Institute on California and the West Railroaded Workshop, Huntington Library, San Marino, CA, July 9, 2011: Railroaded, or just railroading? The mundane madness of management.
Usselman, Steven W.
Madness! Madness!" These are the words uttered by Major
Clipton at the conclusion of David Lean's 1957 epic film, The
Bridge on the River Kwai. Clipton, a British medical officer, has just
watched a Japanese supply train plunge spectacularly from a mangled
railroad bridge to the river below. Moments before, the delirious Colonel Nicholson has managed to blow up the bridge, which he and his
imprisoned troops have spent most of the movie erecting. Nicholson, a
fastidious professional officer, has envisioned the construction project
as a way to sustain morale among his troops while also demonstrating
British fortitude and thus humbling their captors. Belatedly, he has
grasped how the bridge will also serve the purposes of that enemy--a
point Clipton had tried gently to impress upon him as the work
progressed. Now all is dust, and mud, and waste. Madness!
Clipton's summary comment springs to mind as I reflect upon
Richard White's epic new history of the western transcontinental
railroads. Perhaps it is the book's grand cinematic quality. As
history, it harkens back to those star-studded, widescreen productions
of the fifties and early sixties, as filmmakers tried desperately to
lure their wayward audience back from television. Remember How the West
Was Won? (White's version is more like the antidote, How the West
Was Lost.) Here one of our greatest academic historians, a master of
small gems such as The Organic Machine, paints on a truly broad canvas.
Filled with famous men engaged in grand escapades, his book might well
sit comfortably alongside those we expect to find on the front tables of
our national bookstores. You know the ones. Only this book, like
Lean's film in its day, has a decidedly darker cast than most of
its companions. Courage undaunted? Hardly. For White's voice, like
Clipton's, is that of the chorus reflecting on a Greek tragedy. If
the film were a Western--perhaps the more appropriate cinematic analogy
for today's event--White would be the old fellow perched on the
bunkhouse steps or serving up grub to the trail hands, shaking his head
and spitting dismissively into the dirt as the action swirled around
him. Darned foolishness!
HOW DO THINGS MANAGE TO GET DONE?
At its heart, White's book poses the same question that
fascinated Lean: How do things manage to get done, and to work, amidst
such foolishness? How can a material world get built, function, and
endure, when its governing apparatus appears so infused with madness?
For Lean, of course, the source of that madness was war and the ethos of
the officers trained to conduct it. For White, the absurdity resides not
so much in war (though the western railroads that fascinate him might,
in fact, be seen as products of war), but rather in corporate finance
and its attendant politics. Above all, in finance--a world characterized
by White as so filled with chicanery, duplicity, and shenanigans as to
border on madness. Or maybe cross the border. "Money," writes
White in discussing finance of the western cattle trade, "was a
wonderful mask for madness." (476)
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The question White poses is a serious one. It crosses my mind
regularly, in both my private and professional capacities. I begin most
of my days by reading my morning newspaper, the Atlanta
Journal-Constitution, which often leaves me shaking my head at the
latest nonsense perpetrated by my local and state politicians. (Some of
these occasionally make their way into the Times of Los Angeles and New
York.) Then I get into my car for the short drive to work and about
halfway to campus, as I rise up on one of those high-arching flyovers
and see much of the city arrayed before me, I often marvel to myself,
"But it's still there, and working." Or, in a variant
perhaps more to the point, "Well, the bridge hasn't
fallen--yet." It's a wonder, but things do carry on. How?
When I arrive at campus and put on my hat as a historian of
technology, such questions hardly disappear. For in many respects, the
mystery White ponders in Railroaded (and I am indulging on my drive to
work) touches the most basic concern of my field. How do things take
shape? What forces bring our structures and machines and the routines
that govern them to life? And what sustains them? In this sense, I read
White's book as a fundamental contribution to the history of
technology. In posing the questions he does about how finance and
politics and the exaggerated publicity that pervades those realms
pertain to the obvious and inescapable material import of the
railroad--and in suggesting how railroads are at once artifacts of the
imagination as well as of iron and steel--White is addressing central
themes in the history of technology. Indeed, these are the same
questions that occupied me in my studies of railroads located to the
east of the transcontinentals. Regulating railroad technology, I
concluded, was no easy task. (1)
White draws a pretty sharp line between "my" railroads
and his, and there are certainly some good reasons for him to do so.
Lines in the East were not generally built "ahead of demand,"
as White believes the transcontinentals were. Most received little
direct federal aid and drew their support primarily from enterprises in
the territories they served. The regular flow of local traffic enabled
roads such as the Pennsylvania to develop routines that imparted a more
machine-line character to their enterprises and made them a training
ground for ordered management, as business historian Alfred Chandler
famously described. (2) I'm not sure whether White actually
believes this of the eastern roads, or whether he accepts
Chandler's portrayal in order to accentuate the distinctive
characteristics he sees of railroads in the West. My own view of the
matter is that eastern roads were less ordered than Chandler portrayed
them, while those in the West were not nearly so chaotic or ill-guided
as White suggests. To evoke one of White's many witticisms,
Chandler coexisted with Dilbert, in both parts of the country.
Like most attempts at humor, this comment has an edge. It gets to
the heart of what I must confess is my rather critical response to the
book. But before saying more about that, let me first make clear how
much I genuinely admire what White has done. First and foremost, I want
to praise him for his willingness to learn about new and difficult
subjects. He is not resting on his ample laurels. He has waded into
unfamiliar territory here, and he has waded in deep. It is no easy task
to sort through the vast correspondence of railroad executives and
financiers, to parse their extensive testimony before Congress, to
follow the stories written about them (and perhaps by them) in the press
of the day, and to digest this into coherent stories about bond issues
and legislative battles. It is no small matter to master the intricacies
of financial instruments and the receivership process, to comprehend
such concepts as fixed costs and long-haul, short-haul pricing, and to
explain it all cogently in terms readily accessible to a general
audience. And it is no small matter to take seriously a literature in
business history that many American historians would not deign to
address.
Then there is the richness and texture with which White brings the
experience of railroading to life. In a book distinguished by its pithy,
sardonic prose, his vignettes of railroad lives stand out as especially
finely crafted examples of historical writing. Through them we sense the
loneliness and danger inherent to the railroad life, the perpetual
movement, and the ways these qualities shaped how men conceived of
themselves and their place in the larger order of things. And there is
also the appendix, which contains the fruits of a novel exercise in
mapping data and representing in graphic forms how railroads helped
reshape the flows of commerce in the West. White shows, for instance,
that goods often flowed in large volume from East to West--that the
lines were not merely tentacles reaching like straws from Chicago and
sucking out the natural bounty of the western landscape. Some animals
moved West when young and then back East again for slaughter. White
shows as well that the products moving East from California were much
more likely to be high-value foodstuffs, including many subject to
spoilage. Everywhere, bulk grain moved to the nearest port for water
transport. These charts reveal the richness of traffic flows more
vividly than I have ever seen. (523-33)
White also has shed new light on the realm of politics,
particularly in his extended treatment of the antimonopoly tradition,
which he astutely recognizes as central to the period he is studying. He
is particularly astute in explaining how antimonopoly influenced labor
relations, not always in ways that worked to the benefit of workers or
cast those workers in the best of light. He manages to portray
antimonopoly neither as a backward-looking response to progress nor as
an unproblematic antidote to aggregated power. Ever a shrewd observer,
he is alert to aspects of American politics that others often
overlook--not just to the bribery and influence, but also to the fact
that legislation is much easier to block than to pass and lobbyists can
more effectively influence battles over specific bills than shape public
opinion or alter partisan elections. He is alert, too, to the ways
politics operates simultaneously at the local and national levels,
greatly complicating the efforts of those who seek to accomplish ends
through political means. In striving to comprehend how ideology blends
with interest to shape the legislative process, he practices a brand of
political history scholars often seek but seldom achieve.
Above all, White's history sensitizes all of us who study the
nineteenth century to the centrality of information, and to the
sometimes peculiar ways in which information flowed in that world. It is
this quality, of course, that makes his book so resonant with our own
times. But rather than rush to flesh out those parallels, I would prefer
that historians pick up his challenge and consider how information
flowed in the past. White's book brims with suggestions about how
Americans coped with a watershed in communications technology, many of
which beg for further examination.
So, I find much to admire in this work. I have no doubt that it
deserves, and will garner, a large readership and the serious attention
of scholars in many disciplines of history. I suppose that goes without
saying, given the occasion. But the book also gives me some pause, and I
think a forum such as this calls upon me to explain why that is so. I
did not come all this way merely to praise Caesar.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC C OMITTED]
OPERATIONS AND POLITICS: A TRANSREGIONAL PERSPECTIVE
My hesitation goes back to Messrs. Chandler and Dilbert, and to
that matter of whether western railroads were really quite so different
from those in the East. The peculiar roots of the western lines, hatched
in the anomalous congressional politics of Civil War and Reconstruction,
undoubtedly saddled the transcontinentals with unusual burdens and
obligations while also opening unique opportunities for political
chicanery. But the issue of railroad debts had long been a staple of
state politics, and few legislatures in any part of the country escaped
the taint of corruption that followed. Eastern railroads always had been
deemed special entities operating in the public interest, and they came
under scrutiny from antimonopolists at both the state and federal
levels, even before the Golden Spike was hammered. (3) The roots of the
Reagan bill lay in issues arising in Pennsylvania and New York. Rate
structures were hopelessly convoluted in all regions, made more so by
state commissions that heard grievances and refereed disputes. (4)
Capital markets mattered to the eastern lines as well as the
western ones, as lines in the East competed to build connections
(including ones with the transcontinentals, as the Pennsylvania was
doing at St. Louis during the 1870s, with ample assistance from its
former vice president Tom Scott, who in pursuing a southwestern route
was not quite the renegade White suggests) and to push more traffic
through their trunks, while likely milking isolated communities that
lacked competitive service. Strong roads such as the
Pennsylvania grew stronger, while several prominent eastern lines,
such as the Philadelphia and Reading and the Baltimore and Ohio, fell
into the same sorts of receiverships that plagued so many (but not all)
western lines. Lines in the two regions operated in the same political
economy. (5)
What was true of politics was also true of railroad operations. The
sparseness and ruggedness of western geography doubtless presented some
distinctive challenges--not merely in construction, but also in
attracting business, recruiting personnel, and supervising operations.
The labor history of these lines makes this clear, not least through the
region's persistently high wages. There was certainly ample
opportunity for bribes and kickbacks, though this hardly distinguishes
these railroads from other enterprises operating sales networks across
vast regions. Most railroads of the era tended to deal with favored
partners, to butter the bread of those who funneled them business, in
ways that a modern auditor would doubtless find alarming but which were
also commonplace in the East and might well seem familiar to any member
of a modern frequent-flier program. Seasonal variations likewise plagued
lines in all regions of the country; part of the business of management
was to learn to deal with them. Operational managers everywhere were
coping with a world of great uncertainty and trying to reduce the
accompanying risks. They met in the same technical associations, read
the same trade journals, attended the same schools, and solicited advice
from one another. What gave definition to their efforts, in many cases,
were the complexities of the technology itself.
This notion is, of course, the essence of the
structural-functionalism that underlies Chandler, and if he perhaps
takes the concept too far, White seemingly takes pains to discount it at
every opportunity. White promises to dig deep into the managerial
records--to do the hard work that most railroad historians eschew--and
he comes through in spades when this involves presidential
correspondence. The work involved in following the financial and
political machinations is truly prodigious. But I am less impressed when
it comes to operational managers. The promised chapter on them consists
largely of extracts from the correspondence Union Pacific President
Charles Francis Adams Jr. conducted with a parade of general managers
and with others expressing frustration with those general managers.
Adams seems to have had the same luck with general managers that Lincoln
had with generals.
Aside from those lovely vignettes on railroad lives, only
occasionally do we glimpse further down into the managerial hierarchy.
And when we do, it is often to learn of some malfeasance or oddity, as
when one Southern Pacific manager employs a detective to follow another.
(453-54) We have no idea that during this same period these managers
were conducting a trial of freight train brakes that stands as one of
the most significant cooperative technical evaluations in the annals of
American technological history. (6) Nor do we hear much about the
freight agents, whom the historian Olivier Zunz portrays as
enthusiastically embracing the corporate ethos and dutifully carrying
out its dictates and responsibilities, such as filling out weekly
traffic reports. (7) Nor do we get any sense that experts from the world
over came to see for themselves how engineers built these lines across
vast spaces and through rugged mountainous terrain and to observe how
crews handled trains on the steep grades of the Rockies and High Sierra.
When managers at the Pennsylvania wanted to know how to operate long
trains with air brakes, they looked to the Union Pacific.
For these western railroads did carry traffic. And they did drive
down the costs of transport. White presents a series of charts that show
this in dramatic detail. But he often reads them far differently than I
do. He is likely to focus on the jaggedness of the lines, rather than
the slopes or curves. He wants us to concentrate on the disruptions.
Now, there is no denying that the late-nineteenth-century economy was
subject to booms and busts, not least in the West, where booms played
themselves out with stunning rapidity (and often with devastating
effects on the environment). But there is also no denying the long-term
trends. At one point, White quotes an alarmed executive who has
projected that in order to justify the amount of capital being invested
in the western transcontinentals during the mid- to late 1880s, traffic
would have to grow by seven times that carried by the Central and Union
Pacific before the massive expansion in facilities. (205, 211) And when
I look at Chart A, I find that traffic did grow at just about precisely
that rate. Investors did not earn increasing returns, but neither were
their investments for naught.
[GRAPHIC A OMITTED]
Which is why the Union Pacific found itself short on locomotives
and cars in 1892, and its managers fretted about how much the resultant
congestion was driving up costs, and the operating people pointed
fingers at the traffic agents for drumming up too much business, and the
traffic agents pointed back at the operating personnel for failing to do
their job, and top management naturally sided with the agents and took
steps to limit the responsibilities of the operating personnel until
they improved the situation. This was railroading. I describe similar
scenes at the vaunted Pennsylvania in the early twentieth century.
Managers there tried to restore harmony across the ranks, quite
literally, by having the operating personnel and traffic agents join
together in song--"down where the steel tonnage flows" was a
favored number. (This was Pittsburgh.) When that failed, management
considered adding a rule mandating that everyone cooperate. (8) All this
is easy pickings for Dilbert fans. Beyond that, it reveals how
intractable the problems were, and the limits of engineering approaches
in coping with them. But there was great earnestness in the effort--far
more than White allows, or at least certainly more than he admires--and
they learned some useful things along the way.
On the rare occasions when White does give voice to such men, he is
usually quick to read duplicity into their efforts, and above all to
brand them as naive. The engineer William Hyde trying to secure access
to the Southern California harbor doesn't know how to play the game
of politics as practiced by Huntington. (88-92) The engineer Arthur
Wellington, who develops a sophisticated analysis of how to lay routes
in the West--an approach that seeks to incorporate business
considerations such as the potential for traffic development rather than
merely considering narrow technical criteria--is selling out to the
ethos of insider trading. (143-49) The accountant William Mahl, who
strives to produce financial reports that more accurately reflected the
material and commercial assets of the railroads, is a facilitator and
apologist for Huntington. His son, whose promising career as a civil
engineer is cut short by tuberculosis, leaves behind a wallet full of
passes for White to pick. (270-77)
Something of the same is true when White turns to the halls of
politics. He will go to great lengths to question the motives of
politicians, demonstrate their duplicity, and suggest that they have
been bought. He is less interested in exploring what they thought, and
his interest fades further when we turn to the matter of actual
administration, through instruments such as congressional hearings and
appointed commissions. At a couple of places in the narrative, the
California State Railroad Commission comes on the scene. These
appearances come out of the blue; we never learn about its origins or
operations.
White concedes that politics was often running against the
railroads; they lost control of the press in San Francisco and never
achieved much legislative success in Congress once the Democrats
returned in sufficient numbers. He is more reluctant to acknowledge that
reform sometimes accomplished meaningful goals and imposed constraints
on the institutions Congress had created in the hothouse of the Civil
War and early Reconstruction. That task was all the more difficult
because the entities created were still anomalies in American political
economy. It was difficult to meet the challenges railroads posed without
violating fundamental precepts of American governance and potentially
inflicting damage on the rest of the economy. Yet the wheels of politics
did turn to confront the institutions government had created. Bills did
pass. They were not exactly what antimonopolists desired, because as
White recognizes, the last thing railroads needed was additional
competition. But neither were they what the railroads would have
preferred. They established a regulatory framework that provided an
outlet for a new generation of professional social scientists and
ultimately imposed significant constraints on the railroads.
LEARNING FROM RAILROADED
What I came to realize in reading this book is that while White and
I are interested in the same question, he is more interested in posing
the question than in answering it. To answer the question makes it less
interesting and less compelling. Thus, his tendency is to sustain the
sense of mystery. We wallow in the obfuscations and subterfuges, for by
wallowing in them we retain the essential sense of madness.
White characterizes his book as hopeful, while acknowledging that
many readers may have trouble reading it that way. In delegitimizing its
central characters and undermining the supposed necessity and
rationality of their accomplishments, he suggests the possibility that
things can be dramatically different. I follow his logic and sympathize
with the sentiment. Surely, I prefer his approach to the sort of
triumphalism that has characterized so much writing on these western
railroads and on the West more generally. We have much more to learn
from western railroads than the notion that we can summon extraordinary
courage, subdue nature, and build great things.
One never knows, of course, what readers will make of a book. White
worries that he will be read as resurrecting the robber barons. He may
be right, though personally I accept his defense that the notion implies
a more ordered power (and shared consensus) than railroad executives
could actually muster. To my mind, his work is more likely to take us
back to another historical warhorse, that of the "Great
Barbecue," a world where businessmen and politicians are seen as
feathering each other's nests on a scale unprecedented in American
history. (9)
The portrayal here is less one of an organized capitalist class
disrupting and sullying politics (except in White's view when
courts grant corporations the rights of citizens) than of politics
muddying the waters of commerce by handing out favors to privileged
opportunists and enabling firms that should rightly have failed to
survive through generous receivership provisions. If they find it, I
suspect White's book will serve for many readers as a case study in
what can go wrong when government meddles with private enterprise.
Congress got involved, railroads got built ahead of demand, and energies
got directed toward manipulating the strings of politics rather than
toward making an honest living by pursuing efficiencies and gaining
advantage in a competitive marketplace. Tea Party advocates might find
much fuel here for their fire, while progressives advocating public
investment might well take pause. Such are the perils of writing about
American political economy.
What troubles me about White's approach is that it obscures
another source of hope we might derive from the past--the hope provided
by seeing how Americans came to grips with difficult, nearly intractable
problems. They didn't find the best solution; they didn't find
the worst solution. They struck compromises, not least with their own
ideals. They struggled to reconcile market mechanisms with central
administration. They learned the limits of their own expertise. But on
the whole, they tried to find ways to make things work. This was largely
the work of bureaucrats--not the supremely efficient managers imagined
by Chandler but the midlevel types (often trained in the professions,
especially accounting and engineering) who muddle along and tolerate the
daily absurdities and frustrations we laugh about in Dilbert. They are
human; they have biases; they are subject to influence; the solutions
they devise work to the advantage of some and the disadvantage of
others. In short, they have a history; they embody an accumulated
cultural inheritance. They make easy targets, of course. It is easy to
dismiss them or poke fun at them, and hard to make them exciting. What
was the last good movie you saw about middle management that didn't
make them victims of greed or the butts of jokes? But for all that, I
think they have a lot to do with why my overpass doesn't fall.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
NOTES
(1) Steven W. Usselman, Regulating Railroad Innovation: Business,
Technology, and Politics in America, 1840-1920 (New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2002).
(2) Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial
Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press, 1977), 79-187.
(3) The ceremony of the Golden Spike on May 10, 1869, at Promontory
Point, Utah Territory, united the 1,774 miles of railroad built by the
crews of the Union Pacific and Central Pacific Railroads.
(4) During the 1877-78 Congressional session, Texas representative
John H. Reagan, an antimonopolist and chairman of the commerce
committee, introduced a bill for the regulation of interstate commerce.
The bill to federally regulate the railroads was opposed, White writes,
by "virtually all railroad men." (356)
(5) See Usselman, Regulating Railroad Innovation, and Richard
Franklin Bensel, The Political Economy of American Ind The Political
Economy of American Industrialization, 1877-1900 (New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2000).
(6) Usselman, Regulating Railroad Innovation, 191-99, and Steven W.
Usselman, "Air Brakes for Freight Trains: Technological Innovation
in the American Railroad Industry, 1869-1900," Business History
Review 58 (1984): 30-50.
(7) Olivier Zunz, Making America Corporate, 1870-1920 (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1990), 37-66.
(8) Usselman, Regulating Railroad Innovation, 339-71.
(9) The notion, commonly used to describe congressional politics
during the Gilded Age, derives from the practice of politicians throwing
barbecues for favored constituents on the eve of elections; see Vernon
Louis Parrington, Main Currents in American Thought, vol. III, The
Beginnings of Critical Realism in America, 1860-1920 (New York, 1930),
23.
STEVEN W. USSELMAN is professor at the School of History,
Technology, and Society, Georgia Institute of Technology, where he
teaches a variety of courses pertaining to technology, business, and law
and policy in the United States. He has published widely and is the
author of Regulating Railroad Innovation: Business, Technology, and
Politics in America, 1840-1920 (Cambridge University Press, 2002), which
received the Ellis W. Hawley Prize from the Organization of American
Historians and the Hilton Prize in transport history, and coeditor of
The Challenge of Remaining Innovative: Insights from Twentieth-Century
American Business (Stanford University Press, 2009). Previously, he
served as associate director for research at Georgia Tech's Sloan
Center for Paper Business and Industry Studies (CPBIS) and as president
of the Society for the History of Technology.