The multilateral trading system and preferential trade agreements: can the negative effects be minimized?
Dieter, Heribert
Preferential trade agreements pose a big challenge for the
multilateral trading system. Throughout the first decade of the
twenty-first century, their number has grown significantly. However,
these agreements have a range of disadvantages compared with the
multilateral regime, for example, in trade facilitation and in
dispute settlement. Whereas it will be difficult to stop the further
spreading of this wave of preferential agreements, attempts can be
made to reduce the negative effects of trade agreements that do, by
definition, discriminate against other countries. In this article, a
range of potential remedies are discussed, from a moratorium to the
better enforcement of World Trade Organization rules on preferential
agreements as well as improved monitoring. KEYWORDS: world trade,
preferential trade agreements, rules of origin, Article XXIV, World
Trade Organization.
**********
One of the greatest challenges for the multilateral trading system in the twenty-first century is the rise of preferential trade agreements
(PTAs). (1) Both the number and the scope of these agreements are rising
rapidly. The collapse of yet another ministerial meeting of the Doha
Round, in July 2008 in Geneva, will further fuel the trend toward
preferential agreements. Moreover, the global economic and financial
crisis has further reduced the willingness of policymakers to support
trade liberalization. In many countries, the pendulum is swinging from
trade liberalization to economic nationalism. The multilateral trading
system is suffering from the economic crisis at the same time as the
preferential agreements continue to thrive.
Today, no country or region is abstaining from this trend. Though
the European Union (EU), which started with the implementation of a
customs union in 1958, has been implementing preferential agreements for
many years, countries in other regions (notably, East Asia) did not
contribute to the rising number of preferential agreements before the
year 2000. In recent years, however, Asian economies, including that of
China, have contributed to this dangerous trend.
Due to the collapse of the July 2008 ministerial meeting in Geneva,
there will be increased demand for PTAs. The arguments we have heard in
recent years will be repeated. A lack of progress in the multilateral
arena will be given as the prime reason for preferential agreements and,
of course, this argument is now more powerful than before. With no
agreement on the Doha Development Round in sight, the global economy is
poised for a new round of preferential agreements.
The failure of the 2008 Geneva talks has some parallels with the
London Economic Conference of June 1933. Although the purpose of the
1933 conference was not to achieve an agreement on trade, but rather on
financial affairs, the willingness to sacrifice multilateral cooperation
in favor of narrow national economic goals is a striking parallel. Both
then and now, the United States has been suffering from self-inflicted
economic turmoil and unwilling to make sufficient concessions to its
economic partners. (2) Following the failed London conference, the
global economy became less integrated and preferential agreements were
concluded all over the world, leading to fragmentation rather than
integration. The 1930s became a decade of noncooperation, where
"multilateralism was replaced by bilateralism, non-discrimination
by discrimination, free trade by comprehensive protection, freedom for
capital flows by exchange controls and free movement of labour by
rigorous restrictions." (3)
Of course, parallels with the 1930s should not be overdrawn.
Nevertheless, policymakers should be aware of the risks that PTAs pose
for international economic relations. (4) By definition, preferential
agreements exclude countries. PTAs are liberalizing and countries do
make concessions in them, but these are limited to the signatories and
not extended to others. Thus, preferential agreements discriminate.
This, of course, weakens nondiscrimination, which was the central pillar
of the postwar trade regime. Nondiscrimination was intentionally the
core norm of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), embodied
in Article I. The idea behind this clause was not purely, perhaps not
even primarily, economic. Nondiscrimination was considered to contribute
to the stability of international relations. Increasingly, policymakers
seem to forget that international relations cannot flourish in an
atmosphere of discrimination and exclusion.
Against these historic lessons, the first best solution would be to
eliminate preferential agreements altogether. In a world without
preferential agreements, countries could either have unilateral
restrictions on trade or agree in multilateral forums on liberalization
measures. Today, however, this is not a plausible proposal. All
countries, or at least all World Trade Organization (WTO) member
countries, would have to agree on the prohibition of PTAs. This appears
to be pure wishful thinking. In an era of noncooperation that is
characterized by the increasing unwillingness or inability of the major
players to reach consensus on vital issues, how can one realistically
expect policymakers to forgo a policy instrument that is so attractive
to them? (5) Thus, the challenge today is to implement measures that
minimize the negative consequences of PTAs, and canvassing such measures
is one of the purposes of this article.
Several questions have to be asked about the causes and the
consequences of the trend toward PTAs. First, what are the motives for
policymakers to push preferential agreements rather than regulation in a
multilateral context? Second, what are the negative consequences of
preferential agreements, in particular, for developing countries? Third,
how can these trade agreements be modified so that their negative
effects will be minimized? These three questions will be discussed in
turn.
The Rise of Preferential Agreements and Their Variance in Form
In the 1950s and 1960s, the number of PTAs notified to the GATT was
small, resulting in a total of less than ten agreements at the end of
the 1960s. In recent years the number of notifications had risen to
almost 400 by the end of 2007. (6)
In contrast to previous decades, virtually all players in global
trade in the early twenty-first century are engaged in preferential
agreements. In particular, the United States, the EU, Japan, and China
have been pushing these deviations from nondiscrimination. The United
States now seems to offer PTAs to those countries that are willing to
accept the (market opening) US template for preferential agreements,
which puts particular emphasis on intellectual property rights and
market opening in financial services, and to those countries whose
foreign and security policy is in accord with that of the United States.
(7) The EU has joined this trend and has recently given up its
moratorium on new agreements. In Asia, both China and Japan have been
actively pursuing PTAs since the turn of this century.
One of the great paradoxes of today is the fact that the member
countries of the WTO demonstrate a wide gap between their rhetoric,
which continues to be multilateral, and their policy actions, which
favor preferential agreements. The existence of an alternative to the
multilateral system, even if that alternative is a flawed one, may have
been the decisive factor that has hindered a successful conclusion of
the Doha Round thus far and conceivably forever. But what are the
motives of policymakers for negotiating and concluding preferential
agreements?
* The length of negotiations in the current round causes
difficulties for democratically elected governments, which tend to
operate within shorter electoral cycles of three to five years.
Preferential agreements can be tailored to fit into such time frames.
* Bilateral agreements seem to provide immediate, reciprocal gains
for each country's own economy. This perception allows governments
to work with coalitions supporting liberalization, which are
instrumental in overcoming internal opposition to an agreement.
Reciprocity is a useful political tool and is more easily promoted to
domestic constituencies than some arcane economic theory about the
benefits of unilateral or multilateral trade liberalization.
* Transnational corporations are increasingly pushing the
implementation of preferential agreements. Two distinct motivations can
be identified. First, some companies are pursuing an offensive strategy,
seeking the opening of hitherto closed markets (e.g., in financial
services). Second, other companies claim defensive motives, suggesting
that the implementation of free-trade agreements by third countries puts
them at a competitive disadvantage. (8)
* The vanity of politicians and trade negotiators contributes to
the current trend. Negotiators and politicians do not receive much
praise, if any, for successfully concluding a multilateral agreement,
but preferential agreements seem to prompt a more positive media
response and are an opportunity to enjoy television coverage, the
"CNN effect." Bilateral agreements allow the leaders of
not-so-great powers to have their fifteen minutes of fame, especially,
in a bilateral deal with a major global or regional power. The prospect
of media coverage may encourage the engagement in bilateral
negotiations. The CNN effect can be an important visible expression of
state sovereignty and it can boost regime authority. In addition, some
agreements are concluded because of diplomatic pressures (i.e., the
willingness of foreign policy elites to express positive political
relations with a trade agreement).
Of course, this short list of reasons for the emergence of the
strong trend for PTAs is not comprehensive. (9) However, it demonstrates
that the motives for implementing preferential agreements are embedded
in the political systems of the WTO member states. This pattern is
unlikely to change in the short or medium term. Rather, the global
economic crisis has strengthened protectionist thinking in many
economies, both developed and developing. Although the conclusion of the
Doha Round is now quite unlikely, countries may continue to implement
preferential agreements. In an environment characterized by fear and
risk aversion, policymakers may find it considerably easier to promote
bilateral agreements, which demonstrate a more obvious utility to an
economy than the more idealized concept of the multilateral trade
regime.
In addition to the variance that we can observe with regard to the
partners in PTAs, their scope does show great diversity. In recent
years, some agreements have gone well beyond trade in goods and
services, and have addressed policies on mutual recognition of
standards, competition policy, and the movement of persons as well as
investment and cooperation agreements. (10) Thus, we observe a range of
agreements, some of which go far beyond the regulation of trade. Of
course, the interest of countries to pursue so-called WTO-plus
agreements also reflects the problems of agreeing on new issues of
economic governance, both within the WTO and in other multilateral
organizations.
The Disadvantages of Preferential Trade Agreements
In principle, there are two schools of thought on preferential
agreements. The first one argues that these agreements are contributing
to deeper global integration. The second school of thought questions the
utility of these agreements and considers them to be dangerous for
international (economic) relations.
Obviously, one could argue that as long as trade liberalization
occurs, it does not matter whether it is at a bilateral, regional, or
multilateral level. In theory, preferential agreements can have
significant benefits (e.g., promoting technology and knowledge
transfers, domestic reforms, productivity gains, and improved
developmental prospects). By contrast, the critics of preferential
agreements emphasize the negative effects, including the distortion in
trade patterns between "insiders" and "outsiders"
which undermines the welfare gains arising from expanded trade.
The most critical and widely recognized issue with regard to
preferential agreements is the erosion of GATT's fundamental
nondiscrimination principle. The three key exceptions to this principle
are found in Article XXIV of GATT, permitting PTAs; the Enabling Clause of 1979, permitting preferential treatment of goods from developing
states; and Article V of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), which is similar in intent to Article XXIV. Today, the increased
use of these exceptions is reducing the most-favored-nation clause to
the exception rather than the rule.
A major disadvantage of all preferential agreements is the need to
establish the "nationality" of a product. In an entirely open
world economy with no restrictions on the flow of goods, rules of origin
would not matter. Today, however, the origin of a product does matter in
preferential agreements. All PTAs require rules of origin to establish
the nationality of a product, given that participating countries
continue to have diverging external tariffs. Because only goods produced
within the territory of the agreement qualify for duty-free trade
between the partners of the agreement, there have to be procedures that
differentiate between goods produced within and goods from the rest of
the world. The preferential system becomes complicated and expensive.
The administrative burden of issuing certificates of origin is, of
course, most problematic for those countries that have limited resources
(i.e., developing countries).
What makes RoO (rules of origin) particularly relevant is that they
are not a neutral instrument: given that RoO can serve as an
effective means to deter transhipment, they can tempt political
economy uses well beyond trade deflection. Indeed, RoO are widely
described as a trade policy instrument that can work to offset the
benefits of tariff liberalization.'' (11)
The negative consequences of rules of origin rise with the number
of agreements implemented. Furthermore, with multiple agreements,
companies are faced with diverging rules and procedures, which add to
the costs of generating certificates of origin. The operational costs of
meeting diverse requirements in different countries pose a major
challenge, especially for small- and medium-sized enterprises.
Preferential trade agreements with these outcomes are clearly a
second-best option compared to a multilateral agreement at the WTO with
uniform rules applicable to all members.
Some observers have suggested that, over time, the negative
consequences of preferential agreements will become so obvious that
countries will stop implementing them and will return to the
multilateral forum. This may be the case, but waiting for such a
learning process by policymakers in the WTO membership seems to be too
little. Furthermore, the negative consequences of preferential
agreements have been known for decades, and yet the availability of this
knowledge has led only to some caution with regard to new preferential
agreements (e.g. the unilateral moratorium EU trade commissioner Pascal
Lamy implemented after 1999).
We continue to know relatively little about the degree to which
preferences are utilized by companies. Available evidence is limited. A
study by the Canadian government suggests that, even in the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), one of the older preferential
agreements, only about 30 percent of preferences are utilized because of
both the low level of existing tariffs and the cost of establishing
origin. (12) In other agreements, such as the Association of Southeast
Asian Nations (ASEAN), the utilization rate of under 10 percent is even
lower. (13) For many companies, paying the tariff is more attractive
than incurring the cost of complying with the bureaucratic procedures
for establishing origin. (14)
But there are additional disadvantages of preferential agreements.
In particular, transferring dispute settlement to the bilateral level
can be problematic, especially, for the weaker partner in a PTA. In many
bilateral schemes, there is an option--either bilateral dispute
settlement or multilateral dispute settlement. It is obvious that the
bilateral route offers many possibilities for the more powerful partners
to promote their case. Hierarchy and power--never fully absent in
international trade--have a more prominent role in PTAs than in the
multilateral regime. The existence of an alternative to the WTO dispute
settlement mechanism provides the more powerful countries with an
additional choice but, for weaker countries, this can be a drawback. In
some cases, bilateral agreements have no provisions for dispute
settlement, leaving the less powerful trade partner disempowered in the
event of a conflict over a trade measure. Moreover, bilateral trade
agreements are not supported by the Advisory Centre for WTO Law that can
provide legal advice to developing countries and Least Developed
Countries involved in a dispute through the WTO. (15)
How Can the Negative Effects of Preferential Agreements Be
Minimized?
It is widely recognized that preferential agreements are a
suboptimal way to organize world trade. The discrimination that is
endemic in these arrangements is economically inefficient. Moreover, the
deepening of international production networks, through the sourcing of
inputs from a broad range of countries, raises the costs of preferential
agreements. (16) Now that the WTO membership has been unable to reach an
agreement on modalities that would have significantly progressed the
Doha Round in July 2008, WTO members face a choice. They can either
continue to observe the spread of preferential agreements without
changing the rules, or they can address the problem by trying to
minimize their negative effects.
At a quite general level, one way of reducing the attractiveness of
preferential agreements would be to further reduce most-favored-nation
(MFN) tariffs. (17) If these tariffs are below 5 percent, the costs
associated with establishing origin in a preferential agreement are
equal to or even greater than the tariff, so the interest in
preferential agreements would probably fade away quickly. However, the
uneven structure of tariff lines has to be considered. Although many
tariff lines are already quite low today, there continue to be high
tariffs on specific products in both developing and developed economies.
(18)
Given the paralysis in multilateral negotiations and the limited
willingness of policymakers to unilaterally liberalize much further at
this point, the question is whether a political initiative by important
countries could send a signal against the further spreading of
preferential agreements. The Warwick Commission has suggested that the
major industrialized countries as well as large developing countries
should refrain from establishing PTAs with each other. (19) This
recommendation was made with the worst-case scenario in mind in which
the EU, United States, and major Asian economies negotiated PTAs among
themselves. Were such a situation to eventuate, the WTO would face the
prospect of irrelevance. Although not likely today, we have seen some
developments in that direction, including South Korea's bilateral
negotiations with the United States and the EU, and negotiations for a
transatlantic marketplace between the United States and the EU. (20)
Beyond the recommendations of the Warwick Commission, a moratorium
on new preferential agreements is conceivable in Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries. For such an
agreement, two ingredients would be essential. First, an alternative to
preferential agreements would be necessary. So-called critical mass
initiatives, in which subsets of WTO members make agreements whose
benefits are then extended to the entire membership, would constitute
such an alternative. Second, the countries supporting such an initiative
would have had to come to terms with their policies toward
globalization. Today, we observe a widespread reluctance to underwrite
the concept of further international division of labor. (21) Thus,
governments in OECD countries may see little benefit in initiatives that
risk electoral backlashes, even though the direct effect of a moratorium
on preferential agreements would be to safeguard an established and
valuable multilateral regime.
Quite promising are reforms that would directly address one of the
most crucial problems of today's multilateral trade negotiations.
Up until today, an unhealthy dichotomy has emerged. Because the Doha
Round is a "single undertaking" (i.e., nothing is agreed until
everything is agreed), countries are using preferential agreements to
achieve some progress in specific areas. The answer to that dilemma
could be the introduction of critical mass initiatives under the roof of
the WTO. Inter alia, the Warwick Commission has suggested this approach.
(22) In essence, countries willing to agree on certain specific policies
could go ahead and implement policies without needing the consent of all
WTO member countries. In effect, preferential agreements would cease to
be the only alternative to the multilateral regime. Although a critical
mass approach does have disadvantages (see the contribution of Peter
Gallagher and Andrew Stoler in this special issue), on balance this
avenue is superior to the continuation of an uncontrolled and, given
their popularity, probably uncontrollable spreading of preferential
agreements.
One way of exercising greater control of preferential agreements is
to strengthen regulation within the WTO. Preferential agreements are
permitted under Article XXIV of GATT, which permits preferential
agreements subject to certain conditions. However, the disciplines
imposed by Article XXIV lack definitional clarity and have never been
enforced. The key question is whether there are ways to discipline their
use. In theory, preferential agreements could be reviewed under two
different mechanisms. First, member countries must notify the WTO about
agreements, which are subsequently discussed in the Committee on
Regional Trade Agreements. In practice, this track has been of limited
utility. All WTO member countries can participate in the committee,
including the states participating in the preferential agreement.
Although, in theory at least, the committee could by consensus deem a
notified agreement to be WTO inconsistent, as a practical matter the
committee probably never would reach such a consensus.
Second, in principle, a WTO member could challenge the WTO
consistency of a preferential agreement through the dispute settlement
proceedings. Hitherto, member countries have refrained from pursuing
this avenue. The legality of preferential agreements has not been
challenged. A plausible explanation is that virtually all member
countries have been implementing preferential agreements and could
therefore face a challenge to their preferential agreements if they
initiate a legal challenge against other countries. Consider, for
example, a potential legal challenge of the legality of US trade
agreements by the EU. The dispute settlement mechanism of the WTO would
either be blocked for years or the legitimacy of the dispute settlement
might be questioned by one of the major players.
Moreover, given the uncertainty surrounding the precise legal
frontiers of the line between lawful and unlawful preferential
agreements--and the widespread acceptance of them on a de facto basis by
WTO members--dispute panels should probably avoid making a definitive
decision on the WTO consistency of any particular agreement. Political
issues have to be solved by policymakers, not the juridical system.
However, there is room for improvement within the sphere of
activity of the WTO. The Committee on Regional Trade Agreements, which
appears to be at best lacking courage and at worst moribund, should be
given a clear and strong mandate for the improvement of the supervision
of preferential agreements. One significant development in the WTO was
the adoption in December 2006, on a provisional basis, of a Transparency
Mechanism for PTAs. The Transparency Mechanism requires members to
notify of a new PTA as soon as possible, and no later than immediately
following its ratification. The WTO secretariat then prepares a factual
presentation on the detail of the new PTA, in consultation with the
signatories involved. This is an important, albeit limited, development;
as in other areas of regulation, increasing transparency is only a first
step. Even complete information will not alter the structural problems
that are related to preferential agreements. To achieve this, bolder
steps would be necessary.
The inherently discriminatory and puzzling system of PTAs questions
the WTO's ability to manage the increasingly complex system of
trade governance. If the WTO and its members are unwilling to stop the
glut of preferential agreements, one potential avenue for reducing the
negative effects of this trend would be to transform the WTO into a
supervising agency. In such a scheme, the WTO would monitor, evaluate,
and, where necessary, sanction PTAs. Member countries of the WTO would
continue to be free to implement preferential agreements, but the
criteria for permissible agreements would be sharp and coherent.
Needless to say, such a regime would require a reasonably strong
instrument for sanctioning unacceptable agreements. The simplest, and
yet most forceful, one would be to allow the WTO to open the preferences
granted in the preferential agreements to all other WTO member
countries. Thus, if the WTO supervising body concludes that one element
of a particular preferential agreement violates the WTO rules, other
member countries would be permitted to retaliate by being permitted to
take advantage of the agreement's preferences.
The WTO's evolution into a supervisory body--overseeing
preferential agreements, developing a transparency mechanism, and
sanctioning nonconforming agreements--would constitute an effective
response to the recent proliferation of preferential agreements.
Nonetheless, this evolution would require two substantial policy shifts.
First, member countries would have to agree on what constitutes an
acceptable preferential agreement and what does not. In essence, the
currently vague regulations of Article XXIV would have to be expanded
and more explicit formulas would have to be found. For example, the term
"substantially all the trade" would have to be made specific.
Does that mean 80, 90, or 99 percent of all existing trade? Or would the
regulation refer to all potential trade (i.e., including areas that
countries considered to be unsuitable for increased competition from
foreign companies)? Second, member countries of the WTO would have to
give the organization a widened mandate and permit it to interfere in
their foreign economic policy. Although this has been the case in the
past, giving the WTO explicit jurisdiction over preferential agreements
would be an additional step.
In order to know which agreements have less negative effects than
others, it would be necessary to develop best-practice guidelines for
preferential agreements. Member countries would have to negotiate these.
(23) By developing such a catalog, the effects of any preferential
agreement would be much more transparent to both those involved in
negotiations and to third parties.
However, the question is whether this is a plausible proposal.
First, Article XXIV of GATT does contain some guidelines (e.g., the
provision that "substantially all the trade" ought to be
covered by the agreement). Yet member countries have frequently violated
the principle, for example, by excluding agricultural products more or
less completely from preferential agreements. (24) Political pressures
in member countries, in particular the powerful agricultural lobbies,
will be an obstacle for the implementation of a rigid implementation of
standardized regulations on openness. Second, some countries have used
preferential agreements to advance the interests of domestic industries.
A prominent example is the financial sector of the United States, which
managed to secure the prohibition of restrictions on capital flows in
some agreements (e.g., in those with Singapore and Chile). The question
is whether these interest groups could be pacified with a best-practice
agreement that would restrict the remit of preferential agreements to
narrowly defined trade-related issues (of course, restrictions on
capital flows are not).
Some of the proposals made in the discussion on preferential
agreements are ignoring the fact that any binding agreement on best
practice would not be easily accepted in democratic societies. Baldwin
and Thornton suggest that "nations would declare themselves and all
of their RTAs [regional trade agreements] as subject to this
anchorage-building discipline. The benefit of self-declaration would be
the signal it provided to potential investors that the nation was
permanently committed to pro-market reforms." (25) Such
expectations, however, are politically naive and do underestimate the
level of resistance that so-called promarket reforms have been
generating in recent years. Whereas the Baldwin-Thornton approach may
work in autocratic societies, it most probably will not work elsewhere.
Consider, for example, the opposition in EU countries against its failed
constitution. In the debate, many opponents claimed that the economic
policies enshrined in the constitution where too market friendly and did
not give sufficient consideration to social issues. In developing
countries, there has been enormous, lasting resistance against the
Washington Consensus, another variation of seemingly straightforward
principles. John Williamson's description of policies that were
considered to be essential for economic reform could have been
considered to be a set of best practices, yet the academic and political
reaction against them was over-whelming. (26)
Another example of the failure to establish a set of trade-related
best practices are the so-called Singapore issues, which refer to
transparency in government procurement, trade facilitation, trade and
investment, and trade and competition. Opposition to this set of best
practices was opposed by many developing countries, most notably, during
the failed WTO ministerial in Cancun in 2003.
This list is by no means complete, but it shows that the
establishment of a consensus on economic policies at a global level is
an extremely complex endeavor. (27) In an era in which the process of
globalization is contested both in developing and developed countries,
the development of a set of enforceable rules on PTAs will be no less
difficult than previous attempts to establish best practices.
Nevertheless, there are opportunities for reducing the negative
effects of preferential agreements that appear to be more easily
achievable. First, regions could decide to follow the example of the
European countries and establish zones that accept so-called diagonal
cumulation of origin. In effect, the region from which inputs can be
sourced can be dramatically increased. The pan-European cumulation
system (PECS), introduced in 1997, has eased trade within that system
significantly: any good that is deemed as originating in one country of
the PECS zone has to be granted originating status in every other
country in the zone. (28) Developing, for example, a pan-Asian and a
pan-American cumulation scheme would ease trade discrimination at least
within those regions. Of course, the unwelcome side effect would be that
the emergence of three large trading blocs would be facilitated.
Second, preferential rules of origin could be harmonized. Ideally,
this would result in their standardization. If there could be one set of
criteria--uniform for all preferential trade agreements--the negative
effects would be significantly reduced. However, some observers argue
that a complete harmonization of rules of origin would be politically
difficult because it would be "unpalatable to producers around the
world." (29) Although it is true that striking a bargain on rules
of origin would be difficult, it does not appear to be an insurmountable
hurdle. If the beneficiaries of a liberalization measure are
sufficiently powerful to withstand opposition, there is no need to
compensate the losers. If they are not, compensation is necessary. Of
course, mobilizing political support for such a highly technical and
complex area of regulation will not be easy.
Third, dispute settlement could be made exclusive to the WTO. Such
a step would require that all preferential agreements would have to
contain a clause that grants the WTO exclusive jurisdiction on its
disputes. Of course, some larger countries or entities would probably
oppose such a scheme, in particular the EU, which likely would have no
intention to give up jurisdiction over issues related to the single
market. A potential solution could be that the WTO would retain the
jurisdiction for all free-trade agreements, but permit the development
of dispute settlement mechanisms for customs unions and common markets.
Another potential avenue for reducing the negative effects of
preferential agreements would involve multilateralizing commitments that
countries make in preferential agreements. In areas such as procurement,
services, investment, and competition policy, many countries (including
developing nations) have been willing to make commitments in
preferential agreements, but have resisted attempts to negotiate these
matters at the multilateral level. (30) The WTO could launch initiatives
to multilateralize those commitments, and such an endeavor would, if
successful, reduce the negative effects of preferential agreements. (31)
The risk, of course, is that the WTO could itself come under attack from
member countries for pushing them into a certain direction. If the
organization itself were to push such initiatives, the WTO could lose
credibility and legitimacy in some member countries. The potential
losses would probably outweigh the potential gains.
Conclusion
On balance, PTAs do have very few advantages. They are inferior to
regulating trade at the multilateral level, and not many of them support
deeper integration as do some of the larger regional agreements (e.g.,
the EU, NAFTA, and ASEAN). Preferential trade agreements are a
third-best solution for regulating international trade. They are
suboptimal with regard to economic efficiency, and they are imbalanced
because they disadvantage the poorer players and systemically strengthen
the more developed players. Despite these obvious drawbacks, a
fundamental revision of countries' trade policies appears to be
unrealistic. In the early twenty-first century, the willingness of
nations to support the existing institutions of economic governance
appears to be limited and, consequently, preferential agreements are
here to stay.
However, accepting the inevitability of a further spreading of PTAs
does not mean that their negative effects cannot be reduced. Among the
options discussed in this article, reforming the negotiating process
with the WTO is the most promising avenue. The introduction of critical
mass initiatives under the supervision of the WTO would enable members
to form coalitions of like-minded countries that could advance issues of
common concern without having to opt out of the multilateral regime.
In addition, member countries could provide the WTO with a clear
mandate for monitoring and supervising PTAs, including the application
of sanctions for agreements that violate Article XXIV. The harmonization
of preferential rules of origin would be a further step to reduce the
negative effect of PTAs.
By contrast, the development of an agreed set of best practices for
preferential agreements appears to be difficult. The definition of what
constitutes best practice inevitably varies according to the level of
development of a country as well as the political preferences of
societies. Past experience has demonstrated how controversial best
practices can be.
However, the changing geopolitical context appears to be more
important than the details of trade agreements. As discussed in the
introduction, we may currently witness a departure from multilateral
governance not entirely different from the 1930s. The United States may
decide that the disadvantages of globalization outweigh the benefits and
put more emphasis on preferential agreements in line with other OECD
countries. Early statements from me Obama administration are not
encouraging. In March 2009, the United States signaled a tough position
on Doha and expressed the belief that the Doha Round was "tilted
against the US." (32) In his campaign for the presidency, Barack
Obama expressed reservations on the utility of a liberal regime, raising
concerns for instance about the loss of jobs due to offshoring. He even
criticized NAFTA for not considering the needs of American workers, (33)
The combination of a severe and lasting economic crisis, increasing
hostility toward globalization in the United States, and a lack of
supporters of the multilateral trade regime elsewhere may result in a
fatal blow to the World Trade Organization. The return to the world of
the 1930s, not long ago deemed unlikely, is a considerable risk today.
Preferential trade agreements would play a prominent role in a world
characterized by discrimination.
Effectively, the global economy seems to be returning to a regime
where goods originating from befriended countries have easier access to
a national market than others. There is discrimination between friends
and foes. The postwar trading regime had the explicit goal of
nondiscrimination, and today's policymakers are sacrificing this
philosophy on the altar of seemingly quick, but asymmetrical and
eventually unsustainable, economic gains.
Notes
Heribert Dieter is a senior fellow at the German Institute for
International and Security Affairs, Berlin, and teaches at die
University of Potsdam.
(1.) Throughout this article, I will use the term preferential
agreements for all types of trade agreements that exclude other
countries (i.e., bilateral and plurilateral free trade agreements and
customs unions).
(2.) President Franklin D. Roosevelt's rejection to contribute
to the stabilization of exchange rates was the final nail in the coffin
of the gold standard; see Harold James, International Monetary
Cooperation Since Bretton Woods (New York: Oxford University Press,
1999), p. 25.
(3.) Martin Wolf, "Is Globalization in Danger?" The World
Economy 26, no. 4 (April 2003): 393-411.
(4.) For a discussion on the tensions between regional and
multilateral regulation, see Peter Katzenstein, "Regionalism in
Comparative Perspective," Cooperation and Conflict 31, no. 2 (June
1996): 123-159.
(5.) For a discussion of the changing geopolitical context, see
Heribert Dieter and Richard Higgott, Between Crisis and Reform:
Governing the Global Economy in an Era of Non-cooperation (forthcoming),
chap. 1.
(6.) Some 300 of them are trade agreements covering trade in goods
and are notified under Article XXIV while 58 cover trade in services and
are notified under Article V of GATT, and 22 are notified under the
Enabling Clause of 1979 (i.e., agreements between developing countries).
(7.) Countries actively supporting the invasion of Iraq (e.g.,
Australia) were given the "privilege" of a free trade
agreement (Bob Zoellick, US trade representative, New Statesman, 23 June
2003, p. 17) while a country like New Zealand, which refused to join the
invasion forces, did not get such an agreement. (For a discussion of the
securitization of US trade policy, see Heribert Dieter and Richard
Higgott, "Linking Trade and Security in Asia: Has Washington's
Policy Worked?" Aussenwirtschaft 62 [2007]: 151-174.)
(8.) One example is the European car industry, which pushes
preferential agreements between the EU and ASEAN countries, citing these
countries' preferential agreements with Japan as their prime
concern. German industry has been lobbying for preferential agreements
with Asian economies for a few years, typically citing the preferential
agreements of other large economies and arguing that abstaining from the
trend would do harm to their business interests. See, for example, the
press release of the Federation of German Industries in April 2007,
which welcomes the push for bilateral trade agreements (Bundesverband de
deutschen Industrie, or BDI), available at
www.bdi-online.de/download/PMbilateraleFreihandelsabkommen.pdf.
(9.) For a more detailed discussion see, for example, Richard
Baldwin, "Multilateralising Regionalism: Spaghetti Bowls as
Building Blocs on the Path to Global Free Trade," The World Economy
29, no. 11 (2006): 1451-1518; Ross Garnaut and David Vines, Sorting out
the Spaghetti. On Reducing the Damage from the Proliferation of
Discriminatory Regional Free Trade Areas (New York: University of
Columbia Business School, January 2006), available at
http://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/ipd/pub/Vines_Reaction.pdf; John Ravenhill,
"The New Bilateralism in the Asia Pacific," Third World
Quarterly 24, no. 2 (1999): 299-317.
(10.) John Whalley, "Recent Regional Agreements: Why So Many,
Why So Much Variance in Form, Why Coming So Fast, and Where Are They
Headed?" The World Economy 28, no. 30 (2008): 518.
(11.) Antoni Estevadeordal, Jeremy Harris, and Kati Suominen,
"Multilateralising Preferential Rules of Origin Around the
World," paper presented at the conference "Multilateralising
Regionalism," Geneva, September 2007, available at
www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/con_sep07_e/estevadeordal_harris_suominen_e.pdf.
For a detailed discussion of the effects of rules of origin, see,
for example, Anne O. Krueger, "Free Trade Agreements as
Protectionist Devices: Rules of Origin," National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 4352, Washington, DC, 1993; Kala
Krishna and Anne O. Krueger, "Implementing Free Trade Areas: Rules
of Origin and Hidden Protection," National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 4983, Washington, DC, 1995; Antoni
Estevadeordal and Kati Suominen, "Rules of Origin: A World Map and
Trade Effects," paper presented at the conference "The Origin
of Goods: A Conceptual and Empirical Assessment of Origin in PTAs,"
Paris, May 2003, available at
www.inra.fr/Intemet/Departements/ESR/UR/lea/actualites/ROO2003/articles/estevadeordal.pdf; Heribert Dieter, "Praferenzielle Ursprungsregeln
in Freihandelszonen: Hemmnisse fiir den internationalen Handel?"
Aussenwirtschaft: Schweizerische Zeit-schrift fur Internationale
Wirtschaftsbeziehungen 59, no. 3 (2004): 273-303; Estevadeordal, Harris,
and Suominen, "Multilateralising Preferential Rules of Origin
Around the World."
(12.) Whalley, "Recent Regional Agreements," p. 522.
(13.) Baldwin, "Multilateralising Regionalism," p. 1488.
(14.) Richard Baldwin and Phil Thornton, Multilateralising
Regionalism: Ideas for a WTO Action Plan on Regionalism (London: Centre
for Economic Policy Research, 2008), p. 14.
(15.) Christina L. Davis, "Do WTO Rules Create a Level Playing
Field? Lessons from the Experience of Peru and Vietnam," in John
Odell, ed., Developing Countries and the Trade Negotiation Process
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), p. 239.
(16.) Baldwin and Thornton, Multilateralising Regionalism, p. ix.
(17.) Richard Baldwin, Simon Evenett, and Patrick Low, "Beyond
Tariffs: Multilateralising Deeper RTA Commitments," paper presented
at the conference "Multilateralising Regionalism," Geneva,
September 2007, p. 4, available at
www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/con_sep07_e/baldwin_evenett_low_e.pdf.
(18.) A few examples from the automotive sector illustrate this.
For example, the United States still charges 25 percent duty on
so-called light trucks, the currently unpopular commercial vehicles. A
relatively advanced country like Thailand has an import duty of 80
percent on larger cars, and the EU continues to have an import duty of
10 percent on all vehicles.
(19.) Warwick Commission, The Multilateral Trade Regime: Which Way
Forward? University of Warwick, December 2007, p. 53, available at
www2.warwick.ac.uk/research/warwickcommission/report/uw_warcomm_tradereport_07.pdf.
(20.) For a discussion of the risks inherent to a transatlantic
trade agreement, see Rolf Langhammer, "Why a Market Place Must Not
Discriminate: The Case Against a US-EU Free Trade Agreement," Kiel
Working Paper No. 1407, March 2008.
(21.) For a discussion of global economic governance in the
twenty-first century, see Dieter and Higgott, Between Crisis and Reform.
(22.) See Warwick Commission, The Multilateral Trade Regime, pp.
30-31.
(23.) Baldwin and Thornton, Multilateralising Regionalism, p. 38.
(24.) For example, the preferential agreement between Japan and
Thailand, concluded in 2005. excludes rice, wheat, beef, dairy products,
and fish. Of course, these are highly protected sectors of the Japanese
economy; thus, gains from liberalizing would be greatest there.
(25.) Baldwin and Thornton, Multilateralising Regionalism, p. xi.
(26.) John Williamson, What Washington Means by Policy Reform
(1990; reprint, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics,
November 2002), available at
www.iie.com/publications/papers/williamson1102-2.htm. Some of the
policies (e.g., the proposal for the privatization of state enterprises)
were controversial but, by and large, the recommendations were
motherhood and apple pie. Capital account liberalization, an important
element of the financial crisis of the 1990s, was not included in the
Washington Consensus.
(27.) One could add the failed Multilateral Agreement on Investment
(MAI), in effect abandoned in 1998, as well as the fiasco that the
International Monetary Fund experienced with its contingent credit
lines, which would have required countries to accept a set of best
practices.
(28.) Baldwin and Thornton, Multilateralising Regionalism, p. 32.
(29.) Estevadeordal, Harris, and Suominen, "Multilateralising
Preferential Rules of Origin Around the World," p. 44.
(30.) Baldwin, Evenett, and Lo, "Beyond Tariffs," p. 35.
(31.) For a discussion of potential initiatives, see Baldwin,
Evenett, and Low, "Beyond Tariffs," pp. 36-38. For a
comprehensive debate, see Richard Baldwin and Patrick Low, eds.,
Multilateralizing Regionalism (Cambridge; Cambridge University Press,
2009).
(32.) Alan Beattie, "Obama Signals Tough Stance on Doha,"
Financial Times, 2 March 2009, available at
www.ft.com/cms/s/0/cf8757b4-075b-11de-9294-000077b07658.html.
(33.) Barack Obama on NAFTA, available at Greg Mankiw's
website at http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/(accessed 21 February 2008).