Institutional interactions at the crossroads of trade and environment: the dominance of liberal environmentalism?
Zelli, Fariborz ; Gupta, Aarti ; Van Asselt, Harro 等
This article argues that institutional interactions that cut across
the domains of trade and environment are embedded in overarching norms
that shape their evolution and impact. In making this argument it
analyzes three cases of such interactions within the climate change and
biosafety regime complexes: those relating to trade-related climate
policies and measures, forest carbon sinks, and trade in genetically
modified organisms. The analysis highlights the dominance of liberal
environmentalism (a set of global norms promoting economic efficiency
and environmental improvements through market-based mechanisms) in
shaping institutional interactions within these regime complexes, even
as liberal environmentalism is contested by key actors. This, in turn,
has implications for effective management of institutional interlinkages
within regime complexes in global environmental governance. KEYWORDS:
biodiversity, biosafety, climate change, forestry, genetically modified
organisms, institutional interactions, institutional interlinkages,
neolib-eral environmentalism, regime complex, trade.
FOR NEARLY TWENTY YEARS NOW, THE GLOBAL GOVERNANCE LITERATURE HAS
enhanced understanding about interplay among international institutions,
including in global environmental governance. The focus of such
research, however, has been, as Arild Underdal puts it, "primarily
on interaction at the level of specific regimes and less on links to the
kind of basic ordering principles or norms highlighted in realist and
sociological analyses of institutions"; (1) in other words, less on
explanatory approaches based on constellations of power, competing
knowledge claims, normative structures, or other factors. As Amandine Orsini, Jean-Frederic Morin, and Oran Young illustrate in this issue,
the notion of regime complexes has been one important response to such
critiques. (2) In this article, we seek to take this research and policy
agenda further by advancing a norms-based explanation of institutional
interactions within regime complexes in global environmental governance.
(3)
Our point of departure is that a regime and its provisions and
procedures cannot be understood in isolation from the broader normative
context within which it is embedded, as, for instance, Ken Conca also
convincingly argues. (4) This insight applies to the policy domains of
security, human rights, and trade, and just as much to the environment.
As do other factors, for example, the constellation of interests
(Jean-Frederic Morin and Amandine Orsini, in this issue) or
institutional dynamics (Dries Lesage and Thijs Van de Graaf, in this
issue), underlying norms guide the behavior of actors within a specific
regime and thereby shape its design and development. Such an approach
also highlights that the generation and persistence of norms require
shared expectations and purposes among actors; hence, that agency
remains important and relevant. (5)
We hold, furthermore, that the normative structures that shape
individual regimes also impact interactions between regimes and,
consequently, regime complexes. If regimes express or reflect broader
norms, then it follows that regime interactions and regime complexes may
be sites for contestation over different norms. This applies in
particular to regime complexes that cut across more than one global
governance domain (e.g., environment and trade). Such complexes are
shaped by collusion or contestation over the broader norms that underpin
these domains--with the likelihood that certain norms will dominate.
Steven Bernstein's influential analysis posits, for example,
the dominance in a global environmental governance context of what he
terms the "compromise of liberal environmentalism." (6) This
comprises the norms of economic efficiency and environmental
improvements through unfettered markets, deregulation, and
privatization, with reliance on market-based governance mechanisms where
necessary. (7) Building on Bernstein's insights here, we argue that
liberal environmentalism shapes not only the provisions and practices of
specific environmental regimes, but also their interactions with the
global trade regime and other international institutions. Ultimately, it
also dominates whole complexes of regimes that address specific subjects
at the intersection of international trade and the environment. In turn,
regime complexes are sites for promulgating, but also for constantly
challenging, the dominance of liberal environmentalism.
While space constraints do not permit a comprehensive assessment of
this claim, we illustrate its added value in a comparative manner by
briefly applying it to three cases of institutional interactions that
are embedded within the regime complexes on climate change and
biosafety. These three cases are: the interaction between the UN climate
regime and the World Trade Organization (WTO) on trade-related climate
policies and measures; the interaction between the UN climate regime and
the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) on forest carbon sinks; and
the interaction between the CBD's Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety and the WTO on trade in genetically modified organisms (GM0s).
In each case, several developments hint at the dominance of liberal
environmentalism in shaping the nature of these interactions and their
outcomes. Yet we also show that this dominance is being contested across
the cases we examine, a trend that is partly mirrored in recent regime
changes.
Trade-related Climate Policies and Measures
The climate change regime complex encompasses institutions whose
mandate includes trade-related policies and measures by which countries
are to achieve reductions in greenhouse gas emissions. We restrict our
analysis here to the core interaction between the UN climate regime,
comprising the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and
the Kyoto Protocol, and the trade regime of the WTO--especially
regarding emissions reductions by industrialized countries under the
Kyoto Protocol. This notwithstanding, the climate change regime complex
comprises a large array of additional institutional arrangements of
relevance to climate and trade, including a series of transnational and
multilateral technology partnerships on climate and energy as well as
bilateral and multilateral trade agreements. (8)
In both the climate and trade regimes, scholarly analyses suggest
that a US-led coalition was "highly influential in establishing a
market approach to managing climate change." (9) The Umbrella
Group, comprising the United States and various non-European Union
(non-EU) industrialized countries, tabled initiatives for WTO-compliant
elements in the Kyoto Protocol, especially the flexibility mechanisms.
Moreover, accommodating the interests of their domestic industries, the
group successfully rejected trade-restrictive proposals by the EU for a
binding list of policies and measures and their mandatory coordination
as well as those for quantitative limits to the use of flexibility
mechanisms. (10) The EU had advanced such proposals owing to its
self-acclaimed leadership role in climate negotiations. But European
determination for binding policies and measures was also
"predicated, in part, on the fear that the US would never accept
legally binding [emission] targets." (11) Developing countries
largely seconded the Umbrella Group's opposition to trade
restrictions, fearing that such policies would become a form of
"green protectionism." (12) Since the adoption of the Kyoto
Protocol in 1997, moreover, decisions under the UNFCCC have avoided
major trade-restrictive modalities altogether. Eventually, the EU has
also become a major advocate of market-based climate governance
mechanisms, most prominently with its leading emissions trading scheme.
In the WTO, in particular in its Committee on Trade and
Environment, a group of non-EU industrialized countries, including the
United States, has again effectively prevented legal concessions toward
trade-related provisions of environmental regimes, a position supported
by many developing countries as well. This reluctance is in line with
these countries' "desire to preserve their immunity as
non-parties to some significant [multilateral environmental agreements]
from multilateral 'anti-competitive' environmental
commitments." (13) The WTO dispute settlement mechanism hence
remains the most likely arena where overlaps between the trade and
climate regimes might be settled. (14) In line with this, the compliance
mechanism of the climate regime does not include trade sanctions for
greenhouse gas--intensive products, even though these were proposed by
the EU. (15)
These positional differences between the United States and
developing countries on one side and the EU on the other--and the
market-based WTO-compatible compromises arising out of such
differences--correspond to underlying sets of norms in global
governance. The observed reluctance of the United States and developing
countries toward trade-restrictive measures can be seen as embedded in
liberal environmentalism, replacing an earlier dominance of slightly
more trade-skeptical discourses prior to the 1990s. (16) In the case of
climate change, liberal environmentalism implies a focus on efficiency
gains from technological innovation, the diffusion of climate-friendly
goods through trade, and the promotion of emissions trading over
traditional regulation. It claims synergistic aspects among trade and
environment, while sidelining detrimental ones.
The dominance of liberal environmentalism reveals itself not only
in the rejection of certain regulatory proposals, but also in a process
of self-censorship. Ever since the Kyoto summit, negotiators, including
those from the EU, have increasingly refrained from tabling ambitious
proposals for trade-restrictive climate protection measures such as
mandatory coordination of policies. This is in part because members of
the UN climate regime want to avoid legal challenges and potential
sanctions against them via the WT0. (17)
Recent developments suggest, however, that the dominance of liberal
environmentalism is increasingly being challenged in the climate-trade
arena. Robyn Eckersley, for example, discerns a "generic
counter-discourse" in statements from environmental nongovernmental
organizations (NGOs) or green think tanks. (18) Moreover, the past years
have witnessed a shift of interests in US domestic politics toward more
trade-restrictive approaches, but in order to safeguard domestic
industries rather than for environmental reasons. For instance, the US
Congress has discussed legislative proposals requesting purchase of
emissions allowances for imported goods to be allowed to enter the
country. The EU has also begun considering similar measures to equally
address growing concerns about the competitiveness of its industries.
(19) The debate on border carbon adjustments within and beyond both
regimes hints at a possible questioning of the dominance of liberal
environmentalism in this regime complex. However, this development might
simply reflect that safeguarding industries and jobs has become a
primary concern, rather than implying a shift away from a broader
liberalist norm.
In sum we find evidence for a strong, but increasingly contested,
role of liberal environmentalism in this regime complex--with the United
States and developing countries largely pushing for more market-liberal
approaches and the EU, especially at Kyoto and in the years after its
adoption, failing to establish more trade-restrictive measures. But the
analysis also suggests that our norms-based lens needs to be
complemented by power- and interest-based approaches to provide a more
complete picture of the underlying reasons for these developments.
Forest Carbon Sinks
Thanks to the emergence of the issue of reducing emissions from
deforestation and degradation (REDD) on the climate policy agenda, the
climate change regime complex has expanded considerably in recent years.
It now also encompasses public and transnational institutions, which
address the overlap among climate, biodiversity, and forestry, and whose
mandates are either forest-focused (e.g., the Forest Stewardship Council and the International Tropical Timber Organization) or forest-related
(e.g., the CBD and the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations). (20)
Within the regime complex, one of the main institutional
interactions concerns the UN climate and biodiversity regimes on which
we focus in this section. Whereas the UNFCCC and Kyoto Protocol are
aimed at reducing greenhouse gas emissions with a view toward avoiding
dangerous climate impacts, the CBD seeks to promote the conservation and
sustainable use of biodiversity as well as the fair and equitable
sharing of benefits arising from the utilization of genetic resources.
Overlaps between the two regimes have emerged in the implementation
stages of the Kyoto Protocol, particularly relating to the inclusion of
forests as carbon sinks in the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), and
finally in the design of REDD as a climate mitigation strategy.
Including forest carbon sinks in emissions accounting, and
especially in the CDM, has been a controversial issue since the 1990s.
While the inclusion of sinks in the CDM lowers the cost of compliance
with Kyoto targets, critics argue that the rules on CDM sinks do not
sufficiently safeguard biodiversity concerns and could frustrate the
objectives of the CBD. The main concerns raised are that current rules
allow for projects that result in destructive large-scale, monoculture plantations and the use of invasive alien species and GMOs. (21)
Similarly, while a future REDD mechanism provides an opportunity to
cost-effectively reduce emissions through tackling deforestation, its
specific design may lead to either positive or negative impacts on
biodiversity. (22)
The inclusion of sinks in the CDM is closely related to the
emergence of market-based mechanisms in the climate regime in general.
Despite its withdrawal from the Kyoto Protocol in 2001, the United
States has been influential in the CDM sinks discussion. (23) Since the
inception of the climate regime, it has sought to expand opportunities
for using market-based mechanisms, including through the use of sinks.
(24) Referring to the United States and other countries in the Umbrella
Group, Karin Backstrand and Eva Lovbrand identify flexibility,
cost-effectiveness, and a "seductive narrative of 'maximized
synergies'" as the key elements of the "legitimizing
discourse" for the inclusion of sinks in the CDM. (25) Northern
countries favoring the inclusion of sinks in the CDM have emphasized the
cost-saving potential of expanding the scope of the mechanism while
countries in the South have highlighted various cobenefits, including
financial and technology transfers.
These legitimizing discourses again reflect a norm of liberal
environmentalism that favors market-based approaches to environmental
governance. Nonetheless, they also remain contested, as is evident from
ongoing efforts by different actors, such as the EU and the Alliance of
Small Island States, (26) to push for consideration of biodiversity
concerns in the climate regime. Backstrand and Lovbrand argue that
persisting concerns expressed about sinks in the CDM are part of a
"critical discourse" that contests a dominant market-oriented
liberal environmentalist perspective. (27) This critical discourse not
only underlines the potentially negative effects on biodiversity, but
also draws attention to the social and equity aspects of including sinks
in the CDM as well as the use of market-based mechanisms more generally.
The discourse, which found support among NGOs as well as some developing
countries, provides an explanation for the push to include biodiversity
considerations in a REDD mechanism by NGOs, scientists, and several
parties to the UNFCCC. (28) Such efforts to incorporate biodiversity
concerns may increase the costs of compliance and indirectly challenge
the dominance of the norm of liberal environmentalism. While it is clear
that biodiversity concerns are not completely ignored in the UN climate
regime, parties have yet to give biodiversity conservation a prominent
place.
In short this case shows that, instigated by the United States but
also supported by other developed and developing countries,
market-liberal approaches have so far dominated rule development in the
UN climate regime, potentially at the detriment of biodiversity
concerns. However, the EU, small island states, and a host of NGOs have
increasingly sought to contest this dominance by pushing for rules that
seek to enhance the integrity of the mechanisms on forest carbon sinks
adopted under the UNFCCC, in part because of the consequences for
biological diversity.
Trade in Genetically Modified Organisms
The regime complex on biosafety comprises a number of institutions
that, from the 1980s onward, have made "attempts to span and occupy
the newly emerging regulatory field of international trade in
genetically modified organisms." (29) These include, inter alia,
the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, the UN
Industrial Development Organization, the World Health Organization, the
UN Environment Programme, and the Food and Agriculture Organization. But
from the mid-1990s, the WTO and the biosafety treaty under the CBD have
been the major contenders vying for regulatory authority. Here, we
concentrate on the interaction between these two institutions.
The relationship between the Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety under
the CBD and the WTO's Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and
Phytosanitary Measures (SPS agreement) has been highly scrutinized,
given the potential for trade in GMOs to be restricted under the
Cartagena Protocol. (30) Two key aspects have been under scrutiny: the
interpretation of what constitutes precautionary restrictions on trade
in each institution and the extent to which the Cartagena
Protocol's calls for stringent information-sharing prior to GMO trade might conflict with global trade rules.
The Cartagena Protocol seeks to ensure safe trade in GMOs by
calling for the "advance informed agreement" of an importing
country prior to such trade. The notion of advance informed agreement
derives from the longer-established "prior informed consent"
relied on in a global context to govern trade in hazardous wastes and
restricted chemicals. Prior informed consent is explicitly intended to
be a compromise between the two extremes of an outright ban on risky
trade and a lack of any restrictions through caveat emptor ("let
the buyer beware"). (31)
Yet the overarching normative context within which this regulatory
compromise is being interpreted remains contested, as is evident from
how advance informed agreement is being institutionalized within the
Cartagena Protocol. Informed agreement was promoted within the protocol
by the EU and many developing countries as a way to govern GMO risks by
calling for stringent information disclosure and the possibility of
precautionary restrictions on trade. In contrast, it has been
interpreted by the United States and other GMO-producing countries as a
vehicle to ensure efficiency in decisionmaking and to facilitate
trade--through minimal information disclosure and decisions based on
sound science rather than precaution. (32)
On both counts (precautionary restrictions and information
disclosure), institutional interactions between the Cartagena Protocol
and the WTO suggest a dominance of a liberal environmentalist approach
to global GMO governance. This is evident, for example, from the
narrowly circumscribed language on precaution eventually adopted within
the protocol, which is not incompatible with the formulation in the SPS
agreement. (33) On the one hand, the potential for the protocol to
institutionalize a more stringent precautionary approach to GMO trade
than that of the SPS agreement remains alive, given the always present
possibility of flexibly interpreting its provisions. Yet this potential
notwithstanding, its inclusion of precautionary language has not, to
date, directly influenced transatlantic GMO trade disputes in a manner
detrimental to trade or contrary to SPS requirements. (34)
This is partly because reliance on the Cartagena Protocol as a
bulwark against the WTO has been rendered difficult as a result of
diverse memberships across the two global regimes. Given that key GMO
exporters such as the United States have not ratified the protocol, it
has proved harder to evoke its obligations, such as they are, in
countering a push for liberalized GMO trade.
A dominance of liberal environmentalism is also discernible in how
information disclosure relating to the GMO trade is being
institutionalized within the Cartagena Protocol. These obligations, a
raison d'etre to negotiate this global treaty, remain minimally
trade-disruptive. What is more, they may even, paradoxically, have
trade-facilitating effects, given the obligations they also place on
GMO-importing countries to share information with potential exporters
about their domestic biosafety regulations. (35) As a result, there is
arguably a prioritization of market access for GMOs over biosafety
considerations in the existing GMO regime complex--an outcome aligned
with an overarching liberal environmentalist bias in global
environmental governance. (36)
Nonetheless, the dominance of a market-liberal approach does not go
wholly unchallenged in this regime complex. The ongoing transatlantic
GMO trade conflict between the United States and the EU not only goes
back to short-term economic preferences, but reflects fundamentally
divergent normative views about the appropriate aims of GMO governance
as well as the means to fulfill them. In contrast to climate change
where self-censorship by the EU has kept some market- or
trade-restrictive approaches from being proposed or adopted, in the GMO
case the EU has consistently pushed for trade-restrictive policies in
all global GMO regulatory fora, even as the United States has
consistently opposed them.
This normative transatlantic tension endures partly because the
very existence of a governance problem remains contested here. The US
position is that there is no need for global GMO governance since GMOs
are not intrinsically hazardous. Given this US view it is harder to push
back decisively against a privileging of open markets and trade
facilitation, even though the EU, supported by many developing
countries, continually demands the flexibility to do so.
In sum, this case suggests that liberal environmentalism dominates
in institutionalizing regulatory responses to global GMO governance,
even as it is consistently contested by the EU and other GMO-importing
(developing) countries. This flags an issue meriting further attention
in going beyond the norm-based approach adopted here: how contestation
over liberal environmentalism is shaped by the specific global political
economy of GMO trade.
Conclusion
In this article, we analyzed core institutional interactions at the
interface of trade and environment in the climate change and GMO regime
complexes. We illustrated the added value of our norms-based perspective
by suggesting that the institutional interactions we examined are
embedded in overarching norms and they are characterized, to a greater
or lesser extent, by a dominance of liberal environmentalism, which is
mirrored in the interests of influential parties.
Our findings lead to a number of interesting (comparative) claims
that merit further conceptual and empirical analysis. First, in the case
of trade-related climate policies and measures, we postulate a dominance
of a liberal environmental perspective that privileges market
approaches, both through the influence of the United States and through
self-censorship of the EU. In the case of forest carbon sinks, we claim
a dominance of liberal environmentalism in how rules on sinks in the CDM
emphasize cost-effectiveness and flexibility, but potentially at the
cost of biodiversity considerations. Whether climate-induced incentives
to reduce deforestation will be synergistic or conflict with
biodiversity objectives will reveal itself only in the design of the
still-new REDD mechanism. Finally, in the case of trade in genetically
modified organisms, we suggest that a liberal environmentalist approach
to risk governance remains most contested in this realm (given the
EU's desire for stringent regulation), but it is also here that a
challenge to it is most fiercely resisted (given the US view that GMOs
do not merit global regulation in the first place).
Another intriguing aspect of our analysis is that the coalitions
promoting a liberal environmentalist view of global environmental
governance vary across issue areas. For example, developing countries
end up on different sides of a normative spectrum promoting or resisting
liberal approaches. In the climate-trade and forest carbon sinks cases,
a push back against a liberal environmentalist approach tends to line up
the EU against the United States and developing countries. But in the
GMO case. developing countries tend to ally themselves with the
EU's calls for restrictive measures like precaution and stringent
information disclosure.
In terms of policy options for dealing with institutional
interactions at the nexus of trade and environment, our findings suggest
that the usual political practice of calling for better coordination
among specific international institutions, while ignoring the
overarching norms that shape institutional interactions, is doomed to
fail. Thus, to be successful, attempts to manage such interactions in
favor of environmental goals (e.g., through a stronger integration of
certain climate or biodiversity policies under one institutional
umbrella) need to take into account the potential barriers set by
liberal environmentalism as well as influential parties whose positions
reflect this dominant set of norms.
We conclude by identifying some topics for further inquiry. First
of all, our brief case analyses were restricted to a few core
institutional interactions. Thus, to further corroborate our finding of
a dominance of liberal environmentalism, additional studies would need
to scrutinize other institutional interactions--not only within the
climate and GMO complexes, but also in others. Moreover, further
research is needed on the mutual constitution of overarching norms and
specific rules and principles. In this article, we argued that dominant
overarching norms shape specific regime rules at the crossroads of trade
and environment. Equally important, however, would be to consider how
individual regimes, institutional interactions, and entire regime
complexes constitute certain global norms and contribute to their
prevalence.
Finally, the findings from each of our cases--and the variations
across them--suggest that in addition to norms, other factors (such as
power constellations, institutional dynamics, and problem structures)
impact institutional interactions within global environmental regime
complexes. Additional studies with testable hypotheses would thus
complement norms-and discourse-based approaches like ours and could help
establish causal connections between liberal environmentalism and other
explanatory factors. These considerations serve to reiterate that there
is much explanatory ground yet to be covered to grasp the phenomenon of
institutional interactions and to provide for their effective management
in political practice.
Notes
(1.) Arild Underdal, "Determining the Causal Significance of
Institutions: Accomplishments and Challenges," paper prepared for
the conference "Institutional Dimensions of Global Environmental
Change Project Synthesis," Nusa Dua, Bali, Indonesia, December
2006, p. 9.
(2.) We would, however, prefer the term institutional complex to
regime complex, as, following Robert 0. Keohane, we consider
institutions to encompass organizations, regimes, and implicit rules.
See Robert 0. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power
(Boulder: Westview Press), p. 3. Existing analyses of such complexes
refer not only to regimes, but also to other types of international
institutions (e.g., international organizations or more informal
institutional arrangements). But for coherence's sake, and given
the broad understanding of regime complexes outlined by Orsini, Morin,
and Young, we follow the terminology of this issue.
(3.) We understand norms here as legitimate social purpose or
"collective intentionality," that is, "intersubjective
frameworks of understandings that include a shared narrative about the
conditions that make regimes [or governance more broadly] necessary and
... the objectives intended to [be] accomplish[ed]." John Gerard Ruggie, "What Makes the World Hang Together? Neo-utilitarianism and
the Social Constructivist Challenge," International Organization
52, no. 4 (1998): 855885, 870. This understanding extends beyond a focus
that is only on agreed standards of behavior or rules of conduct.
(4.) Ken Conca, Governing Water: Contentious Transnational Politics
and Global Institution Building (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2006).
(5.) John Gerard Ruggie, "Embedded Liberalism and the Postwar
Economic Regimes," in John Gerard Ruggie, ed., Constructing the
World Polity: Essays on International Institutionalization (London:
Routledge, 1998), pp. 62-84, 65.
(6.) Steven Bernstein, "Liberal Environmentalism and Global
Environmental Governance," Global Environmental Politics 2, no. 3
(2002): 1-16.
(7.) An alternative, more trade-skeptical norm would instead hold
that "trade leads to an ecologically unequal exchange" and
that "the WTO's rules permit countries to use the environment
as a free resource." See Robyn Eckersley, "Understanding the
Interplay Between the Climate and Trade Regimes," in Benjamin
Simmons, Harro van Asselt, and Fariborz Zelli, eds., Climate and Trade
Policies in a Post-2012 World (Geneva: UNEP, 2009), pp. 11-18, 15.
(8.) Thomas L. Brewer, "The WTO and the Kyoto Protocol:
Interaction Issues," Climate Policy 4, no. 1 (2004): 3-12; Thomas
L. Brewer, "The Potential of Regional and Bilateral Sectoral
Agreements," in Benjamin Simmons, Harro van Asselt, and Fariborz
Zelli, eds., Climate and Trade Policies in a Post-20I2 World (Geneva:
UNEP, 2009), pp. 65-68.
(9.) Emily Boyd. Esteve Corbera, and Manuel Estrada, "UNFCCC
Negotiations (pre-Kyoto to COP-9): What the Process Says About the
Politics of CDM-Sinks," International Environmental Agreements:
Politics, Law and Economics 8, no. 2 (2008): 95-112,106.
(10.) See Earth Negotiations Bulletin,
www.iisd.ca/enbvol/enb-background.htm: vol. 12, no. 45, p. 2; vol. 12,
no. 55, p. 4; vol. 12, no. 66, pp. 5-6; vol. 12, no. 76, p. 6; vol. 12,
no. 163, pp. 19-20.
(11.) Farhana Yamin, "The Role of the EU in Climate
Negotiations," in Joyeeta Gupta and Michael Grubb, eds., Climate
Change and European Leadership: A Sustainable Role for Europe?
(Dordrecht: Kluwer, 2000), pp. 47-66,54.
(12.) Urs P. Thomas, "Trade and the Environment: Stuck in a
Political Impasse at the WTO After the Doha and Cancun Ministerial
Conferences," Global Environmental Politics 4, no. 3 (2004): 17-18.
(13.) Alice Palmer and Richard Tarasofsky, The Doha Round and
Beyond: Towards a Lasting Relationship Between the WTO and the
International Environmental Regime (London: Royal Institute of
International Affairs, 2007), p. 16.
(14.) Kati Kulovesi, The WTO Dispute Settlement System: Challenges
of the Environment, Legitimacy and Fragmentation (Dordrecht: Kluwer Law
International, 2011), pp. 234-235; Fariborz Zelli and Harm van Asselt,
"The Overlap Between the UN Climate Regime and the World Trade
Organization: Lessons for Climate Governance Beyond 2012," in Frank
Biermann, Philipp Pattberg, and Fariborz Zelli, eds., Global Climate
Governance Beyond 2012 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010),
pp. 79-96. There are ongoing discussions on the likelihood of such a
dispute, for example, due to the profound redefinition of the WTO
dispute settlement system's stance on environmental protection
since the so-called shrimp/turtle case. For a more detailed account, see
Tracy Epps and Andrew Green, Reconciling Trade and Climate: How the WTO
Can Help Address Climate Change (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2010).
(15.) Olav Schram Stokke, "Trade Measures and Climate
Compliance: Institutional Interplay Between WTO and the Marrakesh
Accords," International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and
Economics 4, no. 4 (2004): 339-357.
(16.) Eckersley, "Understanding the Interplay," pp.
16-17.
(17.) Robyn Eckersley, "The Big Chill: The WTO and
Multilateral Environmental Agreements," Global Environmental
Politics 4, no. 2 (2004): 24-40.
(18.) Eckersley, "Understanding the Interplay," p. 15.
(19.) For instance, Jose Manuel Durao Barroso, president of the
European Commission, in his speech delivered at the European Parliament,
Brussels, 23 January 2008; Harro van Asselt and Thomas Brewer,
"Addressing Competitiveness and Leakage Concerns in Climate Policy:
An Analysis of Border Adjustment Measures in the US and the EU,"
Energy Policy 38, no. 1 (2010): 42-51.
(20.) Peter Gliick, Arild Angelsen, Marie Appelstrand, Samuel
Assembe-Mvondo, Graeme Auld, G. Karl Hogl, David Humphreys, and
Christoph Wildburger, "Core Components of the International Forest
Regime Complex," in Jeremy Rayner, Alexander Buck, and Pia Katila,
eds., Embracing Complexity: Meeting the Challenges of International
Forest Governance (Vienna: International Union of Forest Research
Organizations, 2010), pp. 37-55.
(21.) Malte Meinshausen and Bill Hare, "Sinks in the CDM:
After the Climate, Biodiversity Goes Down the Drain. An Analysis of the
CDM Sinks Agreement at CoP-9" (Greenpeace, 2003),
www.greenpeace.org.
(22.) Celia A. Harvey, Barney Dickson, and Cyril Kormos,
"Opportunities for Achieving Biodiversity Conservation Through
REDD," Conservation Letters 3, no. 1 (2010): 53-61; Harro van
Asselt, "integrating Biodiversity in the Climate Regime's
Forest Rules: Options and Tradeoffs in Greening REDD Design,"
Review of European Community and International Environmental Law 20, no.
2 (2011): 139-149.
(23.) Boyd, Corbera, and Estrada, "UNFCCC Negotiations
(pre-Kyoto to COP-9)," p. 107.
(24.) Ibid., p. 99.
(25.) Karin Backstrand and Eva Lovbrand, "Planting Trees to
Mitigate Climate Change: Contested Discourses of Ecological
Modernization, Green Governmental-ity, and Civic Environmentalism,"
Global Environmental Politics 6, no. 2 (2006): 50-75,60-61.
(26.) Boyd, Corbera, and Estrada, "UNFCCC Negotiations
(pre-Kyoto to COP-9)."p. 105.
(27.) Backstrand and Lovbrand, "Planting Trees to Mitigate
Climate Change," pp. 64-65.
(28.) Ibid., p. 69.
(29.) Sebastian Oberthar and Thomas Gehring, "Institutional
Interaction in Global Environmental Governance: The Case of the
Cartagena Protocol and the World Trade Organization," Global
Environmental Politics 6, no. 2 (2006): 1-31,11.
(30.) Oberthiir and Gehring, "Institutional Interaction in
Global Environmental Governance"; Oran R. Young, "Deriving
Insights from the Case of the WTO and the Cartagena Protocol," in
Oran R. Young, W. Bradnee Chambers, Joy A. Kim, and Claudia ten Have,
eds., Institutional Interplay: Biosafety and Trade (Tokyo: United
Nations University Press, 2008), pp. 131-158.
(31.) Cyrus Mehri, "Prior Informed Consent: An Emerging
Compromise for Hazardous Exports," Cornell International Law
Journal 21 (1988): 365-389; see also Amanda Wolf, "Informed
Consent: A Negotiated Formula for Trade in Risky Organisms and
Chemicals," International Negotiation 5, no. 3 (2000): 485-521.
(32.) Aarti Gupta, "Transparency as Contested Political
Terrain: Who Knows What About the Global GMO Trade and Why Does It
Matter?" Global Environmental Politics 10, no. 3 (2010): 32-52.
(33.) For a detailed comparison of the provisions on precaution in
the Cartagena Protocol versus the SPS agreement, see Aarti Gupta,
"Advance Informed Agreement: A Shared Basis to Govern Trade in
Genetically Modified Organisms?" Indiana Journal of Global Legal
Studies 9, no. 1 (2002): 265-281.
(34.) In the quintessential example, a 2003 WTO case brought by the
United States against the EU alleged that the EU was violating its SPS
obligations, given its restrictive approach to GMO imports. In its
defense, the EU invoked, inter alia, its rights and obligations under
the Cartagena Protocol. The WTO ruling in May 2006 found largely in
favor of the United States, arguing that the EU was partially in
violation of its SPS obligations. Yet importantly, it did not rule on
the substantive elements of EU GMO regulation, including the reliance on
precaution therein. Instead, the finding was based largely on procedural
grounds, including the failure of the EU to conduct risk assessments
prior to imposing restrictions. In reaching this conclusion, moreover,
the dispute settlement panel did not take the Cartagena Protocol
obligations into account. See, for example, Sarah Liberman and Tim Grey,
"The World Trade Organization's Report on the EU 's
Moratorium on Biotech Products: The Wisdom of the US Challenge to the EU
in the WTO," Global Environmental Politics 8. no. 1 (2008): 33-52.
(35.) For a detailed elaboration of this argument, see Aarti Gupta,
"Transparency to What End? Governing by Disclosure Through the
Biosafety Clearing Rouse," Environment and Planning C: Government
and Policy 28, no. 2 (2010): 128-144.
(36.) While this conclusion may not hold for the EU's regional
GMO governance approach, it refers here to the global context.
Fariborz Zelli is assistant professor in the Department of
Political Science at Lund University and an associate fellow of the
German Development Institute in Bonn.. He is coeditor of Global Climate
Governance Beyond 2012 (2010) and Climate and Trade Policies in a
Post-2012 World (2009).
Aarti Gupta is universitair docent (assistant professor, tenured)
in the Department of Social Sciences at Wageningen University and
vice-chair of the European Cooperation in Science and Technology (COST)
Action IS0802 on Transformations in Global Environmental Governance. Her
research focuses on the normative bases of global risk and biosafety
governance, trade-environment links, and transparency and accountability
in global governance. She has published in the journals Global
Environmental Politics, Environment and Planning C, and Futures, among
others.
Harro van Asselt is a research fellow at the Stockholm Environment
Institute, visiting research associate at the Environmental Change
Institute, University of Oxford, and PhD researcher at the Institute for
Environmental Studies, University Amsterdam. He is editor of the Review
of European Community and International Environmental Law and coeditor
of Climate Change Policy in the European Union (2010), and has published
in the journals Global Environmental Politics, Climate Policy, and
Stanford Environmental Law Journal, among others.
The authors thank Amandine Orsini, Jean-Frederic Morin, Mark Nance,
Michael Struett, and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments
on earlier versions of this article. Further, they thank Tatiana Lopez
for her assistance in formatting and layout.