Crisis in Cancun.
Wilkinson, Rorden
In opulent surroundings, representatives of the World Trade
Organization's (WTO) 146 member states met 10-14 September 2003 in
Cancun to discuss progress in the so-called development
round--officially the Doha Development Agenda--named after the meeting
that launched the negotiations. The task at hand was difficult: to
relieve the deadlock plaguing the trade agenda and in so doing agree to
concessions designed to address the development concerns of the Global
South, while placating the North's desire to begin negotiations on
multilateral agreements on investment, government procurement, trade
facilitation, and competition policy (the so-called Singapore issues).
The fault line was agriculture, a notoriously awkward area. All of the
usual players were in town: legions of trade officials from the
industrial North; significantly fewer representatives from the more
numerous countries of the South; protestors; nongovernmental
organizations (NGOs); the press; organizing committee officials;
onlookers; and heavy security consisting of armed police, co-opted
personnel and, most formidably, three Mexican warships.
The draft declaration produced prior to the meeting failed to
provide the basis on which negotiation and agreement could ensue. The
production of a second draft declaration midway through the ministerial
proved little better. The meeting finally collapsed when conference
chair Mexican foreign minister Luis Ernesto Derbez called a close to
proceedings. In spite of a rather ironic ministerial declaration that
"considerable progress" has been made in Cancun, little hope
exists that the round will be concluded by its 1 January 2005 deadline.
Amid all the grandstanding, commentary, protests, proposals for
ways forward, suggestions for institutional reform, and calls for
disbanding the WTO that inevitably accompany and follow such a meeting
(especially one that collapses), a deeper and potentially more
troublesome problem has been passed over. The problem arises from the
answer to one simple question: What if the differences over agriculture
and the so-called Singapore issues are resolved, an agreement is
reached, and the negotiations are eventually concluded? This question
warrants serious consideration given that the history of international
trade negotiations is littered with examples that suggest that Cancun is
not unique; that it is merely an expected, albeit frustrating,
punctuation of the negotiations; and that the negotiations will
inevitably reach a conclusion. Contemporary comment and historical
evidence support this claim.
In the immediate aftermath of the Cancun meeting, conference chair
Derbez came in for considerable criticism for his decision to call the
meeting to an early close part way through the final day. Previous
meetings have shown that it is not unusual for vigorous negotiations to
begin only in the very late stages and for meetings to be extended as a
result. Moreover, it appears that key member states had begun to move
away from their entrenched positions. In the late stages of the meeting,
the European Union (EU), whose position seemed to be set in stone, had
suggested it was prepared to consider "unbundling" the
Singapore issues. This would have left negotiations on the more
contentious issues--investment and competition policy--to a later date
in return for movement in other areas (largely agriculture).
Second, the preceding Uruguay Round was also characterized by what
seemed to be a significant setback. The fallout over agriculture between
the EU and the United States, mixed in with a desire to bring certain
trade-related issues (intellectual property rights and investment
measures) into the fray, culminated in an infamous hiatus in the round.
Paralleling much contemporary comment, this hiatus led many to suggest
that the demise of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was
nigh. (1)
Third, the breakdown of the meeting in Cancun has succeeded in
underlining developing country concerns, but a more permanent rupture in
the WTO would not bode so well. Although developing countries were able
to stand firm by forming large coalitions, no such comfort exists
outside of the WTO. The current U.S. administration has stated that due
to a lack of progress in the WTO, it will pursue its trade goals
bilaterally. In such circumstances, developing states will find it
harder to resist pressures to agree to open up markets and to lobby for
reductions in U.S. subsidy regimes. As such, the WTO represents the best
forum in which developing countries can exercise negotiating power.
Fourth, whereas the previous well-publicized breakdown in a WTO
meeting in Seattle in 1999 generated sympathy for issues of development
among the wider membership, the collapse of a second meeting is unlikely
to produce such a result. Indeed, post-Cancun commentary from the major
players suggests an acute frustration with the actions of developing
states and an expressed desire to "reform" WTO procedures to
ensure that such events are not a feature of future meetings.
Fifth, bargaining is at the root of the international trade regime.
Trade negotiations are based on reciprocal exchange. In such situations,
the outcomes are agreed only when a perceived balancing of concessions
offered and received has been achieved--that is, once a bargain has been
struck. It is inevitable then--particularly given the number of players
involved, the complexity and breadth of the issues at hand, and the
pressure to appear to be bringing a good deal back home--that
negotiations will periodically break down. That said, the time and
investment already exerted in WTO processes and the perceived benefits
from a conclusion to the round suggest a deal will inevitably be struck.
This final point is the most troubling. That a bargain will
eventually be arrived at--probably consisting of an agreement to move
forward on one or two of the Singapore issues in return for movements in
agriculture--is perhaps not startling news. What is more illuminating is
the consequence that such a settlement will have when laid upon the
existing foundations of the international trade regime.
The WTO's system of regulation is built on a series of legal
agreements that better suit the economic needs of the industrial states
than their developing counterparts. More than that, it is a system of
regulation that favors the economic preferences and legal customs of its
founding members (contracting parties, as they were known under GATT).
It is instructive to note that as each new layer of regulation is added,
whether in terms of rules and disciplines in new areas or tariff
reductions and other concessions, the asymmetry in WTO rules is
amplified. In this way, the WTO's legal framework resembles a
poorly layered cake. This asymmetry cannot, however, be fully
appreciated by examining the content of bargains struck at set moments
in time; it can be comprehended only when set within the context of a
wider understanding of the evolution of multilateral trade regulation
under the GATT/WTO.
The current system of international trade regulation over which the
WTO presides builds on the disciplines first developed under GATT.
Though itself originally intended to be a provisional agreement paving
the way for a more extensive system of regulation administered by the
International Trade Organization (ITO), GATT put into place a system of
international trade law based on two principles. These
principles--most-favored nation (MFN) and reciprocity--had in various
guises been at the root of most international commercial agreements
since the mid-nineteenth century and had been utilized to great effect
by the principal commercial powers.
GATT also set out to regulate a relatively small segment of
commercial activity--trade in goods. Early on into its history, this
commercial remit was constrained further. By the early to mid-1950s, the
growing competitiveness of newly independent and other developing states
in agriculture and in textiles and clothing saw GATT's original
contracting parties seek to exclude these areas from the liberalization process.
The consequences of these early developments continue to have
important ramifications for the trade regime. First, international trade
regulation was established around a set of economic and legal principles
that its founding members were familiar with and had often utilized.
Second, the arena of commercial regulation was kept artificially small.
Agricultural and textile and clothing producers in the industrial states
were protected from the growing competitiveness of developing and new
independent producers. Nevertheless, producers in industrial states were
able to benefit from negotiated reductions in barriers to trade in
manufactured, semimanufactured, and both low- and high-technology goods.
The result was to build into GATT's evolutionary trajectory
"first mover advantages." (2)
Efforts to redress these imbalances were few and far between and
lacking in substance. Part IV of GATT, introduced in 1966, was
lackluster; and the special and differential provisions that were
introduced thereafter were too little to be of significant economic
benefit. But there were other problems. The relative lack of export
earnings, coupled with fierce competition in emerging sectors,
prohibited developing states from diversifying their economies. Instead,
they remained largely dependent on the production of raw materials,
agriculture, and textiles and clothing and benefited only from the
limited preferential treatment offered by GATT and other international
agreements.
By the time GATT entered its eighth and final round of
negotiations, the Uruguay Round, it had become clear that the General
Agreement could no longer maintain its current form. Pressures, on the
one hand, to extend further the remit of international trade regulation
and, on the other hand, to reverse the exclusion of agriculture and
textiles and clothing, as well as extend special and differential
treatment, resulted in the creation of a much larger legal framework and
the establishment of an organization--the WTO--charged with its
administration. The inclusion of agreements on agriculture and textiles
and clothing came as part of a bargain that also included the
introduction of rules on services, on trade-related investment measures
(TRIMs), and on trade-related intellectual property rights (TRIPS). Two
aspects of this bargain are notable: each of the new agreements
conformed to the now standard GATT model wherein most-favored nation and
reciprocity form the core principles; and the substance of agreements on
services, intellectual property, and investment measures reflected a
negotiated outcome of the legal rules, norms, and customs in place in
the leading industrial states.
However, Uruguay was not a panacea. While the inclusion of
agriculture and textiles and clothing rectified an existing imbalance,
the introduction of new rules in services, intellectual property, and
investment measures extended the trade agenda further. Not only were the
industrial states better suited to taking advantage of these new rules,
but their ability to utilize the market opportunities those rules
presented enabled them to develop a competitive advantage over future
market entrants. The creation of the WTO had brought with it a new set
of first-mover advantages.
By the time the WTO met to convene its Third Ministerial Meeting in
Seattle, significant tensions had begun to emerge. Industrial members,
particularly the United States and the EU, had dug in their heels to
forestall any unraveling of their elaborate agricultural subsidy systems
and to prevent the opening of markets in this area. Significant problems
had emerged with the implementation of Uruguay Round commitments.
Pressure was growing from the United States and the EU to further extend
the remit of WTO rules (to include the four Singapore issues) and to
launch a new round, dubbed the Millennium Round. Moreover, much
consternation emerged over persistent calls by the United States and the
EU to explore the possibility of a linkage between trade and labor
standards within the WTO and to expand the participation of civil
society organizations. Set against the backdrop of a run-up to a U.S.
presidential election and disruptions caused by mass demonstrations, the
meeting collapsed.
The next stop on the WTO road trip was Doha, in November 2001. The
tensions that had emerged in Seattle prompted a change in the way
supporters of a new trade round marketed their aim. The round was to be
"development-centered." Even so, in the run-up to the meeting
it was unclear whether the ministerial conference would give its support
to a new set of negotiations. However, the events of September 11, just
two months before the meeting, cast a different light on the meeting.
Few states wished to be seen to be offering opposition in such a tender
political climate. The result was the launch of the Doha Development
Agenda (DDA).
From the point of view of the developing states, agreeing to the
DDA was a fundamental error. It firmly married a commitment to revisit
the Uruguay Round agreements with a movement forward in four new areas
(the Singapore issues) and possibly a fifth (e-commerce). Moreover, the
DDA put in place a specific time frame: negotiations would commence on
the Singapore issues, subject to minor clarification, after the midterm review of negotiations in Cancun. The broad-based consent that
under-pinned the DDA ensures that any movement forward on those issues
of concern to the South will automatically trigger pressure for a
movement forward on those important to the North.
The consequences of adding a further layer to the WTO's
existing legal framework should the DDA be concluded are significant. On
the other hand, many developing states will consolidate their production
of agricultural produce, textiles and clothing, and some low-technology
goods at a rate of profitability directly related to the rate at which
agricultural subsidies and tariff barriers are wound down in the United
States, the EU, and Japan, among others. Little industrial
diversification will occur among the poorest or smallest economies,
because the costs of moving away from established industries and
investing in new sectors will be prohibitive. This is irrespective of any massive increase in technical and other assistance. After all, it
does not make good business sense to enable competitors to develop
comparative advantages in sectors in which one is competitive. The
leading industrial states will nevertheless be able to benefit from any
WTO movement into the new areas. Not only are these new areas already of
key importance to many industrial states, and insignificant to many of
their developing counterparts, the consequence of their utilization will
be to put in place yet more first-mover advantages. The result will be a
reinforcement of the comparative advantages of industrial states in a
wide variety of economic areas.
As a final point, the greater the number of sectors in which an
economy has, at a minimum, developed a presence or, at most, established
something of a comparative advantage, the better able that economy is to
weather periods of economic downturn. While the onset of recession may
hurt industrial states, the pain will be exponentially greater in their
developing counterparts, with the most vulnerable populations suffering
the worst. The real problem, should a political settlement be agreed
post-Cancun, is that the vulnerability of developing states is likely to
be exacerbated. The only way forward both to address this potential
danger and to remove some of the inertia plaguing the WTO is to put in
place a moratorium on negotiations in these new areas at least until
after the conclusion of the current round and concentrate instead on
addressing the development dimension of the DDA. The problem for the
United States, the EU, and the remainder of the industrial world, of
course, is that to do so would be politically damaging. But for the most
vulnerable, maintaining the present course brings with it greater risks.
Notes
Rorden Wilkinson is senior lecturer at the University of Manchester and visiting associate professor at both Brown University and Wellesley
College. He is also coeditor of the Global Institutions Series of books
forthcoming from Routledge. The author attended the Cancun ministerial
meeting as a representative of the Academic Council on the United
Nations System (ACUNS). He gratefully acknowledges the financial
assistance of the British Academy.
1. J. Michael Finger, "That Old GATT Magic No More Casts Its
Spell (How the Uruguay Round Failed)," Journal of World Trade 25,
no. 1 (February 1991): 39-53.
2. Robert O. Keohane, Power and Governance in a Partially
Globalized World (London: Routledge, 2002), p. 253.