Remodeling the Multilateral Financial Institutions.
Bird, Graham ; Joyce, Joseph P.
Since the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank were
first established in 1946, the world economy has changed in a number of
important ways. [1] Not only have the volume, composition, and pattern
of world trade changed, but capital flows have come to dominate the
global balance of payments, as has been underlined by the financial
crises of the 1990s (Europe in 1992-1993, Mexico in 1994-1995, and East
Asia in 1997-1998).
At the same time, the roles originally envisaged for the
multilateral financial institutions have also changed. The IMF no longer
oversees an adjustable peg exchange rate regime through which it
effectively sought to coordinate macroeconomic policy globally, nor does
it attempt to control the quantity of international reserves. Instead,
it has taken on a new role in clearing up the debris from financial
crises involving developing countries and countries in transition--a
role for which it was not originally designed.
Meanwhile, the World Bank, which was established to fill the
financing gaps left by private capital markets, has over the years found
that in many instances these gaps are fewer than they used to be because
private capital flows have increased; the Bank has therefore tended
toward supporting softer areas of investment where it is still difficult
to raise private money, and focusing, via its International Development
Association, on the poorest developing countries.
The response of the multilaterals to a changing world economy has
been to evolve in an incremental fashion rather than to embark upon
fundamental reform. The reasons for this are easy to see. First, the
problems that the world encountered up until the mid-1990s were not
sufficiently pronounced or universal to warrant fundamental reform. In
many respects, the world continued to perform satisfactorily in terms of
conventional macroeconomic indicators. Second, crises, when they did
occur, seemed to be temporary rather than prolonged, and primarily
regional rather than global. Third, political economy considerations
made piecemeal reform much easier to bring about, since not all members
of the global community agreed on the need for fundamental reform or on
what shape it should take. [2]
However, incrementalism has its dangers. Changes that may make
sense when taken individually may make less sense when taken together.
The whole may end up being less than the sum of the parts. The
multilaterals may have modified and, in some respects, extended their
activities by means of a series of relatively small steps that perhaps
would have appeared unacceptable if taken in one big step. On top of
this, there is the question of whether the individual steps have all
been in the same direction or whether we have been moving three steps
forward and two (or even four) steps back!
The East Asian financial crisis brought about a sea change, or so
it seemed. First, following hard on the heels of the Mexican
peso.crisis, and in turn being followed by the Russian and Brazilian
crises, the question became, "At what point do crises become a
global phenomenon?" Certainly, according to some observers, the
crises represented a crisis of global capitalism. [3] Second, the East
Asian crisis contained strong elements and even stronger threats of
contagion, such that advanced economies worried that they would not
escape the recessionary spillover effects. In these circumstances, calls
for more fundamental reform rapidly started to appear on the global
policy agenda. The Group of 7 (G-7) countries, for example, began to
talk about a "new international financial architecture," with
this phrase suggesting a broader and deeper perspective than had existed
before. [4]
But, although this is an interesting catchphrase, what does "a
new international financial architecture" mean, exactly? Broad
phrases are frequently difficult to define precisely and the new
international financial architecture is no exception. While it
incorporates the dissemination of more information on policies and
performance and increased recognition that the volatility of
international capital flows needs to be addressed, these changes may be
seen as merely a continuation of the previous evolutionary trend. The
establishment of new lending windows in the IMF may be presented in a
similar light. Moreover, strengthening IMF conditionality does not
really sound like new architecture. Indeed, one of the least precise
aspects of many of the new architecture proposals relates to the roles
of the multilateral financing institutions in general and the role of
the IMF in particular. When does tinkering with the existing
international financial system become fundamental reform? Not simply by
dint of being calle d a move toward a new international financial
architecture.
This article, at least initially, tries to break away from ad hoc incrementalism. Instead, it adopts a zero-based approach to consider how
the IMF should be reformed. By examining the deficiencies of private
capital markets and analyzing how they might be rectified, we can design
institutions to accomplish this aim and establish the best route for
getting from where we are now to where we want to be. While a complete
teardown and reconstruction may not be feasible, a blueprint can serve
to guide future incremental reforms and ensure that changes are mutually
reinforcing and consistent. Establishing an overall design seems to be
what a new international financial architecture should be all about, but
this seems to be precisely what is missing in much of the current
"architecture debate."
In the second section of the article, we examine the deficiencies
of private capital markets that in an important sense delineate a role
for the multilateral financial institutions. Having discussed in general
terms what this role should be, we go on in the third section to assess
the institutions that we have (the IMF and the World Bank) and endeavor
to isolate a number of areas where the existing institutions fall short.
In addition, the experience of these institutions and their program
countries allows a number of lessons to be learned. These need to be
factored into the reform process. In the fourth section, we are more
specific about ways in which the IMF and World Bank should be remodeled.
And in conclusion, we offer some remarks about the political economy of
the reform process and contrast our ideas about reform with some other
proposals for reform that have been made.
What's Wrong with Private Capital Markets?
As a way of dealing with the need for short-term
balance-of-payments finance and long-term development finance, there is
a lot that is right with private capital markets. They mobilize huge
amounts of finance and generally show an ability to adapt quickly to
market opportunities by devising new instruments. While official,
long-term resource flows to developing countries shrank during the
1990s, private flows grew from approximately $44 billion to over $200
billion (see Table 1). There can be little doubt that private capital
markets have made a massive positive contribution to world economic
welfare by intermediating globally between savers and spenders and by
relieving financial constraints.
However, there is a downside, and in analytical terms it is a
fairly conventional one. Reliance on markets in any situation opens up
the possibility of "market failure." The principal sources of
market failure include concentration among producers (monopoly,
oligopoly), negative and positive externalities, the nonproduction of
public goods, the overproduction of "bads" (such as addictive
drugs), inadequate coordination, informational deficiencies,
instability, and inequality. Some of these failures, as well as others,
can be shown to appear in the context of private capital markets. [5]
First, private markets will generally find it unattractive to lend
to low-income countries when the lenders make decisions with a
short-term horizon or the countries have not established a record of
borrowing. Either because of their lack of resources or because of
economic mismanagement of one sort or another, the poorest countries of
the world lack creditworthiness. In one sense this may create an
incentive for their governments to improve economic policies, but the
world community has generally responded to this financing gap by
providing foreign aid either bilaterally or via multilateral agencies,
in particular the World Bank.
Second, lending decisions made by private lenders seeking a
risk-adjusted commercial rate of return may be inappropriate where they
are made with inaccurate or partial information. Because of asymmetric
information, markets will never know for sure what the policy intentions
of governments are. Moreover, it may be very expensive or simply not
feasible for individual market operators to collect and interpret all
the economic data that they might ideally wish to have before making
lending and investment decisions. In any case, if they were to collect
it individually, this would represent a tremendous waste of resources.
Working on partial information, however, there are dangers of adverse
selection. Should markets, for example, ration their lending exclusively
on the basis of the rate of interest that borrowers are prepared to pay?
Perhaps a willingness to sign loan contracts with relatively high
interest rates is an indicator of a government's willingness to
default. How do markets then assess the risks of re pudiation when
information is partial? Although they will have mechanisms for assessing
country risk, experience shows that these are far from perfect.
Imagine that borrowing countries do encounter problems in meeting
their outstanding debt obligations. How will markets respond?
Individually, the best outcome for any single creditor is that all other
creditors grant the borrower debt relief, thus ensuring that the
borrower is able to meet its full obligations to the remaining creditor.
But if all creditors pursue this strategy, no relief will be given and
everyone will end up worse off. In this situation, debt relief may be
Pareto-improving. But, at the same time, it is unlikely to be adopted by
markets because each creditor will ideally prefer to get a free ride on
the back of the debt relief provided by others. In principle, this
free-rider problem may be overcome by coordination, but who within the
context of private capital markets carries the responsibility for
providing this function?
Similarly, in the midst of a financial crisis, where a borrowing
country is experiencing extreme illiquidity, the incentive for each
individual creditor will be to withdraw funds as quickly as possible.
However, if all creditors do this, it will merely exacerbate illiquidity
and make it more likely that everyone--creditors and debtors alike--will
lose. The conventional analogy is with a fire in a building. An
organized evacuation is likely to save more lives than a disorganized stampede by individuals in a state of panic. But who is responsible for
organizing fire drills, identifying emergency exits, and so on? This is,
in essence, a public good that will not be provided by individuals in
isolation. Again, there is a coordination failure.
Financial crises flamed by investor panics may also have spillover
and contagion effects, which individual creditors do not take into
account when making their decisions. There can then be a domino pattern.
In part, contagion may be an economic phenomenon, because recession,
interest rate hikes, and currency depreciation in one country adversely
affect export performance and the overall balance of payments elsewhere.
But there may also be an important psychological or bandwagon effect as
the predominant market sentiment changes. In other words, there will be
externalities that are not internalized into the decisions made by
private capital markets. Individual market operators will not see it as
part of their role to deal with systemic risk, of which contagion is a
part.
Even in dealing with individual country risk, private markets will
be largely unable to enact measures that reduce risk other than by their
own portfolio diversification. What measures might there be? An
important risk-reducing mechanism is conditionality, by which loans are
made contingent on a borrowing government pursuing an agreed range of
economic policies designed to strengthen economic performance. Why will
private markets find conditionality difficult to organize? First, and
yet again, conditionality has to be a coordinated activity. Clearly,
individual creditors cannot negotiate separate and possibly mutually
inconsistent conditions. Apart from anything else, the transactions
costs would, in all likelihood, be prohibitively high. Second,
individual creditors have neither the information nor the expertise to
devise appropriate conditions. They would have to start at the bottom of
what would be a steep learning curve. Third, given the relatively poor
data that creditors are likely to have, it would be difficult for them
to monitor progress. Fourth, it would be equally difficult for private
markets to enforce conditions and ensure that appropriate penalties were
applied where countries lapsed.
Experience confirms the above. On the only occasion that private
banks endeavored to put together a loan based on their own
conditionality, they ended up saying never again. Creditors complained
of at least as many problems dealing with each other as they did dealing
with the borrowing government. [6]
In addition to the systemic risk discussed earlier, there will be
systemic issues that lie outside the sphere of private capital markets
on which decisions need to be made. These relate to the generalized
exchange rate regime, international macroeconomic policy coordination,
and the regulation of both domestic and international financial systems.
What would be the implications of leaving these various
deficiencies of private capital markets unattended? In short, global
economic welfare would be lower than it need be. Capital would be
inefficiently allocated throughout the world. Capital movements would
tend to be unstable and volatile, and there would be a high incidence of
balance-of-payments crises. Governments might be effectively forced to
pursue excessively strict deflationary (counterinflationary) policies in
an attempt to impress private capital markets, so that while private
capital markets might relax financing constraints in one way, they might
impose an additional constraint in another. Because there would, in any
event, be a high degree of contagion of financial crises, some
governments would lose the ability to pursue macroeconomic policies
based on domestic needs. Poor countries would find themselves starved of
external finance, and living standards for many millions of people would
therefore be adversely affected.
How can the deficiencies of private capital markets be overcome
while retaining their undoubted advantages? To some extent, bilateral
aid may help by providing external finance to low-income countries. But
bilateral aid donors might be little better than private markets in
collecting and interpreting data and in organizing conditionality.
The Role of Multilateral Financial Institutions
If there is a conventional list of market failures, there is also a
conventional way of trying to deal with them. Market failure provides an
analytical justification for government intervention, and domestic
governments regulate domestic financial markets. But we do not have a
global government. An alternative therefore has to be found in dealing
with the failures of private capital markets, and this is where
multilateral financial institutions fit in.
But just as markets may fail in certain ways, so too may
governments. There are government failures, and costs associated with
policy interventions, that need to be considered. These include poor
information and slow decision and implementation processes. Partly as a
consequence, there may be gaps between what policymaking governments
intend and what actually happens. People may, for example, second-guess
what policies governments will pursue and adjust their own behavior in
such a way that the policies are no longer effective (the Lucas
critique). Government intervention may encourage rent-seeking behavior,
which wastes resources, and there may be little incentive for the public
sector to be efficient (a common justification for privatization).
Finally, governments are run by politicians and bureaucrats who,
according to public choice theory, are likely to be self-serving. [7]
Pursuing their own interests is unlikely to result in maximizing some
social welfare function. In order to minimize these problems,
governments need to be open, accountable, and democratic.
In designing multilateral financial institutions, it is therefore
as important to bear in mind possible sources of government failure as
it is to seek to overcome the sources of market failure. From the above
analysis, the comparative advantage of multilateral financial
institutions is likely to be in the areas of collecting information and
interpreting it, negotiating policy conditionality, internalizing global
externalities, coordinating behavior to offset free riding, dealing with
systemic risk and other systemic issues, and providing finance (in
appropriate circumstances) to countries that are shunned by private
capital markets. However, they also need to ensure that their
interventions are effective and efficient and that their organizational
structures enable them to avoid the public choice critique. As part of
this they need to discipline any bureaucratic tendency to grow in size
and in sphere of activity. As a general guideline, the multilaterals
should not seek to do things that private capital mark ets can do
better.
How Do the IMF and World Bank Score?
While this section accentuates the negative in order to focus on
areas where reform is necessary, this approach tends to misrepresent the
contribution of the multilaterals to global economic welfare. One of the
problems, however, is that it is difficult to measure their contribution
with any great precision. To look at the flows of finance that they have
provided and adjust these according to some "reasonable" rate
of return gives one indication. Anne Krueger carries out such an
exercise and concludes that World Bank lending alone has probably
contributed to economic growth in the countries receiving its support by
about .2 percent of GDP. [8] However, to the extent that the
multilaterals have also exerted a positive effect on the quality of
economic management via technical training and policy dialogue, their
contribution overall is almost certainly very significantly greater than
this.
Any cost-effectiveness study or cost-benefit study would, with
little doubt, show that the IMF and the World Bank have played a useful
and constructive role in the world economy. [9] This implies that
draconian proposals to close them down are misplaced. However, to say
that the multilaterals have played a constructive role is not to deny
that they might be able to do better. Where have they fallen short?
The IMF may be assessed in terms of its adjustment role, its
financing role, and its role in systemic management. As far as
adjustment is concerned, the principal modality through which it has
attempted to exercise this role has been conditionality. Incrementalism
has witnessed an expansion in conditionality. Over the years, low
conditionality finance (historically available via the Compensatory
Financing Facility) has been abandoned and the number of conditions
involved in Fund programs has increased. [10] Conditionality now covers
not only demand-side instruments such as fiscal policy, monetary policy,
and exchange rate policy, but often also detailed microeconomic and
supply-side policies. Does the expansion in Fund conditionality reflect
a track record of success that the Fund has been anxious to build upon?
No; in many respects conditionality has become less effective, with the
majority of Fund programs remaining incomplete." But why might
governments fail to implement Fund programs? Clearly, there can be a
range of reasons, including external shocks that blow programs off
course and overambition in design. However, the Fund tends to blame a
lack of commitment to reform by governments, although this is
oversimplistic because it fails to go on to analyze why governments may
be uncommitted and the complex political economy that underpins
implementation. [12]
Assuming for a moment that conditionality is appropriately designed
and identifies the right policies, it still appears to be a less than
effective means of ensuring that these policies are adopted. Much the
same can be said for World Bank conditionality in the context of
policy-based structural adjustment lending. [13]
But has conditionality been well designed? There are concerns that
by using conditionality, the multilaterals have encouraged governments
to pursue policies about which there is legitimate debate. [14] These
concerns cover the routine items of interest rate policy, fiscal policy,
and exchange rate policy, as well as specific measures of economic
liberalization and the speed and sequencing of liberalization in
general. If there are things in economics that we know and things that
we do not know, or at least are uncertain about, it may be sensible for
conditionality to concentrate on the former and downplay the latter,
allowing governments to retain more discretion in these areas. [15] This
would limit the scope of conditionality. Moreover, given the
uncertainties surrounding economic policy, it may be unjustifiable to be
too precise quantitatively. While, because of the difficulties alluded
to earlier, the multilaterals have a comparative advantage in
conditionality as compared with private markets, it is a m istake to
squander this by designing it in such a way as to make it relatively
ineffective.
There is another point here that links the multilaterals'
conditionality to private capital markets. In principle, conditionality
should have a catalytic effect on private flows by signaling that
governments are committed to economic policy reform. However, poor
implementation and the rather weak overall effects of conditionality on
economic performance undermine potential catalysis. Since countries turn
to the Fund only when they are in severe economic distress and have no
alternative source of finance, and since there are strong elements of
recidivism in borrowing from the IMF and the World Bank, a program with
the multilaterals may well be interpreted by the markets as an indicator
of economic difficulties ahead. The evidence on catalysis suggests that
overall the effect is weak, and in a sense this reflects the
markets' judgment on conditionality. [16]
Another thing that may get in the way of the multilaterals
maintaining a strong financial reputation is where their lending becomes
influenced by external factors, with some major shareholding countries
such as the United States putting pressure on the IMF and World Bank to
make loans in circumstances where they would otherwise have said no. If
multilateral lending is allowed to become affected by politics, its part
in overcoming the failures of markets will become constrained. Indeed,
it is possible that the failures will be magnified.
Turning to the Fund's financing role, how much lending should
it do? To take criticism to the extreme, an argument can be formulated
that the Fund has lent too little to the many and too much to the few.
In recent years there has been a large dispersion in the amount of funds
committed to various countries. A few large countries have accounted for
significant proportions of the total amount of IMF financing (see Table
2). What does this mean for the many smaller countries that divide up
the remaining funds? Low-income countries that form the majority of the
Fund's clients often encounter structural balance-of-payments
problems that are likely to take a lengthy period of time to correct.
Relatively slow adjustment implies relatively high financing in the
short term (although lower financing in the long term). But what if
external financing represents a binding constraint? Countries will have
to change their adjustment strategies and opt for the quicker
elimination of their current account balance-of-payments deficits.
However, rapid adjustment will imply adjustment based on deflating
domestic aggregate demand and, to the extent that the problems are
structural, demand deflation will fail to correct them.
Although deflating aggregate demand will tend to reduce the current
account deficit in the near term, the deficit will reemerge in the
longer run when deflationary policies lapse. Indeed, to the extent that
next period's aggregate supply is positively related to current
period aggregate demand, deflationary policies will make the long-run
situation worse. [17]
Inferior adjustment may therefore reflect inadequate financing.
There is some evidence to suggest that the success of IMF programs is
positively related to the amount of financing that is provided by them.
[18] Moreover, countries will be keen to escape Fund conditionality as
soon as possible, and this may help explain why so many programs break
down.
But what about the idea of lending too much to the few? By this is
implied the recent critique that the Fund has bailed out private capital
markets and thereby created a moral hazard problem, in the sense that
the prospect of bailouts encourages private markets to overlend. In a
similar vein, the argument was made during the 1980s that the presence
of the IMF and its unwillingness to lend to countries in arrears with
private banks served to discourage banks from offering debt relief--the
very relief required to provide a systemic solution to the debt crisis.
The Fund was sometimes portrayed as a debt collector for the banks.
The general point is that intervention by the multilaterals
designed to deal with a particular problem associated with private
capital markets, such as the volatility of private capital flows, may
itself have undesirable side effects. In both the 1980s debt crisis and
the East Asian crisis of 1997-1998, the solution is that the lending
role of the multilaterals may need to be replaced by an enhanced
coordinating role, with creditors being encouraged to share a larger
proportion of the burden. Coordination is the mechanism through which
private creditors can be prevented from attempting to secure a free
ride. Excessive lending by the multilaterals may therefore reflect
inadequate coordination.
What about systemic management? With the demise of the Bretton
Woods system, much of the scope for systemic management disappeared. The
world will not return to the 1950s and 1960s. To the extent that there
is a systemic role for the Fund to play, it is not therefore in terms of
managing a quasi-fixed exchange rate regime. Instead, it is in terms of
the coordination role described above, and in terms of collecting,
disseminating, and interpreting data and ensuring that countries comply
with financial regulatory requirements. Although it may not immediately
be apparent why the Fund needs to get involved in domestic banking
standards, there is evidence to suggest that currency crises, in which
the Fund has an unambiguous interest, often follow on domestic banking
crises. This implies that the Fund needs to take an interest in domestic
banking arrangements in its member countries just as much as it takes an
interest in their domestic macroeconomic policies. [19]
Much of what has been said could also apply to policy-based lending
by the World Bank. The Bank, however, focuses mainly on project lending,
which it finances by mobilizing international capital either by its own
direct borrowing, in which context it acts as a financial intermediary,
or by contributions in the case of its soft loan arm, the International
Development Association. The rationale for these activities again hangs
on informational failures (with the Bank having better information than
markets), monitoring and enforcement, public goods, and inequality.
Private capital markets may fail to support worthy projects for reasons
similar to those that mean domestic governments often have to take on
the responsibility for public/infrastructural investment, such as the
existence of public goods or the need for a longer time horizon to
evaluate the benefits of the project. The principal area of criticism of
the Bank tends to be in terms of whether it has defined this activity
sufficiently narrowly, or whethe r it has carried on financing projects
for which private capital would be directly available. To the extent
that low-income countries continue to encounter a gap between the
external finance they need for developmental projects and the finance
they can raise on private capital markets, there will be a role for a
multinational agency such as the World Bank.
The broad principle behind designing multilateral financial
institutions must be the idea of filling gaps or making good
deficiencies left by private provision but without creating additional
problems as a consequence of their intervention.
An alternative way of approaching the task is to group member
countries of the multilaterals into a range of classifications. Because
of their unimpaired access to private capital markets, advanced
countries are unlikely to need multilateral financial institutions.
Middle-income developing countries and countries in transition usually
have access to private capital markets but at other times may experience
impaired access. Here the multilaterals need to support these countries
and private capital markets--not in terms of providing a guaranteed and
costless safety net, but by endeavoring to ensure that private lending
decisions are well informed and that sound economic policies are
pursued. This may imply occasional lending by the multilaterals, but the
emphasis needs to be on helping to shift these economies across the
margin of creditworthiness.
Low-income countries, by contrast, face longer-term financing
problems, and here the lending role of the multilaterals is more
important on an ongoing basis, or at least until these countries
graduate into the category of better-off developing countries.
In both low- and middle-income developing countries, the
multilaterals need to see external financing as part of a package of
services they offer, with their adjustment input being an important part
of the package. However, multilaterals need to ensure, as best they can,
that they support appropriate policies and create an incentive for
countries to pursue them. This almost certainly implies a flexible
approach to conditionality.
To be effective, the multilaterals also need to carry the support
of the world community as a whole. While quota-weighted voting systems
may facilitate efficiency, the multilaterals need to avoid becoming
dominated by their more powerful shareholders. This may be difficult to
achieve if they rely heavily on subscriptions, reviewed by a political
process, to finance their activities.
In the next section, we go on to examine some more specific
proposals for remodeling the IMF and World Bank to comply with the
blueprint laid out above. Our conclusion is that these institutions do
not need to be rebuilt from scratch. Demolition is unnecessary.
Remodeling: Design Features
In terms of a new international financial architecture, the IMF
will continue to be the premier multilateral financial institution. The
role of the World Bank, however, should not be overlooked. It will
continue to be important as a source of development finance for
low-income countries. As far as its policy-based lending is concerned,
many of the comments made below about IMF conditionality could also be
applied to that of the Bank.
While some observers have seen reform of the Fund as a relatively
small component of the new international financial architecture, we
present it as much more central. After all, the very word architecture
suggests some overall plan, and it is unwise to assume that this will
somehow satisfactorily emerge from private capital markets. Taking the
design lead is precisely what the Fund should be doing. But what items
should be on the IMF remodeler's checklist?
First, and fundamental, is the reform of conditionality. The aim
should be for consensus and commitment. This will require more
flexibility than in the past. The Fund should adopt as light a touch as
possible and seek to minimize its interventions. There should be a
greater distinction between low- and high-conditionality lending,
reflecting the distinction between liquidity and solvency problems. The
Fund should also distinguish between balance-of-payments crises that are
the product of poor domestic macroeconomic management and those due to
volatile capital markets. Conditionality might be reformed to follow a
sliding scale; governments with a good track record of economic policy
and in possession of their own economic reform agenda might expect to
receive light conditionality, with this becoming heavier only in cases
where governments are reluctant to formulate their own programs or where
past promises have not been kept. The Fund in the future needs to work
harder to avoid the accusations of excessive an d misdirected
intervention, a classic source of "government failure," and
arrest and reverse the trend toward more conditionality.
Second, reforming conditionality would be an important element in
improving program implementation and success, which is a function of
"ownership." Countries would then be encouraged to turn to the
Fund earlier, when their economic situations were not so dire. At the
same time, slippage should be more heavily penalized. There should be
sticks as well as carrots. Countries that have failed to keep their
policy promises would find that it becomes harder to negotiate a new
program, not least because the degree of conditionality would be
greater. At this stage, the Fund would become more hands on than hands
off.
It is important, however, that the Fund recognize more fully that
economic growth may be a constraint on the balance of payments and not
simply constrained by the balance of payments. For low-income countries
this almost certainly means that the Fund needs to increase the amount
of finance it provides to such countries. This in turn would further
encourage countries to design and implement sensible programs of
economic reform. Moreover, given the absolute volume of finance
involved, it would not have a significant effect on the Fund's
resource position.
Of course, improving the track record of conditionality and
strengthening the commitment to economic reform would also have the
benefit of reinforcing the Fund's catalytic effect on other capital
flows, such that an increased proportion of the financing could be met
from private sources. Low-income countries could also be assisted by
means of a special allocation of special drawing rights (SDRs) to them,
an idea that has been around for some time. [20]
In the case of better-off developing countries and countries in
transition, the Fund needs to avoid, as far as possible, getting into
the situation where it is making large loans in crisis conditions. This
is what puts pressure on the Fund's resource base and threatens to
perpetrate a moral hazard problem. Even if it were to be politically
feasible, the Fund should resist invitations to develop in the direction
of becoming a formal international lender of last resort; it lacks many
of the characteristics of an international central bank and could become
exposed to moral hazard problems. It should attempt to play down its
crisis lending role and play up its crisis management role. The emphasis
should be on coordinating creditors at a time of crisis in a way that
ensures that they are unable to pass the cost of the crisis on to the
Fund. This will almost certainly impair the willingness of private
capital markets to lend, but currency crises often reflect excessive
lending in the past more than deficient lendi ng in the present. The
details of strengthening the Fund's coordinating role are complex
but not insurmountable.
In terms of dealing with capital volatility, the logic of proposals
that the Fund should collect and disseminate fuller amounts of data
almost goes without saying. To the extent that there are informational
failures of one sort or another, these need to be corrected. However,
more doubts exist about what should be expected from the Fund in terms
of interpreting data and drawing appropriate policy conclusions. Like
other institutions, the Fund's forecasting record has not always
been strong.
In the context of capital volatility, it is perhaps more important
that the Fund should not make countries liberalize their capital
accounts as part of conditionality. There are strong arguments that if
anything should be open, it should be the Fund's mind about capital
account liberalization. In order to help avoid their destabilizing
effects, many developing countries may need to retain the option of
imposing some sort of tax on capital movements. The Fund often likes to
see itself as a doctor diagnosing country illnesses and prescribing
appropriate medicines (which, of course, may be unpleasant to take). The
Fund also needs to recall that the doctor's first objective is to
do no harm. Premature capital account liberalization may harm developing
countries. [21]
While attempting to minimize its role as a crisis lender to
better-off developing countries, the Fund also needs to avoid becoming
itself resource constrained. The use of IMF credit has more than doubled
in the years 1994-1998 (see Table 3). It therefore needs to break away
from the system of periodic quota reviews by which its resource base is
increased at discrete moments in time. Instead, its resources need to be
determined with a higher degree of automaticity by, for example,
maintaining a ratio between Fund quotas and world trade within a
specified range. A formula could be devised that also endeavored to
capture the importance of the capital account in causing overall
balance-of-payments difficulties, which will remain the primary focus of
the Fund. An automatic formula-based approach would also overcome some
of the accusations that have been made against the Fund's
management--including, that it engages in hurry-up lending prior to a
quota review. [22] It would also serve to protect the Fund from dire ct
political influences over its lending capacity. More radical proposals
to use additional SDR allocations as a way of financing the Fund would,
however, probably encounter substantial resistance from the Fund's
principal shareholders, who may wish to keep the institution on a short
leash.
This may also rule out the option of the Fund following the lead of
the Bank and financing itself by borrowing directly from private capital
markets. However, in many ways this is an attractive option, because by
using this mechanism the Fund would be able to directly catalyze private
capital. [23] To private capital markets, lending to the Fund could be
an appealing complement to direct country lending since, while it might
offer a lower return, it would also carry less risk. In this way the
Fund would be able to offer a safety net to private capital markets. The
Fund would, of course, need to continue to receive subscriptions and
other contributions to finance its concessionary activities. Where the
Fund's major shareholders insist on the short-leash approach,
however, the task is to ensure that the leash is not so short as to
cause strangulation.
Insulating Fund decisions from political considerations represents
a substantial challenge, since it is in many ways a fundamentally
political institution. But its remodeling needs to take into account
that it will lose an important part of its financial reputation if its
decisions become too heavily influenced by the political preferences of
its major shareholders. This is a case for allowing the Fund's own
staff more executive discretion. But then, who checks up on them? The
Fund often comes over as a rather closed, opaque, and self-defensive
institution. If Fund staff is to be granted more decisionmaking power,
this has to be accompanied by greater openness and accountability.
Either the Fund has to become more self-critical or expose itself
formally to the criticisms of others. [24] At the same time,
depoliticizing the Fund should not exclude the borrowing countries from
the sense of partnership with the Fund, which they require if they are
to undertake fundamental policy reforms.
The final "design feature" strongly follows on from a
zero-based strategy. The Fund now possesses a mind-boggling array of
lending facilities, including standbys and the Extended Fund Facility
(EFF), the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PROF), formerly known
as the Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility (ESAF), the Compensatory
Financing Facility (CFF), and the Supplemental Reserve Facility (SRF).
The Fund's response to the East Asian crisis was to add to this an
extra swift disbursement window. There is considerable scope for
rationalizing this range of lending facilities and concentrating on
maybe two that emphasize the analytical distinctions that were made
earlier. [25] One could involve short-term loans where the principal
problem is a lack of liquidity. The second could be longer term and
would deal with problems of insolvency and structural adjustment. The
degree of concessionality could be determined by the per capita income of the borrowing country. To some extent, this would be a matter of r
egularizing the current situation, since in reality some of the
Fund's existing lending windows are little used. There is little
chance that if the Fund were being built from scratch it would be
designed with as many windows as it currently has.
Conclusion
The East Asian financial crisis has led to claims that a new
international architecture is needed. But what does this mean? Most
accounts of it are rather imprecise. It is usually seen as involving
only limited reforms to the IMF, the world's premier international
financial institution. The accent, where reform to the Fund is
envisaged, is placed on either expanding its role in providing
information and in "strengthening" conditionality or
abandoning conditionality altogether in favor of preconditions. The Fund
itself has favored increasing its jurisdiction to cover capital account
liberalization, while others have suggested an increased supervisory
role as important, particularly in terms of domestic financial systems.
To us, some of these ideas are good and largely uncontroversial,
although perhaps of more limited benefit than is sometimes assumed;
others, however, are bad and potentially damaging.
In any case, our view is that the Fund is central to the concept of
a new international financial architecture and therefore requires much
closer fundamental examination. The Fund should be designed to make good
the deficiencies of private capital markets, while bearing in mind the
potential dangers of intervention. Following on from this analytical
approach is a "job specification" that delineates a clear role
for the Fund. Reform of the Fund should cover its adjustment role, its
financing role, and its role in systemic management. At the same time,
the World Bank needs to adopt a similar orientation in dealing with the
deficiencies of private capital markets.
Is this a task that can be achieved? It can if there is sufficient
political will. Failure to agree on and implement a program of reform
will indeed, in this case, reflect a lack of political will (irony
intended). In previous years, and even at the time of the fiftieth
anniversary of the Bretton Woods institutions, there was little
enthusiasm for fundamental reform. But the severity of the East Asian
crisis along with its contagion effects may have created a global
environment that is conducive to reform. The hope is that political
leaders grasp the opportunity to undertake the necessary institutional
remodeling and refurbishment. The worry is that as the global economy
recovers and memories of the crisis fade (until the next one), the
temptation will be to settle for marginal incremental reform. As a
consequence, the reality will lag behind the rhetoric and the new
international financial architecture will end up becoming just another
empty phrase.
Notes
Graham Bird is professor of economics at the University of Surrey and director of the Surrey Centre for International Economic Studies. He
is the author of IMF Lending to Developing Countries (1995). Joseph P.
Joyce is professor of economics at Wellesley College.
(1.) See Harold James, international Monetary Cooperation Since
Bretton Woods (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996), for a history
of the international monetary system; and A. F. P. Bakker, International
Financial Institutions (London: Addison Wesley, 1996), for a survey of
multilateral financial institutions.
(2.) For a more detailed and structured discussion of the
circumstances under which fundamental reform to the international
monetary system may and may not take place, see Graham Bird, "From
Bretton Woods to Halifax and Beyond: The Political Economy of
International Monetary Reform," World Economy 19, no. 2 (1996):
149-172.
(3.) For example, Jeffrey Sachs, in The Economist (12 September
1998), writes about the shortcomings of global capitalism and the
reforms necessary to make it work better.
(4.) Barry Eichengreen discusses many of the proposals that have
been offered in the wake of the Asian crisis to reform the international
financial institutions in Toward a New International Financial
Architecture (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics,
1999).
(5.) The benefits and risks of international capital flows are
examined in IMF Occasional Paper No. 172, Capital Account
Liberalization: Theoretical and Practical Aspects (Washington, D.C.:
IMF, 1998).
(6.) The experiences of commercial lenders in trying to organize
their own conditionality in the case of Peru in 1976 are nicely
summarized in Dani Rodrik, "Why Is There Multilateral
Lending?" in Michael Bruno and Boris Pleskovic, eds., Annual World
Bank Conference on Development Economics 1995 (Washington, D.C.:
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1996), pp.
167-193.
(7.) See, for example, Roland Vaubel's use of the public
choice approach in "The Political Economy of the International
Monetary Fund: A Public Choice Analysis," in Roland Vaubel and
Thomas D. Wilett, eds., The Political Economy of International
Organizations (Boulder: Westview, 1991), pp. 204-244.
(8.) Anne O. Krueger, "Whither the World Bank and the
IMF?" Journal of Economic Literature 36, no. 4 (1998): 2016.
Krueger derives this estimate for Bank lending to areas outside of
Africa.
(9.) Mohsin Khan summarizes the evidence on the impact of
Fund-supported adjustment programs in "The Macroeconomic Effects of
Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs," IMF Staff Papers 37, no. 2
(1990): 195-231; "Do IMF-Supported Programs Work? A Survey of the
Cross-Country Empirical Evidence," with Nadeem Ul Haque, IMF
Working Paper No. 98/169, 1998.
(10.) The increase in conditionality is explained in Jacques J.
Polak, "The Changing Nature of IMF Conditionality," Essays in
International Finance, No. 184, Princeton University, 1991.
(11.) Tony Killick, Moazzam Malik, and Marcus Manuel examine the
reasons for noncompletion of IMF programs in "What Can We Know
About the Effects of IMF Programmes?" World Economy 15, no. 5
(1992): 575-597.
(12.) Graham Bird analyzes the political economy of policy reform
in "The Effectiveness of Conditionality and the Political Economy
of Policy Reform: Is It Simply a Matter of Political Will?" Policy
Reform 1, no. 1 (1998): 89-113.
(13.) An excellent analysis of policy-based lending by the World
Bank is provided by Paul Mosley, Jane Harrigan, and John Toye in their
Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending (London:
Routledge, 1998).
(14.) For an analysis of IMF programs, see Tony Killick, IMF
Programmes in Developing Countries: Design and Impact (London:
Routledge, 1995).
(15.) For a fuller discussion of this general theme, see Graham
Bird, "How Important Is Sound Domestic Macroeconomics in Attracting
Capital Inflows to Developing Countries?" Journal of International
Development 11, no. 1 (1999): 1-26.
(16.) Graham Bird and Dane Rowlands, investigating whether
involvement with multilateral institutions has a positive catalytic
effect for a country, find evidence for such an effect only in the case
of official lending. See Bird and Rowlands, "The Catalytic Effect
of Lending by the International Financial Institutions," World
Economy 20, no. 7 (1997): 917-991.
(17.) For a more detailed discussion of these ideas, with
supporting evidence, see Graham Bird, "External Financing and
Balance of Payments Adjustment in Developing Countries: Getting a Better
Policy Mix," World Development 25, no. 9 (1997): 1409-1420.
(18.) See Killick, IMF Programmes in Developing Countries, for
evidence on this issue.
(19.) See, for example, Jeffrey D. Sachs, Aaron Tornell, and Andres
Velasco, "Financial Crises in Emerging Markets: The Lessons from
1995," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1 (1996):
147-198; and Graciela L. Kaminsky and Carmen Reinhart, "The Twin
Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,"
American Economic Review 89, no. 3 (1999): 473-501. Barry Eichengreen,
Toward a New International Financial Architecture, provides further
jutification for this point of view.
(20.) For recent examination of this idea, see Graham Bird,
"Economic Assistance to Low Income Countries: Should the Link Be
Resurrected?" Essays in International Finance, No. 193, Princeton
University, 1994.
(21.) For a brief analysis of capital account liberalization, see
Graham Bird, "Convertibility and Volatility: The Pros and Cons of
Liberalizing the Capital Account," Economic Notes 27, no. 2 (1998):
141-156.
(22.) See Roland Vaubel, "The Moral Hazard of IMF
Lending," World Economy 6, no. 3 (1983): 291-303.
(23.) Adam Lerrick presents the case for IMF borrowing from the
private sector in Private Sector Financing for the IMF: Now Part of an
Optimal Funding Mix (Washington, D.C.: Bretton Woods Committee, 1999).
(24.) The Fund has moved to greater use of external evaluators.
See, for example, External Evaluation of the ESAF (Washington, D.C.:
IMF, 1998).
(25.) U.S. treasury secretary Larry Summers recently advanced his
own proposal for reforming the IMF, which included a reduction in the
number of the Fund's lending facilities (The Economist, 18 December
1999), p. 123.
Net Long-Term Resource Flows to Developing Countries, 1990-1998
(U.S.$ in billions)
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 [a]
Official flows 56.9 62.6 54.0 53.3 45.5 53.4 32.2 39.1 47.9
Private flows 43.9 60.5 98.3 167.0 178.1 201.5 275.9 299.0 227.1
Source: World Bank, Global Development and Finance. Analysis and
Summary Tables (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1999), p. 24.
Note: a. Signifies provisional.
Major Borrowers from IMF
Total Program Program Commitment
Commitment as % of All
Year Country (U.S.$ in billions) Commitments in Year
1995 Mexico 17.8 53
1996 Russia 10.1 58
1997 South Korea 21.0 53
Source: IMF, Annual Reports.
Total Use of IMF Credit
(U.S.$ in millions)
Year Credit
1994 44,144
1995 61,101
1996 60,106
1997 70,798
1998 95,459
Source: World Bank, Global Development and
Finance: Country Tables (Washington, D.C.:
World Bank, 1999), p. 14.