Pathways through financial crisis: Argentina.
Setser, Brad ; Gelpern, Anna
By the end of 2001, Argentina faced economic recession, a collapse
in its banking system, and an external sovereign debt crisis. While
preemptive action earlier in the year might have made one or more of
these crises less severe, preemption was a political orphan at home and
abroad. The country's long-standing relationship with the
International Monetary Fund brought with it a mutual dependence: the IMF had come to embrace Argentina as a symbol of the success of its policy
advice, and Argentina had come to rely on the IMF's endorsement and
occasional financial support to navigate the choppy international
markets. That relationship deepened along with Argentina's growing
difficulties in the run-up to default. IMF support was used to put off a
correction of the overvalued currency and to postpone a major debt
restructuring. A new Argentine policy regime--and a new, more
adversarial relationship with the IMF--emerged only after devaluation and default. KEYWORDS: Argentina, financial crises, banking crises, debt
restructuring, International Monetary Fund.
**********
Argentina's relationship with the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) has been remarkably long-standing and intense. For fourteen of the
twenty years preceding Argentina's crisis in 2000, its economic
policy operated within an IMF program. Even after the initial success of
its currency board arrangement and debt restructuring in the early
1990s, Argentina relied on the IMF's endorsement and occasional
financing to navigate choppy international markets. As the IMF came
under criticism for its handling of Asia's financial crisis, it set
aside early doubts about Argentina's currency board arrangement and
embraced the country as a symbol of the success of IMF policy advice.
When external shocks left the Argentine peso overvalued at the end of
the 1990s, neither Argentina's political system nor its
relationship with the IMF could adjust successfully to a financial
crisis that proved far deeper than either Argentina's elite or the
IMF had recognized.
Between 1999 and 2001, Argentina's economic slump transformed
into a deep financial crisis. Two theories for Argentina's malaise
dominated the policy debate. One held that Argentina was suffering from
a crisis of confidence. Another held that the crisis was mostly fiscal.
Both theories were too simplistic. They ignored the central importance
of an overvalued currency and the heavy use of the dollar in domestic
financial contracts. They also failed to recognize the extent to which
the "convertibility" system (Argentina's currency board
arrangement) had become an organizing device for Argentina's
politics--not just an anchor for monetary policy--and how access to
external financing had provided the critical glue that held together the
political economy of "convertibility." (1) Argentina's
political system was unwilling to act preemptively to reduce the scale
of what in many ways was an unavoidable crisis. At no time was there a
political consensus to incur the costs of exiting convertibility
immediately to avoid a bigger, deeper, and more costly exit later.
Neither was there a consensus to shrink Argentina's economy and
drive down wages and prices to abide by the constraints of a currency
board, particularly once those constraints started to bite in the face
of reduced capital inflows. Argentina's leaders preferred to hope
that its difficulties were temporary: they drew on IMF financing, spent
reserves, and then resorted to increasingly desperate attempts at
financial engineering to postpone a payments crisis.
Default and devaluation did not immediately bring political
consensus on how to allocate financial pain. A desire to avoid probable
losses transformed into an inability to allocate losses already incurred
and demands for compensation from all sides. All the major players
initially hoped that someone else would get stuck with the bill. The
denouement of Argentina's crisis turned out to be as protracted as
its buildup. External bondholders eventually agreed to a large
"haircut"--effectively helping to finance compensation to the
domestic financial system. Yet by early 2006, five years after the
default, only some domestic interests had received compensation--and the
fate of key sectors, notably Argentina's regulated utilities,
remained unresolved.
President Kirchner's popularity suggests that Argentines
endorsed the policies that followed devaluation and debt default. Growth
remained brisk, at over 9 percent for 2005. Inflation rose in 2005 to
just above 10 percent, in part because Argentina's central bank has
resisted pressure for the peso to appreciate. Argentina is managing
inflation partly through price agreements with key industry groups. But
it avoided the bout of hyperinflation many predicted would follow the
initial devaluation. Its budget remained in balance, with interest
payments financed out of tax revenues. International investors were keen
to buy Argentina's inflation-indexed domestic debt despite ongoing
litigation over the US$20 billion in external bonds that did not
participate in its 2005 debt exchange. In 2005, President Kirchner
replaced the finance minister and central bank governor with close
political allies and repaid the IMF in full, signaling confidence that
his policy course no longer needed technocratic validation.
This article is organized into four sections. The first section
traces the evolution of Argentina's crisis. The second looks at the
key decisions that defined how the crisis unfolded, paying particular
attention to internal political forces that made alternative policy
directions unattractive during the initial stages of Argentina's
crisis, and to the decision to resolve Argentina's domestic debt
crisis through pesification and compensation. The third section looks at
who has borne the costs of Argentina's crisis. The conclusion
examines the constraints Argentina's political institutions imposed
on its approach toward crisis management.
The Dynamics of the Crisis
Argentina experienced three conceptually different crises:
* An economic crisis. Argentina was pushed into recession in 1999
by reduced market access following Russia's default, the
competitive challenge from Brazil after its devaluation, and the slump
in soybean prices. Output stalled in 2000, fell sharply in 2001, then
collapsed in early 2002 after devaluation and default. The country did
not emerge from this recession until late 2002.
* An external sovereign debt crisis. As Argentina's economy
cooled, external investors lost interest in its government bonds. The
government then turned to domestic banks, domestic pension funds, and
the IMF for financing. After exhausting these sources, the government
unilaterally restructured its domestic debts and defaulted on its
external bonds at the end of 2001.
* A domestic banking crisis. Argentina experienced a series of
domestic bank runs in 2001. After default and devaluation, the banking
system was in shambles and required extensive restructuring.
Argentina's three crises were tightly interlinked. The series
of shocks that led to the economic slump called for a real depreciation
of the peso, yet the dollar's rise at that time led the peso to
appreciate in real terms. (2) Breaking the dollar peg institutionalized
in convertibility would have allowed the exchange rate to adjust--but at
the cost of bankrupting many firms and the government, since the peso
value of their dollar debts would balloon. The alternative was slow
deflation, which strangled growth, reduced tax revenues, and risked the
same outcome: bankruptcies throughout the private sector and perhaps the
government as well. (3) With no growth and no market access, the
government sought financing from the banking system, increasing the risk
of a banking crisis (see Table 1).
Growing Difficulties Raising New External Financing
A steadily shrinking real economy contributed to persistent
political tension, and both combined to lead successive groups of
creditors to lose confidence. (4) Argentina's initial difficulties
accessing international capital markets came at a politically
inopportune time: in 1999, Argentine president Carlos Menem and Buenos
Aires governor Eduardo Duhalde were competing for the Justicialist
(Peronist) Party presidential nomination. (5) As the economy slowed and
bond markets closed, neither cut back on spending. Rather, both sought
credit from domestic banks. In the end, both lost to the Radical Party
candidate, Fernando de la Rua.
Between 1998 and 2000, the IMF swallowed its own doubts about the
consistency of Argentina's fiscal policy with its exchange rate
regime and backed a precautionary program that briefly helped reassure
the markets. Argentina's ability to tap unsophisticated retail
investors in Europe (6) initially made up for the shortfall of
institutional investors willing to buy new Argentine bonds. (7) However,
by the end of 2000, Argentina was losing access to the retail market as
well. After a political scandal forced the vice-president to resign,
Argentina needed more than the IMF's seal of approval. It needed
IMF emergency financing.
The IMF responded with a $15 billion program--dubbed blindage
(shield)--which, unusually, deferred fiscal consolidation until after
2001. However, it soon became clear that Argentina would have trouble
meeting even these relatively loose fiscal targets, since the ongoing
slump reduced government revenues. In the spring of 2001, President de
la Rua chose orthodox economist Ricardo Lopez-Murphy as economy minister
but failed to back his demands for budget-cutting authority.
Lopez-Murphy resigned, prompting significant withdrawals from the
banking system even as the IMF program implicitly relied on the banking
system for additional financing.
The return of Domingo Cavallo, architect of Argentina's 1991
Convertibility Plan, stopped the bank run. When he took over the finance
ministry, Cavallo rejected calls for severe fiscal tightening, arguing
that technical changes in the operation of convertibility could provide
a monetary easing and jumpstart growth. (8) Central bank president Pedro
Pou resisted Cavallo's efforts to loosen reserve requirements for
banks; he was forced out. Lopez-Murphy had failed to win control over
the spending ministries; Cavallo succeeded in winning control of the
central bank.
In June 2001, Cavallo also initiated an ambitious $29.5 billion
voluntary government debt swap (the mega canje) to push out maturities.
Creditor participation in the swap exceeded expectations, but the
operation also increased the net present value of Argentina's debt
by $9.5 billion. (9) The government's willingness to pay so much to
defer payments signaled desperation to the markets. (10) Both local and
international markets turned for the worse. A failed Treasury bill
auction led Cavallo to reverse fiscal policy course; the government
announced that it had lost access to credit and therefore had to run a
zero-deficit policy. The ensuing deposit run concentrated rationally on
the banks most actively involved in financing the government: two state
banks and one Argentine-owned private bank. (11)
Cavallo played his last card, audaciously announcing that the IMF
would speed up and augment its next disbursement, even though he had yet
to secure commitment from Fund management or its shareholders. (12) The
bluff worked--the announcement helped to stem the run, and Argentina got
more money. The $15 billion IMF program was increased to $23 billion,
with $6 billion made available immediately to supply emergency financing
to the banking system in what became the IMF's last disbursement
before default. The augmentation alone was more than four times the $1.9
billion in net financing Argentina received from the IMF in 1995, after
Mexico's Tequila crisis spawned a bank run. Net disbursements from
the IMF in 2001 totaled $9 billion.
However, the economy continued to contract, government revenues
continued to fall, and the pace of deposit withdrawals picked up again
after Peronist opposition won congressional and provincial elections in
October. (13) In November, Argentina converted domestically held
international bonds into loans. Although the loans were issued under
Argentine law and carried a lower interest rate, they were backed, at
least in theory, by revenues from the financial transactions tax. (14)
But efforts to cut spending, including interest spending, lagged falling
revenues. Many provinces resorted to paying their workers with IOUs
marketed as quasi-currencies. The federal government itself started
issuing a quasi-currency, Lecops, to cover shortfalls in revenue
transfers to the provinces. McDonald's started selling
Lecopburgers.
In December, growing pressures on the banks led the government to
restrict access to sight deposits (corralito), and then to time deposits
(corralon). Financial standstill quickly turned into a full-blown
political crisis. Riots followed the bank holiday, resulting in several
deaths. De la Rua and Cavallo resigned, and de la Rua's successor
declared default on Argentina's external debt. Days later yet
another government, led by Duhalde, formally devalued the peso,
introduced exchange controls, and issued a decree that converted
domestic financial contracts from dollars into pesos.
Financial Stabilization and Economic Recovery
Argentina's crisis reached its nadir in the spring of 2002.
Economic activity plummeted, poverty rates surged, the financial system
remained frozen, and the peso briefly fell to four to a dollar.
Duhalde's new government--and a new economic team led first by
Jorge Remes Lenicov and then by Roberto Lavagna--eventually managed to
achieve a degree of financial stabilization without the IMF. Central
bank intervention to the tune of $3 billion, capital and exchange
controls, and, above all, responsible fiscal policy combined to stop the
peso's free fall. Government revenues were plunging, but the
government generally spent only what it took in, refusing to print
money. (15)
The real economy started to rebound in mid-2002; stabilizing the
banking system took more time. The deposit freeze was never watertight:
frozen deposits could, for example, be used to pay peso debts, and the
courts ordered additional deposits to be released from the freeze.
However, once both the peso and the economy had stabilized, the
government was able to lift the freeze in stages without triggering a
renewed run. By the end of 2002, all sight deposits had been freed.
This started a new phase of Argentina's crisis--a phase marked
on the one hand by a strong domestic recovery and the steady improvement
in domestic financial conditions, and on the other hand by deliberations
on allocating enormous financial losses from the crisis among domestic
and external constituencies. The phase ended when Argentina restructured
its external debt and repaid the IMF in full, ahead of schedule.
However, nearly five years after the crisis, Argentina's
restructuring remains incomplete. Holders of nearly $20 billion in bonds
refused the exchange; many have sued. The standoff continues between the
government and foreign investors over utility tariffs. Investor
complaints against Argentina still dominate the World Bank's
arbitral tribunal.
Managing the Crisis
Argentina made three key decisions during the course of its crisis.
The first was to seek IMF assistance in the fall of 2000 to support the
currency board and a relatively accommodative fiscal policy. The second
decision, made by Cavallo in the summer of 2001, was to seek more money
and push out bond maturities instead of exiting convertibility and
seeking debt relief. The third key decision, made after the IMF left the
scene, was to restructure public and private domestic debts through
pesification.
Seeking IMF Financing
Neither Argentina's decision to seek IMF financing in late
2000 nor the IMF's decision to support Argentina came as a
surprise. The IMF had a long and close relationship with Argentina. IMF
financing supported the initial reform package that launched
convertibility and helped Argentina through the bank run that
accompanied the 1995 Tequila crisis. Another IMF program followed in
1996-1998, and a nondisbursing "precautionary" program was in
place from 1998 until the crisis (see Table 2).
While IMF programs are often viewed as a major constraint on a
country's macroeconomic freedom, the opposite became true in
Argentina as the 1990s wore on. Private foreign investors flocked to
Argentina after the success of its initial stabilization. Market access
allowed Argentina to exit from the cycle of IMF programs and debt
reschedulings of the 1980s. Private external financing also helped
loosen the constraints that otherwise would accompany a strict currency
board. However, during market disruptions--notably in 1995--the IMF
stepped in to offset a fall in private funding and, above all, to
bolster domestic and external confidence in Argentina's policies.
Particularly after Asia's crisis, both parties believed that they
gained from this relationship: Argentina's success showed the value
of IMF advice, and IMF endorsement helped Argentina secure financing in
increasingly difficult market conditions.
Argentina's federal authorities have long struggled to bridge
the gap between their limited ability to raise money and the demands for
government spending, notably for transfers to Argentina's
politically powerful provinces. (16) In the 1980s, the federal
government closed the gap by borrowing from the central bank, which led
to hyperinflation. (17) "Convertibility," along with the Brady
debt restructuring, anchored a classic "liberalize, privatize, and
stabilize" package that sought to break this political and economic
constellation. A currency board, at least in principle, required that
all pesos be backed one to one by hard currency reserves and thus
precluded central bank financing of the government--though, in practice,
Argentina designed convertibility in a way that gave the government room
to maneuver. (18)
Stabilization brought an economic boom. An expanding economy meant
growing revenues; privatization added substantial onetime gains. The
apparent success of the reform project and changes in global markets
combined to open new sources of market financing to the government.
These early gains allowed the government to reward supporters and to buy
off opponents to its other promarket reforms--a general pattern that
Dani Rodrik has emphasized. (19) But after the first gains from ending
inflation had been spent, Argentina's government came to rely more
and more on access to external capital markets to generate the resources
to lubricate Argentina's political system. (20)
The institutional power of the economy ministry in particular
hinged in no small part on its ability to deliver external financing.
This meant a delicate balancing act: to tap the markets, the economy
ministry needed to sell Argentina as a model of financial prudence, even
though the financing obtained on the back of such promises was needed to
pay for the spending ministries' priorities. External financing
delivered yet another benefit: external inflows meant that the current
account deficits associated with rapid growth never triggered the
currency board's automatic adjustment mechanism.
At the end of the decade, de la Rua may well have needed access to
external financing even more than Menem. Commenting on the politics of
the Menem era, the head of emerging markets research for JP Morgan
observed:
Menem's authority was very much influenced by his ability to provide
goods in exchange for favours. Once privatisation proceeds were
exhausted, the power of the executive branch was severely weakened. By
the time De la Rua took office, there was relatively little in the way
of goods to distribute to political leaders. Menem was in the position
to "give and splurge" while De la Rua was left with the task of
attempting to "take back and save." (21)
The ability "to provide goods in exchange for favours"
became more important, not less, when different parties controlled
different parts of the government. Market commentary at the time often
criticized de la Rua's political weakness, without observing that
the structural basis of strong executive leadership disappeared along
with access to external financing when the Peronists won control of the
legislature and the provinces.
When IMF-endorsed policies no longer generated the market financing
Argentina needed to avoid deflationary adjustment, it was eminently
logical for Argentina to seek financing from the IMF itself. IMF
financing specifically made fiscal easing a policy option for de la Rua
where it would not have been available otherwise.
Before turning to the IMF, de la Rua had backed tax hikes to curb a
deficit that was rising on the back of falling revenues and rising
interest payments (see Table 3). The Peronists promptly blamed the hikes
for Argentina's inability to grow. (22) The Peronist legislators
had no desire to provide political cover for unpopular spending cuts,
but imposing cuts by decree would have threatened de la Rua's
political position further: most constituencies, including the
provincial governors, wanted protection from a deflating economy, not a
program of shared sacrifice. (23) Since IMF financing allowed de la Rua
to make one last effort to "grow" out of the crisis, the
political costs of asking the IMF to finance the status quo were smaller
than the costs of the alternatives.
The IMF's willingness to finance a program that, at least
initially, supported a slight short-term loosening of fiscal policy is
more surprising than Argentina's desire for IMF support. (24)
However, at the end of 2000, IMF staff and management--and for that
matter the G7 and most market participants--were torn between two
competing analyses of Argentina's troubles. Some believed the core
problem was with Argentina's profligate public finances and
dysfunctional relations between the provinces and the center. Others saw
the problem as a temporary disruption in market access attributable to
Russia's default and a self-fulfilling loss of confidence brought
about by the economic slump that followed fiscal tightening. (25) The
split within the IMF, Argentina's reputation as a bastion of
IMF-backed market reforms, and widespread criticism of the IMF's
tight fiscal conditionality during Asia's crisis certainly
strengthened the hand of Argentina's negotiators. (26) The
credibility of the Fund's traditional policy prescription--fiscal
tightening--was nearly exhausted. The IMF was loath to be seen as the
constant enemy of growth.
Argentina's close relationship with the IMF, its reputation in
the markets, and intellectual currents that favored "corner"
exchange rate regimes after the collapse of various intermediate
"pegs" in the late 1990s all weighed against another policy
option: moving away from convertibility. Some prominent economists,
notably Paul Krugman, argued that Argentina's real problem was that
its exchange rate regime had, after the dollar's appreciation
against the euro and the Brazilian real, become inconsistent with
growth. Some US policymakers had sympathy for this view. However,
President Clinton's last treasury secretary, Larry Summers, was a
lame duck when Argentina's crisis broke. A truly bold course--like
pushing Argentina off its chosen exchange rate regime or making debt
restructuring a condition for IMF financing--would have reverberated
throughout the region. Such policy (or, for that matter, giving
Argentina a Mexico-style megabailout) would have required the sort of
sustained US leadership that Summers could not put on the table. In many
ways, the late-2000 program was a placeholder with relatively modest
upfront financial commitments that deferred hard decisions. But even if
Summers had had more political capital, Argentine policymakers likely
would have refused to abandon convertibility before exhausting other
options.
Turning to Cavallo and Yet More IMF Financing
The IMF's failure to lend Argentina yet more money in November
2001 to give convertibility yet another chance is not surprising.
Michael Mussa and Paul Blustein describe how staff and management
scepticism of Argentina's policy mix deepened during the course of
2001. (27) The puzzle is why Argentina's authorities refused to
discuss alternatives to convertibility and voluntary debt reschedulings
as economic, financial, and social conditions progressively
deteriorated. For all the attention to Cavallo's deviations from
economic orthodoxy--introducing special import tariffs and a financial
transactions tax, and talking abut pegging to both the euro and the
dollar--he continued the core policies of his predecessors. Cavallo has
suggested that Argentina should have moved off convertibility in the
late 1990s, before it came under pressure. (28) But in office, he
remained committed to it, refused to seek debt reduction, and eventually
resorted to orthodox fiscal tightening. (29) Cavallo's core
accomplishment was to draw on his considerable reputation to secure a
series of additional injections of IMF liquidity to finance what turned
out to be a classic gamble for resurrection.
Argentina's failure to meet the program's fiscal targets
provided an obvious point for all parties to reassess their strategy, as
did Argentina's request for yet more financing in the summer of
2001. But no one was willing to take the risk of changing course.
Even as popular support for sacrifice waned, no alternative to
convertibility commanded widespread support. Some wanted to float,
others wanted to dollarize, yet others wanted to devalue and dollarize.
In the face of a deteriorating economy, the only consensus inside
Argentina was to seek more IMF financing and to spend its remaining
reserves to defend the status quo. Blustein reports that convertibility
was the one subject Cavallo would not even discuss at a meeting with the
IMF on 7 December 2001--when Argentina had no real option other than to
exit.
This had a cost. N. Roubini and B. Setser have argued that the odds
that Argentina could have abandoned its peg and restructured its
external debts without freezing the banking system fell during the
course of 2001. Early in 2001, Argentina still had substantial reserves
and credit with the IMF to provide additional backing to the banking
system. (30) Yet any major change of course--including a policy based on
abandoning the peg and seeking a comprehensive debt restructuring (the
"Uruguay option")--also risked bringing about the complete
collapse of domestic confidence and extreme overshooting in the exchange
rate. The case for preemptive action hinged on the argument that it was
less risky than waiting--not that it guaranteed an easy path to
recovery.
Continued support for the status quo reflected a key economic
reality: all other policy options carried higher short-term costs than
trying to muddle through. Seeking meaningful debt relief meant losing
access to domestic and external credit and immediately moving into
fiscal and external balance. About half of Argentina's $90 billion
in bonds were held domestically; reducing the value of the
government's debt would reduce the financial wealth of those
Argentines who had invested in the debt--banks and pension funds as well
as wealthy Argentines with offshore accounts. (31) A deep restructuring
was not an alterative to adjustment; rather, it traded more short-term
pain for potential long-term gains. (32)
Abandoning convertibility and letting the peso float also held few
short-term political rewards. A wide swath of the Argentine society,
including the big winners from the 1990s reforms who dominated Argentine
politics, had extensive dollar-denominated debts and thus a financial
stake in dollar parity. This may explain why, in Argentina, the noisy
opposition to fiscal consolidation was not matched by an open political
debate about the costs of convertibility. Political analysts argue that
support for currency stability traditionally comes with trade
integration, as exporters and importers demand a stable--though not
necessarily strong--currency to facilitate commerce. (33) But
Argentina's overall trade was limited, and its trade with the
dollar zone was particularly small. Demand for a stable exchange rate
came from the nontradables sector, which, ironically, was heavily
foreign owned. Firms and households in this sector had borrowed in
dollars during the early convertibility boom and wanted a stable and
strong peso to facilitate access to new dollar financing or to
facilitate repayment of existing dollar debts. (34) Argentina's
eventual solution to the domestic dollar debt dilemma--converting
domestic loans into pesos, issuing compensation bonds to the banks, and
servicing these new bonds ahead of defaulted external debt--was too
radical for the government, or the IMF, to contemplate until the crisis
really bit.
Why Did Argentina Get More Money in the Summer of 2001?
Many in the IMF and the G7 finance community had serious doubts
about providing additional financing to Argentina in the summer of 2001.
Blustein reports that at an internal staff discussion, the optimists in
the IMF thought the augmentation had a less than 20 percent chance of
succeeding. IMF management nonetheless supported Argentina's
request. (35)
One explanation rests on the IMF's institutional aversion to
forcing a change in its member's currency regime. The IMF likes to
define its role as advising members on the policies needed to make their
own choice of exchange rate regimes work. Telling a country that it had
to let its currency fall and suffer the consequences of a disruptive
default was more than the Fund could bear. But it was also willing to go
the extra mile and provide Argentina with extra financing largely
because it hoped that the money would help inoculate it from blame for
Argentina's collapse. The IMF's leadership calculated that its
reputation would suffer less if Argentina got one last chance and then
failed to live up to a demanding adjustment program. When Cavallo
refused to discuss options for exiting from convertibility, the IMF did
not press--in part because, as Blustein writes, "If IMF officials
explicitly urged a devaluation, Cavallo could hold them accountable for
the outcome." (36)
The IMF's major shareholders also bear responsibility for the
decision to disburse. After blessing an unprecedented bailout for Turkey
(a critical strategic ally in a critically important region) in the
spring of 2001, the new Bush administration had a clear opportunity in
Argentina to break from the "jumbo" packages of the Clinton
era that many administration officials had criticized (37) and show that
fear of contagion would not drive policy. The head of the National
Economic Council, Lawrence Lindsey, and Treasury Secretary Paul
O'Neill both had indicated that they opposed IMF bailouts that had
little chance of working. However, the Bush administration was not
monolithic. The foreign policy team did not want to create the
impression that the administration was turning its back on Latin
America. Eric Helleiner suggests that, among other things, the White
House saw Argentina as central to its efforts to create a
hemisphere-wide free trade zone. (38) And it is plausible that the
president himself did not share his economic team's aversion to
bailouts: as governor of Texas, George W. Bush had backed the Clinton
administration's bailout of Mexico.
However, chances were slim for a Mexico-style success.
Argentina's government debt to GDP ratio, its external debt to GDP
ratio, its external debt to export ratio, and its level of
"liability dollarization" were all far higher than in Mexico.
(39) No one in the new administration stepped up with a comprehensive,
workable plan and insisted that the international community and the
crisis country coalesce around this plan, as Rubin and Summers had done
in Mexico. Rather, US policy coalesced around a fleeting compromise
among different parts of the administration: Argentina got a $5 billion
augmentation along with the scheduled $1 billion under the original
program to stem the bank run but, at O'Neill's insistence,
also received $3 billion to back a market operation to improve debt
sustainability. O'Neill's own staff, the IMF, the US Council
of Economic Advisers, and market participants involved in the
short-lived discussions of the operation all came away convinced that $3
billion was patently insufficient to catalyze a $100 billion
restructuring. (40) Argentina never put forward its own proposal. (41)
Bush treasury officials never pressed the Fund to push Argentina to
consider alternatives to convertibility, perhaps because key officials
did not agree among themselves on an alternative. Treasury Secretary
O'Neill publicly suggested that Argentina needed to let its
exchange rate float. Yet, after Argentina floated, O'Neill's
chief deputy for international affairs, John Taylor, testified in
Congress that he believed that Argentina should have dollarized--but
that it was not his place to tell this to the Argentines. (42)
Neither did the rest of the G7 press. Many economic and financial
policymakers, led by the Bank of England, believed that Argentina could
not be saved; however, European political leaders were reluctant to
block a multilateral support package that had US backing.
Key Decisions in 2002: Pesification
By the end of 2001, Argentina could not avoid devaluing the peso
and defaulting on its external debt. A bank holiday was no longer
avoidable: the banking system lacked dollars, and the government did not
have nearly enough dollar reserves--even after breaking
convertibility--to back all dollar deposits. (43) But Argentina did not
have to pesify, or to convert deposits and loans into pesos at different
rates (asymmetrically), or to index interest payments on loans to
increases in peso wages, and the consumer price index and interest
payments on deposits to increases in the consumer price index. After
considerable pressure and litigation, the government eventually issued
new low-coupon bonds to compensate banks for the 40 percent difference
in conversion rates.
The final outcome reflected political limits on the scale of losses
that a democratic government could impose on depositors; it also
reflected economic constraints on the scale of the losses the government
could impose on banks. The political imperative to help depositors
regain access to their frozen deposits is not hard to understand.
Citizens wanted their money back. The economic constraints are harder to
grasp. The populist policy of asymmetric pesification initially pushed
enormous paper losses onto the banks' owners. But there is no way
to force a bank's owners to lose more money than they had put up in
capital. It soon became clear that the government would either have to
pick up some of the tab, or, in the words of one policymaker, take the
keys to every bank in Argentina--a politically untenable outcome.
Despite its myriad of detractors, pesification has proved to be a
qualified success: it instantly restructured domestic contacts and
restored payment flows; it made it possible to unfreeze deposits
relatively rapidly; and, by resolving the internal payments crisis, it
helped lay the basis for Argentina's current recovery.
No bankruptcy regime is designed to function effectively when
insolvency is the norm rather than the exception. After the devaluation,
almost all firms, households, and individuals with dollar debts were
effectively bankrupt. (44) Some form of across-the-board solution was
needed: the banks neither had the capacity to assume control over all
technically insolvent firms nor the ability to monitor the behavior of
this many debtors. (45) Keeping deposits frozen while restructuring
banks on a case-by-case basis was neither politically nor economically
viable. Across-the-board reduction in the debts of small firms and
households had another virtue: it allowed scarce workout resources to be
devoted to the biggest and most important cases.
Nonetheless, pesification has many flaws. The government lacked the
capacity to convince firms, banks, and markets that the measure was a
legitimate response to the unprecedented difficulties from ending
convertibility rather than a populist attack on the banking sector. (46)
Initial decisions on conversion rates and indexation were arbitrary.
Those who benefited most from the initial pesification decision paid
down their pesified debts quickly; those who lost sought and often
obtained compensation.
It is reasonable to ask if domestic debtors should have picked up
more of the cost of the crisis, leaving less to be borne by other
stakeholders. One-to-one pesification and indexation effectively kept
the real debt burden constant for domestic firms without export
revenues. That was broadly right. On the one hand, given the scale of
economic contraction, any solution that was substantially less favorable
to debtors without export revenues risked leading to more nonperforming
loans--and the deadweight losses associated with more widespread
bankruptcy. (47) On the other hand, influential dollar debtors lobbied
hard to extend a solution initially meant to cover only mortgages and
other small loans to cover Argentina's biggest firms. (48) It might
have been possible to do something that offered less relief to the firms
with more capacity to weather the crisis. (49)
The Consequences of the Crisis
In 2001, Argentina used its substantial reserves and IMF funds to
buy time in the hope that its troubles would pass. In the process, it
dug itself into a deeper hole and, in our view, increased the scale of
the resulting crisis. (50) Clearly, no strategy would have avoided large
losses. Correcting the real overvaluation of the peso required a fall in
the real income of most Argentines. Most domestic financial assets were
dollar-denominated claims on borrowers who had no way of earning enough
dollars to pay their debts in full. The resulting restructuring had to
reduce the real value of many domestic financial assets.
But even if delay increased losses overall, some benefited from it.
The domestic depositors who moved their funds ($16 billion) abroad in
2001 were the biggest beneficiaries of delay. The real domestic value of
assets moved offshore increased substantially after the devaluation. The
banks' short-term external creditors who cut their exposure by $8
billion also benefited, as did those holding the $6.5 billion in bonds
that came due in 2001. Investment bankers earned large fees on
Argentina's megaswap.
Big losers include all private creditors who provided additional
financing to Argentina in 2001. Argentines with accounts in Argentine
pension funds and Argentines who kept money in the banking system bore
the bulk of domestic losses--though the restructuring ultimately
protected the real domestic value of their investments, limiting the
domestic political fallout. The IMF, which provided roughly $10 billion
in net new financing in 2001, recently got repaid in full ahead of
schedule: lending to Argentina damaged the IMF's reputation, but
not its financial health.
Clear winners from Argentina's decisions to abandon
convertibility, to default, and to pesify include Argentina's
exporters and import-competing industries, which gained both from the
devaluation and from pesification if they had borrowed locally in
dollars. Farmers did particularly well: their dollar debts were pesified
just before the harvest brought in an influx of dollar revenue. Indeed,
relative to most alternative scenarios, those who borrowed dollars under
Argentine law won: the compensation bonds issued to cover the costs of
asymmetric pesification were a subsidy that Argentine taxpayers granted
to bank borrowers as well as to bank depositors.
The clear losers are Argentina's external bondholders. They
had to wait over three years for a restructuring offer, and the terms of
the final restructuring were far less generous than in other sovereign
restructurings. Those who accepted reduced the face value of their
claims by about 50 percent in the aggregate and had to accept relatively
low coupon payments for a long time. Using market discount rates, the
new bonds issued in the exchange were worth about 32 cents on the
original dollar. (51) External creditors ended up subsidizing
Argentina's domestic bank compensation scheme. Argentine taxpayers
are another likely loser--they will be paying off the domestic debts
from the crisis for a long time. (52)
One of the more salient factors of the postrestructuring period is
that many of the groups that benefited the most from
convertibility--external bondholders, private banks, the owners of
privatized utilities--have been among the biggest losers, while some
groups who lost out before the crisis have emerged as the biggest
beneficiaries of the new policy regime.
However, the impact of many decisions remains ambiguous five years
after the default. Although domestic bank depositors believe they are
among the losers, since they did not get paid in full, they in fact did
better in the restructuring than Argentina's other creditors. (53)
Domestic bank owners decry asymmetric pesification and court injunctions
(amparos). But compensation bonds and, for local banks, the regulatory
leeway to value compensation bonds at par helped. Foreign banks may have
benefited from pesification (particularly after compensation) as
compared to the alternative of foreclosure on scores of
dollar-denominated mortgages after the devaluation. Regulated utilities
gained from the pesification of their domestic debts even as they were
hurt by Argentina's price freeze. Spanish-owned Telefonica did not
come out badly: most of its debts were pesified, and its declining costs
reduced the impact of the price freeze. French-owned Telecom did worse,
because more of its debt was foreign law (and thus not pesified).
Domestic energy firms were hit especially hard, because their prices
remained frozen while world energy prices rose. The large number of
ongoing challenges to the emergency measures from foreign-owned
utilities makes any final assessment of their losses premature.
Argentina's urban poverty rose steadily during the recession,
reaching 38 percent just before the devaluation. It peaked at 58 percent
in October 2002 and fell back to just under 34 percent in the second
half of 2005. (54) Devaluation likely brought forward the increase in
poverty that was bound to accompany Argentina's external
adjustment, which required a fall in Argentina's real income. The
poor also suffered from rising unemployment and the increase in the
price of basic necessities. The peso price of food--a tradable good
priced in dollars--soared after the devaluation. In this context, using
the proceeds from the export tax to pay a subsidy to the poor (the
"heads of household" program) can be viewed as a way of
redistributing gains from the devaluation to help those hurt the most.
Default affected the poor indirectly. Those who were poor before
2001 generally did not own government bonds and had little savings in
the banking system. However, both before and after default, the
government's perilous finances constrained its ability to ease the
suffering of Argentina's vulnerable population with large transfer
payments. In 2001, Argentina's ability to help the poor was
constrained by its large and growing interest bill. After 2001, the
government initially lacked access to credit and had to finance all
spending out of tax revenues. Printing money would have led to
inflation, which disproportionately hurts the poor. Government spending
on the poor increased after default and devaluation, but the rise did
not keep pace with growing poverty, so spending per poor person fell.
Conclusion
No easy path was open to Argentina in 2001. Nonetheless, the IMF
got both the economics and politics wrong by continuing to support
Argentina's attempts to cling to its peg and avoid a restructuring
through 2001. In 2001, the IMF bet that continued support for
convertibility would be less risky politically, even if the economics
did not work. However, the IMF underestimated the extent to which it
would be blamed for backing a failed system. Conversely, in early 2002,
the IMF refused to lend to Argentina and effectively bet that
Argentina's attempt to stabilize the peso, the domestic banking
system, and the government's finances would fail. It did not. By
the summer of 2002, the relationship between the IMF and Argentina had
changed for good: Argentina's policymakers now looked at the IMF as
just another creditor to be satisfied at the lowest possible cost.
Yet Argentina's leaders would be hard pressed to attribute the
policy mistakes of 2001 to pressure from the IMF or its shareholders.
Argentina opted to use all its potential sources of flexibility going
into 2001--the banking system's liquid reserves, the pension
system's free cash flow, Argentina's capacity to borrow from
the IMF, Argentina's relationship with the US government--not to
develop a way out of its economic and political trap, but rather to
mount an extended, painful, and ultimately futile defense of
convertibility.
Argentina's political establishment, not the IMF, set
Argentina's 2001 policy course. However, access to IMF financing
opened up policy options that otherwise would have been unavailable to
Argentina's establishment. De la Rua got the financing to defer
fiscal tightening in the face of a recession in late 2000. Cavallo got
the financing to try to loosen the constraints of covertibility without
abandoning it--and yet more financing to avoid shutting down the banking
system. But IMF financing also allowed successive Argentine governments
to avoid the really hard choices needed to put Argentina on a clear
pathway out of its crisis. Argentina did not seek debt reduction until
after it lost access to IMF funding. From that point on,
Argentina's government charted its own course, going so far as to
walk away from a Fund review in 2004 with great fanfare in the name of
preserving its negotiating independence.
In 2001, though, no one in Argentina wanted to "own" the
painful steps it had to take to escape from the trap created by
extensive dollar debts and an overvalued exchange rate. The IMF, the
United States, and the other G7 countries were equally reluctant to push
Argentina toward developing a workable exit plan. The US administration
neither wanted to be perceived as turning away from Argentina, a
promarket Latin friend in need, nor wanted the responsibility for
foisting a potentially costly solution on reluctant Argentines. And the
IMF seemed more eager to avoid responsibility for the messy decisions
Argentina would have to take than to help Argentina develop a workable
Plan B.
Notes
Brad Setser is a research associate of the Global Economic
Governance Programme and a senior economist at Roubini Global Economics.
He served as acting director of the office responsible for US policy
toward the International Monetary Fund at the US Treasury Department and
was a visiting scholar at the International Monetary Fund. His work
focuses on the reform of the international financial architecture,
sovereign debt restructurings, and global imbalances. Anna Gelpern is an
associate professor of law at Rutgers University School of Law, Newark,
and the Rutgers University Graduate Division of Global Affairs. She is
also a visiting fellow at the Institute for International Economics, and
has served in legal and policy positions at the US Treasury Department.
Her recent writing focuses on sovereign debt and systemic crises.
The authors would like to thank Ngaire Woods and the Global
Economic Governance Programme, the Council on Foreign Relations, and all
those in Argentina who were so generous in sharing their time and
insights.
1. Convertability generally refers to the ability to convert the
national currency into foreign currency without restriction. In the
Argentine context, "convertability" became short-hand for
Argentina's currency broad arrangement--a policy that pegged the
peso to the dollar at a 1:1 rate and required Argentina's central
bank to back pesos in circulation with hard currency reserves as well as
guaranteeing the free convertability of the national currency.
2. G. Perry and L. Serven, Argentina: What Went Wrong (Washington,
DC: World Bank, May 2003). The World Bank estimates that the peso was
overvalued by roughly 40 percent, with about half the overvaluation
explained by the dollar's appreciation. See also Independent
Evaluation Office, "The IMF and Argentina, 1991-2001"
(Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 30 September 2004); and
Mario Blejer, "Managing the Financial Crisis in Argentina,"
powerpoint presentation at the World Bank's "Practitioners of
Development" seminar series, Washington, DC, 22 October 2003.
3. N. Roubini, "Should Argentina Dollarize or Float? The Pros
and Cons of Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes and Their Implications for
Domestic and Foreign Debt Restructuring/Reduction," New York
University (manuscript, 2 December 2001), available at
www.stern.nyu.edu/~nroubini/asia/argentinadollarization.doc. Roubini
emphasizes that the real exchange rate adjustment brought about by
deflation increases the real burden of foreign currency-denominated
debts in the same way as a nominal depreciation.
4. Javier Fronti, Marcus Miller, and Lei Zhang, "Sovereign
Default by Argentina: 'Slow-Motion Train Crash' or
Self-Fulfilling Crisis?" CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3399 (London:
Centre for Economic Policy Research, May 2002), available at
www.cepr.org.
5. The year 1999 was the only year nominal noninterest spending
sharply increased.
6. Wall Street Journal, 13 January 2004.
7. See, among others, A. Ades, Emerging Market FX and Bond Views,
Goldman Sachs, 30 October 2003.
8. Cavallo reduced mandatory reserve requirements to free up bank
credit, allowed the banks to reduce the quality of their remaining
reserves by encouraging the banks to sell US treasuries to buy a new
government bond (generating a capital inflow of $2 billion), introduced
a set of tax subsidies to help firms facing competition from Brazil, and
signaled his intent to change the currency board from a pure dollar peg
to a dollar-euro peg.
9. Republic of Argentina, prospectus supplement dated 10 January
2005, and prospectus dated 27 December 2004, filed pursuant to Rule
424(b)(5) under the US Securities Act of 1933, Registration No.
333-117111 (Washington, DC: United States Securities and Exchange
Commission), p. 165, available at www.sec.gov (accessed 12 June 2006).
10. The swap did not cover euro-denominated bonds, yet these bonds
accounted for a large share of Argentina's near-term external debt
payments. For more, see N. Roubini and B. Setser, Bailouts or Bail-Ins
(Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2004); and M.
Mussa, Argentina and the Fund: From Triumph to Tragedy, Policy Analyses
in International Economics No. 67 (Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economics, March 2002).
11. V. Miles, "Argentine Banks. Why Deposits Hold the
Key," JP Morgan, 23 July 2001.
12. See Mussa, Argentina and the Fund, pp. 40-46.
13. Short-term lines fell from $28 billion to $20 billion during
the course of 2001. See World Bank, Global Development Finance
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 2003).
14. The government continued to tap local banks for financing,
particularly those local banks that depended on support from the central
bank.
15. Primary expenditures fell from 18.6 percent to 17.2 percent of
GDP. Argentina's fiscal stabilization did not come just from ending
interest payments.
16. The provinces' enduring independence is in stark contrast
to the power of the Argentine presidency over the legislature and even
the judiciary. Most presidents have had a working majority in the
legislature as well as the ability to use decree power to shift the
power balance between the executive and the legislature. See L. A.
Romero, A History of Argentina in the Twentieth Century, trans. J. P.
Brennan (University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press, 2002).
17. Mussa, Argentina and the Fund.
18. Argentina allowed some of the monetary base to be backed by the
government's own dollar-denominated bonds rather than true reserve
assets. It also kept more reserves on hand than required just to back
the pesos in circulation. See Kurt Schuler, "Ignorance and
Influence: U.S. Economists on Argentina's Depression of
1998-2002," Econ Journal Watch 2, no. 2 (August 2005).
19. D. Rodrik, "Understanding Economic Policy Reform,"
Journal of Economic Literature 34, no. 1 (1996), argues that the
"liberalize, stabilize, privatize" policy package typical of
many "reform" programs of the early 1990s used the large,
broad-based gains from ending hyperinflation to help compensate the
losers from other reforms, which often had ambiguous or negative
distributional effects.
20. Pamela K. Starr, "Government Coalitions and the Viability
of Currency Boards: Argentina Under the Cavallo Plan," Journal of
Inter American Studies and World Affairs 39, no. 2 (Summer 1997).
21. Joyce Chang, "Comments and Discussion on the Argentine
Papers," Brookings Trade Forum 2002 (Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 2002).
22. The 2001 IMF program assumed that Argentina would retain access
to captive domestic sources.
23. The point can be extended even further. Many of
Argentina's privatized utilities had the right to index their
prices to the US dollar and to increase their prices in line with US
inflation even as other prices in Argentina were falling. Neither the
utilities nor Argentina's labor unions were volunteering to give up
their hard-fought privileges.
24. International Monetary Fund, Argentina: Second Review Under the
Stand-by Arrangement and Request for Augmentation--Staff Report, IMF
Country Report 01/26 (Washington, DC: IMF, 2001). See also International
Monetary Fund, "Lessons from the Crisis in Latin America"
(Washington, DC: IMF, 9 October 2003).
25. M. Gavin, "Argentina Update: Drowning in a Cup of
Water," UBS Warburg, 29 October 2000.
26. The Argentine and Asian crises, however, were not analogous.
Several Asian governments had little government debt going into their
crisis, though they had large contingent liabilities as a result of weak
banking systems.
27. Mussa, Argentina and the Fund; Paul Blustein, And the Money
Kept Rolling In (and Out): Wall Street, the IMF and the Bankrupting of
Argentina (New York: Public Affairs, 2005).
28. Domingo Cavallo, "Argentina and the IMF During the Two
Bush Administrations," International Finance 7, no. 1 (2004).
Cavallo wanted Argentina to peg to a currency basket that more closely
reflected Argentina's trade mix.
29. Cavallo's own statement in 2004 that a currency basket
should have replaced the dollar peg is consistent with his efforts to
modify "convertibility" in ways that made it less restrictive
in the first part of 2001. Cavallo may have hoped to use the credibility
he gained as the father of convertibility to change it in ways others
could not, without being accused of abandoning the arrangement. He was,
however, unwilling to go further. See Cavallo, "Argentina and the
IMF," and Fronti, Miller, and Zhang, "Sovereign Default by
Argentina."
30. At the end of 2000, Argentina had $27 billion in reserves, and
the banking system held an additional $7 billion in cash and mandatory
liquidity reserves in an offshore account. Argentina might have
supplemented this $34 billion pool of reserves with a $15 billion loan
from the IMF. The parent firms of foreign-owned banks might have been
willing to contribute to help back their local operations. Argentine
banks had only $49 billion in dollar deposits at the time, along with
$18 billion in short-term external liabilities and around 35 billion in
peso-denominated deposits. See International Monetary Fund,
"Debt-Related Vulnerabilities and Financial Crises: An Application
of the Balance Sheet Approach to Emerging Market Countries"
(Washington, DC: IMF, 1 July 2004); Roubini and Setser, Bailouts or
Bail-Ins; and Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In (and Out).
31. Giselle Datz, "Pension Privatization and the Politics of
Sovereign Default," Rutgers University (manuscript, 2006).
32. The political difficulty of selling a restructuring was
compounded by the technical challenges to a preemptive restructuring
created by the size and complexity of Argentina's external debt.
Uruguay's bonded debt was roughly one-twentieth the size of
Argentina's, with a considerably less diverse range of holders and
instruments.
33. Argentina's currency board never fit entirely comfortably
with either economic or political models that seek to explain exchange
rate preferences. Economically, it was clearly not an optimal currency
area with the United States. Nor was it the small open economy that
political theorists suggest favor a fixed currency to meet the demands
of commercial interests. See Jeffrey Frieden, "The Political
Economy of Dollarization: Domestic and International Factors," in
Dollarization: Debates and Policy Alternatives, Eduardo Levy-Yeyati and
Federico Sturnzenegger (eds.) (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001); and
Jeffrey Frieden and Ernesto Stein, "The Political Economy of
Exchange Rate Policy in Latin America: An Analytical Overview," in
The Currency Game: Exchange Rate Politics in Latin America, Jeffrey
Frieden and Ernesto Stein, eds. (Baltimore: John Hopkins University
Press, 2002).
34. Liliana Rojas-Suarez has noted that Argentina's banking
system was in far worse health than most believed because of its
extensive dollar lending to firms that lacked export revenues. See
Liliana Rojas-Suarez, "Comments and Discussion on the Argentine
Papers," Brookings Trade Forum 2002 (Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 2003).
35. Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In (and Out), pp. 155-156,
183-184.
36. Ibid., p. 184. Blustein writes: "As an institution, the
IMF would not muster sufficient gumption to proactively impel the
Argentines to change course in a fundamental way before disaster struck.
Nor would the U.S. Treasury, which could have intervened directly (as
the Clintonites had in previous crises) but would instead defer to the
Fund."
37. Ron Suskind, The Price of Loyalty: George W. Bush, the White
House, and the Education of Paul O'Neill (New York: Simon &
Schuster, 2004).
38. Eric Helleiner, "The Strange Story of Bush and the
Argentine Debt Crisis," Third World Quarterly 26, no. 6 (2005).
39. Both Robert Rubin and Larry Summers believed Mexico's exit
from its peg was central to the success of the rescue package. See
Robert E. Rubin and Jacob Weisberg, In an Uncertain World: Tough Choices
from Wall Street to Washington (New York: Random House, 2003).
40. For more, see Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In (and
Out).
41. At the discount rates Argentine debt traded at in the fall of
2001, any market-based exchange would have been prohibitively expensive.
Three billion dollars allowed Argentina to buy back $4 billion in
short-term debt or $6 billion in longer-term debt--a drop in the bucket
for a country with $90 billion in debt. To get around this proposal,
most investment bank proposals made at the time assumed a far larger
commitment of official funds--say $20 billion--to back an exchange.
42. John Taylor, Senate testimony, 2002.
43. In August, it might have been economically possible to have
closed down some locally owned banks without triggering a run on
foreign-owned banks, so long as it was clear the foreign owners of
foreign-owned local banks were willing to back their local operations.
By December, this option was clearly no longer economically viable. It
was never politically viable. Closing Galicia--the largest
Argentine-owned private bank--without closing Nacion or Provincia--the
large publicly owned banks--would have been hard to justify financially,
yet closing Nacion and Provincia was politically impossible. Nacion was
the only bank in many smaller communities; Provincia was tightly linked
with the governor of the province of Buenos Aires. Moreover, at the
time, Argentina relied heavily on these banks for emergency financing,
sometimes involving rather questionable transactions.
44. The prospect that a firm's equity investors would lose
control of the firm in the bankruptcy process is the key incentive for
payment.
45. Anna Gelpern, "Systemic Bank and Corporate Distress from
Asia to Argentina: What Have We Learned?" International Finance 7,
no. 1 (2004): 151-168.
46. Randall S. Kroszner, "Is It Better to Forgive Than to
Receive? An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Debt Repudiation,"
Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 2003; Randall S.
Kroszner, "Is It Better to Forgive Than to Receive? History Lessons
Guide Policy Choices," Capital Ideas: Selected Papers from the
Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, University of
Chicago Graduate School of Business, February 2006, available at
www.chicagogsb.edu/capideas/feb06/4.aspx; Marcus Miller, Javier
Garcia-Fronti, and Lei Zhang, "Contractionary Devaluation and
Credit Crunch: Analysing Argentina," 2005, unpublished manuscript,
available at www.bde.es/doctrab/seminar/sie0519.pdf; and Gelpern,
"Systemic Bank and Corporate Distress."
47. Kroszner, "Debt Repudiation."
48. See Mario Blejer, "An interview with Mario Blejer,"
Central Banking 13, no. 1 (August 2002).
49. Most large firms had external as well as domestic debts and
were not able to avoid bankruptcy in any case.
50. For a similar view, see Ricardo Hausmann and Andres Velasco,
"Hard Money's Soft Underbelly: Understanding the Argentine
Crisis," Brookings Trade Forum 2002 (Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 2003).
51. Government of Argentina, "Argentina Announces Results of
Successful Exchange Offer," Secretariat of Finance, Ministry of
Economy and Production, Buenos Aires, 18 March 2005, www.mecon.ar;
Republic of Argentina, "Recent Restructuring Developments,"
SEC form 18-K/A, Secretariat of Finance, Ministry of Economy and
Production, Buenos Aires, September 2004, www.mecon.ar; Mario Damill,
Roberto Frenkel, and Martin Rapetti, "The Argentine Debt: History,
Default and Restructuring," CEDES, Buenos Aires, August 2005
revision.
52. Cooper and Bessma and Miller and Fronti describe
Argentina's successful efforts to play creditor constituencies
against one another. See Andrew F. Cooper and Momani Bessma,
"Negotiating Out of Argentina's Financial Crisis: Segmenting
the International Creditors," New Political Economy 10, no. 3
(September 2005); and Marcus Miller and Javier Garcia Fronti, "Case
Study: Restructuring Argentine Debt: A Renegotiation Game?"
University of Warwick and CEPR, September 2005, available at
www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/csgr/research/keytopic/global/csgr28febversion.pdf.
53. Anna Gelpern and Brad Setser, "Domestic and External Debt:
The Doomed Quest for Equal Treatment," Georgetown Journal of
International Law 795 (Summer 2004): 35.
54. World Bank, "Country Assistance Strategy for the Argentine
Republic 2006-2008," annex F: Poverty and Social Development
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 6 June 2006).
Table 1 Access to Domestic and External Financing (in US$ billions)
Net Private Net Financing Net Financing
External from the from the Increase in
Year Financing Bonds Market IMF and MDBs Bank Deposits
1995 13.2 2.4 3.8 -2.9
1996 11.5 10.0 1.1 8.9
1997 14.5 8.4 0.4 13.1
1998 16.8 11.6 2.3 8.9
1999 3.4 2.8 1.3 5.5
2000 1.3 -0.8 1.4 3.7
2001 -6.4 -9.2 10.6 -19.8
1996-1998 42.8 30 3.8 30.9
(fat years)
1999-2001 -1.7 -7.2 13.3 -10.6
(lean years)
Source: Government of Argentina, external debt statistics; and BCRA.
Table 2 History of Lending Arrangements, 1 May 1984-31 May 1996 (in
thousands of SDRs (a))
Date of
Date of Expiration or Amount
Facility Arrangement Cancellation Agreed
Standby arrangement 20 Sept. 2003 5 Jan. 2006 8,981,000
Standby arrangement 24 Jan. 2003 31 Aug. 2003 2,174,500
Standby arrangement of 10 Mar. 2000 23 Jan. 2003 16,936,800
which Supplemental
Reserve Facility 12 Jan. 2001 11 Jan. 2002 6,086,660
Extended Fund Facility 04 Feb. 1998 10 Mar. 2000 2,080,000
Standby arrangement 12 Apr. 1996 11 Jan. 1998 720,000
Extended Fund Facility 31 Mar. 1992 30 Mar. 1996 4,020,250
Standby arrangement 29 July 1991 30 Mar. 1992 780,000
Standby arrangement 10 Nov. 1989 31 Mar. 1991 736,000
Standby arrangement 23 July 1987 30 Sept. 1988 947,500
Standby arrangement 28 Dec. 1984 30 June 1986 1,182,500
Total 38,558,550
Amount Amount
Facility Drawn Outstanding
Standby arrangement 4,171,000 0
Standby arrangement 2,174,500 0
Standby arrangement of 9,756,310 0
which Supplemental
Reserve Facility 5,874,950 0
Extended Fund Facility 0 0
Standby arrangement 613,000 0
Extended Fund Facility 4,020,250 0
Standby arrangement 438,750 0
Standby arrangement 506,000 0
Standby arrangement 616,500 0
Standby arrangement 1,182,500 0
Total 23,478,810 0
Source: International Monetary Fund, available at
www.imf.org/external/np/tre/tad/extarr2.cfm?memberKeyl=30&date1key=
2006%2D05%2D31.
Note: a. Special drawing rights is a unit of account in the IMF, whose
value is based on a basket of key international currencies. As at 18
August 2006, 1 SDR was worth $1.48672.
Table 3 Fiscal and Public Debt Indicators
Interest
Payments Implicit RER Adjusted
on Debt Interest Rate Primary Debt to GDP Debt to GDP
(% of GDP) (% of GDP) Balance (%) (%)
1991 2.8 8.6 -0.4 28 28
1992 1.6 6.2 1.4 24 24
1993 1.4 5.0 1.2 28 28
1994 1.6 5.1 -0.1 29 29
1995 1.9 5.4 -1.0 32 32
1996 2.1 5.6 -1.3 35 35
1997 2.3 6.1 0.2 38 39
1998 2.6 6.4 0.6 41 46
1999 3.4 7.1 -1.6 48 63
2000 4.1 8.0 0.3 51 71
2001 5.4 8.7 -1.4 62 95
2002 2.4 0.9 151
2003 2.4 2.4 149
Source: From G. Perry and L. Serven, Argentina: What Went Wrong
(Washington, DC: World Bank, May 2003); International Monetary Fund,
Argentina: Request for a Standby Arrangement and Request for an
Extension of Repurchase Expectations (Washington, DC: IMF, September
2003).