein, that are the real purposes of an inquiry into global
governance. Yet how many of us assign to our students Rosenau and
Czempiel's original book, or indeed Rosenau's landmark
statement about command and control in the first issue of this
jour-nal?37 We suspected--and confirmed by a brief survey of available
course syllabi on international organization and global governance from
universities across the world--very few. Why? Because these texts are
difficult, and their meaning is obscured by a struggle to understand
just what was going on in the post--Cold War moment.
Chief among a host of thorny problems resulting from the widespread
confusion about the term's meaning is our failure to recognize that
the global governance of the 1990s and early 2000s is different from the
kind of global governance that existed in the nineteenth century, the
first millennium CE, or indeed today. We should recognize that global
governance, if it makes sense at all, is not merely a descriptor for a
post--Cold War pluralistic moment but rather is a legitimate set of
questions about how the world is governed, ordered, and organized in
every historical period.
Historical change is perhaps the best point of departure for a
wider debate to overcome the contemporary and seemingly ever growing
fragmentation and atomization of IR. Put differently, if we apply the
same kinds of questions that led to understanding global governance as a
pluralization of world politics at the end of the last century, we
should also be able to determine what kinds of systems of world order
existed before the current one, and how power and authority were
exercised therein. We should have insights about the ultimate drivers of
change and their impact. Our argument is that a deeper investigation of
contemporary global governance can potentially capture accurately how
power is exercised across the globe, how a multiplicity of actors relate
to one another generally as well as on specific issues, how to make
better sense of global complexity, and how to account for alterations in
the way that the world is and has been organized (or governed) over
time--both within and between historical periods.
However, wrenching global governance from the contemporary moment
and applying it historically is half the battle. This move backward
would have limited salience if it also was not a valuable approach to
understanding tomorrow. The future-oriented value lies in treating
global governance as a set of questions that enable us to work out how
the world was, is, and could be governed as well as how changes in grand
and not so grand patterns of governance occurred, are occurring, and
ought to occur. In short, if we have nothing to say about how the world
was, is, and should and could be governed, we should wonder whether what
we are actually doing qualifies as international relations.
Saving IR?
We have an advantage in trying to save IR from tumbling into an
abyss that other disciplines do not necessarily have. We have a captive
audience and we will be employed because what we do is associated with
the big events of today--terrorism, torture, recession, rising powers,
poverty, proliferation, atrocities, climate change, famine, pandemics,
and the list goes on--and our students continue to see international
careers as attractive. Yet we should not underestimate the problems that
will arise if we do not stem and reverse the field's ever growing
atomization, begin to talk more with one another, and address serious
questions about improving the way that the world is gov-erned--all part
of what global governance should push us to explore. It is a pursuit, a
set of questions, a form of inquiry. Ultimately, we are interested in
different manifestations of global governance and how they transition,
mutate, change, and develop.
If global governance does not come to the rescue of IR, we active
participants in the field may retain the dignity of the condemned
walking to the gallows in George Orwell's retelling of "a
hanging." (38) We may step aside and temporarily avoid treading in
a puddle of rainwater in our way. The outcome will nonetheless be the
same.
Notes
Thomas G. Weiss is presidential professor of political science and
director of the Ralph Bunche Institute for International Studies at the
City University of New York's Graduate Center. He is past president
of the International Studies Association (20092010). His recent
single-authored books include Governing the World? Addressing
"Problems Without Passports" (2014); Global Governance: Why?
What? Whither? (2013); Humanitarian Business (2013); What's Wrong
with the United Nations and How to Fix 11 (2012); and Humanitarian
Intervention: Ideas in Action (2012).
Rorden Wilkinson is professor of international political economy in
the School of Social Sciences and research director of the Brooks World
Poverty Institute at the University of Manchester. His recent books
include What's Wrong with the WTO and How to Fix It (2014); The
Millennium Development Goals and Beyond (2012); Trade, Poverty,
Development (2012); Global Governance, Poverty and Inequality (2010);
and The WTO: Crisis and the Governance of Global Trade (2006).
Weiss and Wilkinson are coeditors of International Organization and
Global Governance (2014) and the Routledge Global Institutions Series.
A Spanish-translation of this article has been published in Foro
Internacional, the journal of the Center for International Studies at El
Colegio de Mexico, vol. 53, no. 3-4 (July--December 2013), under an
agreement between Global Governance and Fora to simultaneously publish
two articles. The editors of both journals feel that sharing our work
will spark greater collaboration between our readers.
(1.) Notable exceptions are Andrew Hurrell, On Global Order: Power,
Values and the Constitution of International Society (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 2008); Philip G. Cerny, Rethinking World Politics: A
Theory of Transnational Neopluralism (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2010).
(2.) Lawrence Finkelstein, "What Is Global Governance?"
Global Governance I. no. 3 (1995): 368.
(3.) Henry Teune's history of the International Studies
Association's first twenty five years,
www.isanet.org/Portals/O/Documents/Institutional/Henry_Teune_The
_ISA_1982.pd. More recent figures provided by the ISA secretariat.
(4.) See Richard Jordan, Daniel Maliniak, Amy Oakes, Susan
Peterson, and Michael J. Tierney, One Discipline or Many? TRIP Survey of
International Relations Faculty in Ten Countries (Williamsburg, VA:
College of William and Mary, 2009); Nicola Phillips and Catherine
Weaver, eds., International Political Economy: Debating the Past,
Present and Future (London: Routledge, 2011); Steve Smith, "The
Discipline of International Relations: Still an American Social
Science?" British Journal of Politics and International Relations
2, no. 3 (2000): 374-402.
(5.) Daniel W. Drezner, Theories of International Relations and
Zombies (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2011).
(6.) See, for example, Jennifer Hart Weed, Richard Brian David, and
Ronald Weed, eds., 24 and Philosophy: The World According to Jack
(Oxford: Blackwell, 2008).
(7.) Carol Cohn, "Sex and Death in the Rational World of
Defense Intellectuals," Signs 12, no. 4 (1987): 687-718.
(8.) Michael N. Barnett, "The UN Security Council,
Indifference, and Genocide in Rwanda," Cultural Anthropology 12,
no. 4 (1997): 551-578.
(9.) Steve Smith, "Six Wishes for a More Relevant Discipline
of International Relations," in Christian Reus-Smit and Duncan
Snidal, eds., The Oxford Handbook of International Relations (Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2008), pp. 725-732. See also Ole Wxver,
"Still a Discipline After All These Debates?" in Tim Dunne,
Milja Kurki, and Steve Smith, eds., International Relations Theories:
Discipline and Diversity, 3rd ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2013), pp. 306-328.
(10.) Margot Light and A. J. R. Groom, eds., International
Relations: A Handbook of Current Theory (London: Pinter, 1993).
(11.) David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The
Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993).
(12.) Yosef Lapid, "The Third Debate: On the Prospects of
International Theory in a Post-positivist Era," International
Studies Quarterly 33, no. 3 (1989): 235-254; Richard Ned Lebow, A
Cultural Theory of International Relations (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2009); Jeffrey T. Checkel, "The Constructivist
Turn in International Relations Theory," World Politics 50, no. 2
(1998): 324-348.
(13.) See, for example, Richard Price and Christian Reus-Smit,
"Dangerous Liaisons? Critical International Theory and
Constructivism," European Journal of International Relations 4, no.
3 (1998): 259-294.
(14.) Thomas G. Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson, "Rethinking Global
Governance: Complexity, Authority, Power, Change," International
Studies Quarterly 58, no. 2 (forthcoming).
(15.) See, for example, Jennifer Clapp and Eric Helleiner,
"Troubled Futures? The Global Food Crisis and the Politics of
Agricultural Derivatives Regulation," Review of International
Political Economy 19, no. 2 (2012): 181-207.
(16.) John M. Hobson and Leonard Seabrooke, eds., Everyday Politics
of the World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007).
(17.) Timothy Sinclair, "Credit-rating Agencies," in
Thomas G. Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson, eds., International Organization
and Global Governance (London: Routledge, 2014), pp. 349-359; Peter J.
Hoffman, "Private Military and Security Companies," in Thomas
G. Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson, eds., International Organization and
Global Governance (London: Routledge, 2014), pp. 385-396.
(18.) Axel Marx et al., eds., Private Standards and Global
Governance: Economic, Legal and Political Perspectives (Cheltenham, UK:
Edward Elgar, 2012).
(19.) Hans J. Morgenthau, Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for
Power and Peace (New York: McGraw-Hill. 1948).
(20.) Craig Murphy, International Organization and Industrial
Change: Global Governance Since 1850 (Cambridge, UK: Polity, 1994).
(21.) Elise Boulding, "Interview in Needham, Massachusetts by
Thomas G. Weiss in the United Nations Intellectual History Project, 16
April 2001," in Thomas G. Weiss, Tatiana Carayannis, Louis Emmerij,
and Richard Jolly, eds., The Complete Oral History Transcripts from UN
Voices (New York: Ralph Bunche Institute for International Studies,
2007), CD-ROM.
(22.) Andrew J. Williams, Amelia Hadfield, and Simon J. Rofe,
International History and International Relations (London: Routledge,
2012),
(23.) Murphy, International Organization and Industrial Change.
(24.) Thomas G. Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson, "International
Organization and Global Governance: What Matters and Why," in
Thomas G. Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson, eds., International Organization
and Global Governance (London: Routledge, 2014). pp. 1-22.
(25.) Craig Murphy and JoAnne Yates, The International Organization
for Standardization (ISO) (London: Routledge, 2009).
(26.) Robert C. Allen, Global Economic History: A Very Short
Introduction (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011), pp. 3-5.
(27.) Erik S. Reinert, How Rich Countries Got Rich and Why Poor
Countries Stay Poor (New York: Public Affairs, 2008).
(28.) Peter Heather, Empires and Barbarians: The Fall of Rome and
the Birth of Europe (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009).
(29.) Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative
Perspectives on Ancient World Empires (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2009).
(30.) See Taylor C. Sherman, "From Hell to Paradise? Voluntary
Transfer of Convicts to the Andaman Islands 1921-40," Modern Asian
Studies 43, no. 2 (2009): 367388; Uma Kothari and Rorden Wilkinson,
"Colonial Imaginaries and Postcolonial Transformations: Exiles,
Bases, Beaches," Third World Quarterly 31, no. 8 (2010): 1395-1412;
David Vine, Island of Shame: The Secret History of the U.S. Military
Base on Diego Garcia (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2009).
(31.) See John Gerard Ruggie, "Multilateralism: The Anatomy of
an Institution," International Organization 46, no. 3 (1992):
568-569; Louise Young, Japan's Total Empire: Manchuria and the
Culture of Wartime Imperialism (Los Angeles: University of California
Press, 1999).
(32.) Ralph Fox, The Colonial Policy of British Imperialism (1933;
reprint, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008), p. 1.
(33.) Robert W. Cox, ed., The New Realism: Perspectives on
Multilateralism and World Order (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1997).
(34.) Thomas G. Weiss and Ramesh Thakur, Global Governance and the
UN: An Unfinished Journey (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 2010).