The financial crisis: toward an explanation and policy response.
Steelman, Aaron ; Weinberg, John A.
The financial market events since August 2007--and especially those
after September 2008--have raised a number of important issues. Some
commentators have argued that these events demonstrate fundamental flaws
in the market system, flaws that can be corrected only by large-scale
intervention. The causes of the financial market turmoil are far from
settled and may not be fully known for some time. This essay will offer
one perspective. We will argue that, although there is some evidence of
market failure, the current crisis does not represent a wholesale
failure of financial markets. Instead, we will argue that the crisis
stems from the difficulty of responding to large shocks, the roots of
which are multifaceted, including past policy errors. While there are
ways in which financial regulation can be improved, there is also a
strong case to be made that the functioning of market discipline can be
improved by constraining some forms of government intervention,
especially those that dampen incentives by protecting private creditors
from loss.
It will be useful to think of the essay as divided into the
following components. First, what has happened in the financial markets.
Second, why those events took place. Third, possible market
imperfections that could produce turmoil in the financial markets and an
assessment of the role they have played in this case. And, fourth, how
policymakers should respond in these diff cult and uncertain times.
Again, it is important to note that the thesis offered is only
tentative. Financial economists, no doubt, will examine this period for
many years to come and debate the merits of competing explanations. In
doing so, they will refine those ideas and come closer to a
comprehensive understanding of what has occurred. This research,
hopefully, will be more than an academic exercise. It should provide
insights to financial market participants and policymakers so that
similar events do not arise in the future.
1. WHAT HAPPENED: A BRIEF TIMELINE
In the first half of 2007, as the extent of declining home prices
became apparent, banks and other financial market participants started
to reassess the value of mortgages and mortgage-backed securities that
they owned, especially those in the subprime segment of the housing
market. In early August 2007, the American Home Mortgage Investment
Corporation filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection, prompting
concern among financial market participants. At its August 10, 2007,
meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) stated that in
"current circumstances, depository institutions may experience
unusual funding needs because of dislocations in money and credit
markets. As always, the discount window is available as a source of
funding." The following month, the FOMC lowered the federal funds
rate 50 basis points to 4.75 percent, the first in a series of rate cuts
that would ultimately bring the target to a range of 0 to 0.25 percent
in December 2008.
The autumn of 2007 saw increasing strains in a number of market
segments, including asset-backed commercial paper, and banks also began
to exhibit a reluctance to lend to one another for terms much longer
than overnight. This reluctance was reflected in a dramatic rise in the
London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) at most maturities greater than
overnight. LIBOR is a measure of the rates at which international banks
make dollar loans to one another. Since that initial disruption,
financial markets have remained in a state of high volatility, with many
interest rate spreads at historically high levels.
In response to this turbulence, the Fed and the federal government
have taken a series of dramatic steps. As 2007 came to a close, the
Federal Reserve Board announced the creation of a Term Auction Facility
(TAF), in which fixed amounts of term funds are auctioned to depository
institutions against any collateral eligible for discount window loans.
So while the TAF substituted an auction mechanism for the usual fixed
interest rate, this facility can be seen essentially as an extension of
more conventional discount window lending. In March 2008, the New York
Fed provided term financing to facilitate the purchase of Bear Stearns
by JPMorgan Chase through the creation of a facility that took a set of
risky assets off the company's balance sheet. That month, the Board
also announced the creation of the Term Securities Lending Facility
(TSLF), swapping Treasury securities on its balance sheet for less
liquid private securities held in the private sector, and the Primary
Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF). These actions, particularly the latter,
represented a significant expansion of the federal financial safety net
by making available a greater amount of central bank credit, at prices
unavailable in the market, to institutions (the primary dealers) beyond
those banks that typically borrow at the discount window. (1)
Throughout the summer of 2008, the stability of the housing finance
government-sponsored enterprises, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, came under
increasing scrutiny. While their core businesses have historically been
in the securitization of less risky, "conforming" mortgages,
they had in recent years accumulated significant balance sheet holdings
of less traditional mortgage assets. In September, both companies were
placed in conservatorship by the newly created Federal Housing Finance
Agency.
In the fall of 2008, financial markets worldwide experienced
another round of heightened volatility and historic changes for many of
the largest financial institutions. Lehman Brothers filed for Chapter 11
bankruptcy protection; investment banking companies Goldman Sachs and
Morgan Stanley successfully submitted applications to become bank
holding companies; Bank of America purchased Merrill Lynch; Wells Fargo
acquired Wachovia; PNC Financial Services Group purchased National City
Corporation; and the American International Group received significant
financial assistance from the Federal Reserve and the Treasury
Department.
On the policy front, the Federal Reserve announced the creation of
several new lending facilities--including the Asset-Backed Commercial
Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF), the Commercial
Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), the Money Market Investor Funding
Facility (MMIFF), and the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility
(TALF), the last of which became operational in March 2009. The TALF was
designed to support the issuance of asset-backed securities
collateralized by student loans, auto loans, credit card loans, and
loans guaranteed by the Small Business Administration, while also
expanding the TAF and the TSLF. The creation of these programs resulted
in a tremendous expansion of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet.
Furthermore, Congress passed the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) to
be administered by the Treasury Department. And in February 2009, the
president signed the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, a fiscal
stimulus program of roughly $789 billion. (2)
2. WHY THE CRISIS?
The proximate cause of the financial distress since 2007 has been
the decline in the housing market, which imposed substantial losses on
financial institutions and led to disruptions throughout the credit
markets. These disruptions have spread to the real economy, leaving the
United States in the midst of a significant recession and prompting many
of the measures described earlier.
What caused the boom in the housing market and its subsequent
decline? Again, the answers are not obvious and various explanations
will need to be vetted by economists over time. While multiple factors
likely contributed to the cycle, some of which we will discuss below, a
key factor involves the risk-taking incentives facing market
participants.
First, there were what could be called "fundamental"
factors. From roughly 1995 to 2005, the U.S. economy experienced a
significant increase in productivity growth and thus real household
income. Insofar as households saw these conditions as likely to
continue, they increased demand for housing and thus housing prices.
Indeed, housing investment and prices continued to rise through the 2001
recession, unlike most postwar business cycles. Those gains in
productivity and household income began to weaken in 2005--and with it,
consumers' ability to repay their loans. Another plausible
explanation involves technological advances in retail credit delivery.
As financial institutions were able to more efficiently gather
information about potential borrowers, they were able to more carefully
craft loans to a wider segment of the population. In retrospect, some of
those decisions may have been suspect--but, again, insofar as lenders
believed economic conditions would continue on the trajectory they were
then following, there was good reason for financial institutions to
expand lending to people who in the past may not have received
mortgages. One might argue that both borrowers and lenders
"overshot" or behaved irrationally. But, given the information
available to them at the time, their behavior seems less like mania and
more like the actions of reasonable, foresighted actors, who happened to
make an error in judgment about future trends in economic conditions. In
addition to what we may consider explanations based on economic
fundamentals, there were also a series of public policy decisions that
probably fueled the housing boom to levels inconsistent with market
conditions. First, the Federal Reserve pursued an accommodative monetary
policy following the terrorist attacks of 2001. This was especially true
in 2003 and 2004 when the target for the federal funds rate was held
between 1 percent and 2 percent, as the economy began to rebound from
the earlier brief recession. Such policy created an environment in which
credit grew quite freely. (3) Others have argued that beyond the effects
of monetary policy, long-term interest rates were held down by a
"global savings glut." (4) This may have heightened
investors' interest in "reaching for yield" by taking on
greater risks.
Moreover, in an effort to expand access to housing credit,
especially for people at the lower end of the income distribution,
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac increased their purchases of subprime
securities. (5) Many of the underlying loans in these securities proved
problematic and, as noted earlier, contributed to Fannie and Freddie
being placed under federal conservatorship. Why have problems in the
housing market caused substantial turmoil throughout the banking sector,
leading many institutions to become more cautious about their current
lending actions and investors to be cautious in their dealings with
banks? There are at least three possible explanations, all having to do
with uncertainty.
First, there is uncertainty about the aggregate magnitude of the
losses financial institutions are likely to suffer. Many of the
mortgages they issued are of relatively recent vintage, so how those
borrowers--and, in turn, the lenders--will fare is unclear. Also, the
extent of mortgage defaults and foreclosures will depend on the size of
the decline in house prices--an ongoing process as of this writing.
Second, financial market participants are unsure about the
distribution of those losses. Mortgage risks were spread widely, through
securitization and use of the insurance capabilities provided by credit
derivative contracts. Thus, institutions are concerned about how their
counterparties' mortgage-related losses will affect their own
viability.
Third, there is policy uncertainty. After the onset of the crisis,
the Federal Reserve and the Treasury took several actions to help
stabilize the financial sector. However, these actions appeared to
evolve on a case-by-case basis. Some institutions received support,
while others did not, making it more difficult for market participants
to discern the governing principles and to make predictions about future
policy moves. These institutions were already facing an uncertain
economic environment, which contributed to relatively sparse lending
opportunities.
Coupled with an uncertain public policy environment, it is not
surprising that many have been hesitant to lend and that many have had
trouble raising private capital.
Any narrative of this boom-and-bust cycle must take into account
the risk-taking incentives of financial market participants. And, here,
the role of the federal financial safety net is important. Many
financial transactions take place under some form of government
protection. Some protections are explicit--such as the guarantee offered
to bank depositors. Arguably, such protection has reduced
depositors' incentive to scrutinize the riskiness of their
banks' lending practices and may have contributed to the crisis
experienced by thrifts in the 1980s. In addition, it seems likely that
market participants view the safety net to include more than simply
those explicit guarantees. That is to say, many market participants may
believe that there are implicit guarantees, which also affect their
risk-taking behavior. (6) For instance, there has long been a widely
held notion that some financial institutions are simply "too big to
fail." Such institutions are perceived to be essential to the
functioning of domestic and often of international financial markets. As
a result, these institutions and their creditors may assume that, should
they encounter difficulties due to unwise lending practices, the public
sector will respond to maintain their solvency. (7)
Such public-sector action might take several forms. It could
involve direct lending to troubled firms by the Federal Reserve or the
Treasury Department. Or it could take a less direct form, such as that
which occurred in the case of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM). The
Federal Reserve helped to orchestrate a recapitalization of LTCM by its
creditors. Had LTCM's creditors not taken action to keep the firm
from bankruptcy, it is unclear how the Fed would have responded. But
market participants might have reasonably assumed--given the Fed's
interest in seeing LTCM survive--that explicit federal assistance would
have been forthcoming. Further, the Fed's involvement signaled a
concern about the possible systemic consequences of losses incurred by
the large institutions that were exposed to LTCM. (8)
Given the presence of the federal financial safety net--both its
explicit and implicit guarantees--what options do policymakers face?
Some might argue that the moral hazard problems associated with a large
federal financial safety net cannot be avoided, especially in rich,
advanced countries. As a result, we must more stringently regulate those
firms that may avail themselves to such protection to ensure that they
are acting prudently and, hence, to protect the taxpayer. Indeed, one
may be skeptical--or remain relatively agnostic--about the inevitability
or desirability of the federal financial safety net, yet still argue
that, given its presence, the current regulatory regime may need to
remain intact or be strengthened. (9)
Such arguments are reasonable. However, additional regulation of
financial markets would likely hamper innovation in that industry. An
alternative approach is to seek to reduce the scope of explicit safety
net protection--as well as creditors' expectations of implicit
protection of firms deemed too big to fail. (10) The presence of the
federal financial safety net was not the sole cause of questionable
risk-taking by financial institutions. (11) But it likely altered those
institutions' behavior and, hence, contributed to the current
turmoil. Any future attempt to redesign financial regulation should be
undertaken with an assessment of the safety net, including the
desirability and feasibility of scaling back implicit protections.
Attempting to restructure the regulatory landscape without taking into
account the effects of the safety net is like "putting the cart
before the horse." (12)
In summary, the boom and subsequent decline in the housing market
had numerous causes. In hindsight, private lenders and borrowers may
have made some imprudent decisions. But they were acting on what they
believed to be sound information about the current state of the economy
and the path of future growth.
Also, the Federal Reserve kept interest rates low for a long
period, which may have encouraged additional lending that exacerbated
the crisis. In addition, the government-sponsored enterprises greatly
expanded their portfolios, boosting the market for loans that have
proved difficult for many borrowers to repay. Finally, the presence of
the federal financial safety net likely encouraged institutions to take
risks that they otherwise would have forgone. The decline in the housing
market has sent shocks throughout the banking industry and related
financial institutions. Already, the Federal Reserve, the Treasury
Department, and Congress have taken considerable actions to stem the
financial crisis. Later, we will comment on those programs and consider
how the Federal Reserve, in particular, should try to implement an
"exit strategy" that will ultimately lead to the winding down
of current lending facilities and to renewed focus on price stability.
3. RATIONALES FOR PUBLIC-SECTOR CREDIT IN FINANCIAL CRISES
Much of the public policy response to turmoil in financial markets
over the last two years has taken the form of expanded lending by the
Fed and central banks in other countries. The extension of credit to
financial institutions has long been one of the tools available to a
central bank for managing the supply of money--specifically, bank
reserves--to the economy.
Indeed, discount window lending by the 12 Reserve Banks was the
primary means for affecting the money supply at the time the Fed was
created. Over time, open market operations, in which the Fed buys and
sells securities in transactions with market participants, have become
the main tool for managing the money supply. Lending became a relatively
little-used tool, mainly accessed by banks with occasional unexpected
flows into or out of their Fed reserve accounts late in the day. If such
banks were to seek funding in the market, they would likely have to pay
above-normal rates for a short-term (overnight) loan. In this way, the
discount window became a tool for dampening day-to-day fluctuations in
the federal funds rate. In 2006, average weekly lending by the Reserve
Banks through the discount window was $59 million.
Since the outset of the widespread market disruptions in the summer
of 2007, the Fed has changed the terms of its lending to banks and
created new lending facilities. In the first three quarters of 2008,
weekly Fed lending averaged $132.2 billion, and in the fourth quarter of
the year, that figure rose to $847.8 billion.
In some cases, lending in response to a crisis can be seen as an
extension of the use of central bank credit as a tool for managing the
money supply. But for much of the current crisis, the Fed has not used
its lending in this way.
Even though lending rose sharply, the Fed's overall balance
sheet, and therefore its supply of money to the economy, remained
roughly unchanged until September 2008. Until that time, the Fed was
"sterilizing," or offsetting, its lending growth with open
market operations. This suggests that, at least initially, the aim of
expanded Fed credit was not growth in the overall supply of money or
liquidity to markets but rather the direction of money or liquidity to
particular market segments deemed to be in the greatest need of support.
The use of sterilized lending in order to direct funding to
institutions or markets is based on the belief that, at times, financial
markets cannot properly function in directing funds to where they are
needed the most. (13) Like any argument about the need for or
consequences of public-sector intervention in markets, this is a
statement of economic theory. In discussions of the Fed's actions
in the last two years, two theoretical concepts have stood out as
reasons why markets might fail to effectively allocate funds among
market participants--coordination problems and "firesale"
prices.
The classic example of a coordination problem in a financial market
is a bank run. When depositors have the right to take their funds out of
the bank on demand, and when the bank uses these highly liquid
liabilities to fund longer-term, illiquid assets, then the bank is
fragile in the sense that a sudden demand by many depositors for their
money could force the bank to liquidate some of its longer-term assets
inefficiently. This fragility makes the bank subject to a run in which
depositors demand their funds because they think other depositors are
doing the same. In such a case, all depositors might be better off if
they could coordinate their decisions and leave their money in the bank,
saving the bank from the costs of ineffcient liquidations. The inability
to coordinate means that bank runs could conceivably cause even a
solvent bank to fail. (14)
The key characteristic that makes runs possible is the maturity
mismatch on a bank's balance sheet--funding long-term assets with
short-term liabilities. In recent years, this feature has not been
limited to traditional, commercial banking. The securitization of
mortgages and other assets has brought with it a number of other types
of this maturity transformation--asset-backed commercial paper,
auction-rate securities, and the funding of investment banks'
holdings of securities through overnight repurchase agreements. Most of
these nonbank arrangements have come under stress at some point during
the ongoing market turbulence.
The fragility that makes runs possible, however, is itself the
result of choices made by market participants. The willingness to create
a fragile balance sheet structure should depend on market
participants' beliefs about what would happen in the event of a
run-like event. And part of these beliefs should involve people's
expectations about public-sector actions in the event of a run. In
particular, the likelihood of assistance in the form of government or
central bank lending reduces the prospective private costs of a run and,
on the margin, increases the incentive to engage in maturity
transformation. This is an essential part of the moral hazard problem
resulting from the federal financial safety net. (15)
Another important ingredient of the theory of runs is that the
early liquidation of long-term assets is costly. If a bank is forced to
sell an asset to meet its depositors' demands for funds, there must
be a real loss compared to holding the asset to maturity. If all assets
could be sold at a price equal to the expected, discounted present value
of the ultimate returns, then depositors' demands could be met
without loss, which in turn eliminates a depositor's incentive to
run. In traditional banking, the possibility of a run comes from the
notion that the bank would have to sell loans, for which the originating
bank has an advantage in monitoring borrowers' performance and
ensuring repayment. But in the recent episode, assets at the heart of
maturity transformation increasingly have been asset-backed securities,
for which there may be no particular advantage to the institution
holding securities on its balance sheet. Indeed, such securities were
envisioned as a way of making loans more "tradeable" by
pooling together many loans into a security.
Through much of this episode of financial volatility, many
commentators have argued that the prices observed on many types of
assets, especially those related to housing, represent deviations from
fundamental market value. The available prices are seen as firesale
prices--lower than fundamental value because many institutions have been
or may be forced to sell their assets in attempts to repair their
balance sheets. For such low prices to persist, there must be no patient
market participants with the financial resources and knowledge necessary
to profit from buying assets at artificially low prices. This suggests
that either the fundamental shocks affecting financial markets were so
pervasive as to compromise essentially all participants' financial
positions or there is some incompleteness or segmentation that prevents
those with financial resources from taking advantage of arbitrage
opportunities. (16)
Theories of market imperfections that give rise to financial market
disruptions in which prices deviate persistently from fundamentals might
imply that targeted public-sector credit can improve the functioning of
the market. But matching conditions observed in actual markets to
conditions in these theories is a difficult judgment.
Much of what we have observed is also consistent with a market in
which significant fundamental shocks have greatly increased the
uncertainty facing market participants. If policymakers have no better
information than market participants about fundamental values as
compared to market prices, then the ability of targeted public-sector
intervention to improve market conditions is limited.
4. PAST, CURRENT, AND FUTURE PUBLIC POLICY RESPONSES
It is understandable that the Federal Reserve, the Treasury
Department, and Congress were eager to act as the financial system began
to face what many feared to be systemic risks. However, problems in the
financial system have persisted in spite of these efforts and some of
those resulting policies could create challenges of their own over time.
The most fundamental issue, of course, is moral hazard. How will
current federal intervention affect the behavior of banks and investors
in the future? That is, will the support that has been provided
encourage financial institutions to engage in behavior that they
otherwise would have eschewed? Basic economic theory suggests so: The
more something is subsidized, the more that is likely to be provided. In
this case, the "something" is leveraged risk-taking, leading
to potentially imprudent lending. How large this effect will be is
ultimately an empirical question. But it is important to note that even
if all of the new lending facilities were eliminated as the economy and
financial system recover, moral hazard will still be a problem. Market
participants know that federal support was readily forthcoming during
the current turmoil--and most now would reasonably expect that such
support will be there when the next turmoil occurs. Changing these
expectations will be a long and hard process. In short, the Fed will
need to regain credibility for not bailing out insolvent
institutions--and as we know from our experience with monetary policy in
the 1970s, such efforts to gain credibility can be long and difficult.
(17)
The current situation, with a vastly expanded financial safety net,
presents long-term challenges with respect to private-sector risk-taking
and risk-management incentives. Even in the near term, the task of
scaling back the safety net toward its pre-crisis status raises many
difficult questions. For instance, the extent to which the new lending
facilities should be either eliminated or moved to the Treasury
Department is a matter of debate. But, as a matter of governance and
central bank independence, there is a strong argument that those
facilities which target specific industries or credit markets should be
handled first. The provision of subsidized credit--especially on a
sustained basis--is a fiscal policy action. Depending on one's
perspective, this may or may not be a desirable policy goal, but it is
arguably not one that should be pursued by the central bank. Placing the
administration and funding of such programs under the direction of the
Treasury Department puts those programs more directly under
congressional authority.
The conflation of the roles of the Federal Reserve and the Treasury
Department during the current crisis could threaten the Fed's
independence. The Federal Reserve's principal policy goal is to
conduct monetary policy in pursuit of price stability and sustainable
macroeconomic growth. That goal is much harder to pursue in a world
where the Fed is also operating a number of lending facilities. In the
near term, inflation does not appear to be a problem, certainly not
relative to continued weakness in the real economy. But when the economy
recovers, the Fed must have the flexibility to restrain monetary growth
and prevent rising inflation. And the Fed's ability to exercise
this vigilance will be enhanced if it can separate its credit policy
activities from its management of the money supply. Expansion of Fed
credit expands the monetary base by adding to reserves held by the
banking system with the Fed. Indeed, from the beginning of September of
2008 through the end of the year, total reserves held at the Fed grew
from close to $10 billion to about $785 billion. Other things equal, an
expansion of the monetary base is stimulative. Such stimulus is
generally warranted in a period of economic contraction. But when the
economy recovers, the Fed will need to have the flexibility to remove
the monetary stimulus brought about by an expanded base.
Fundamentally, the Fed must determine how it wishes to act as a
lender of last resort. The Fed could benefit from heeding the advice of
two classical economists, Henry Thornton and Walter Bagehot, who
considered how the Bank of England could act effectively as the lender
of last resort. The Thornton-Bagehot framework stressed six key points:
* Protecting the aggregate money stock, not individual institutions
* Letting insolvent institutions fail
* Accommodating only sound institutions
* Charging penalty rates
* Requiring good collateral
* Preannouncing these conditions well in advance of any crisis so
that the market would know what to expect. (18)
Current Federal Reserve credit policy has deviated from most if not
all of these principles. Before the crisis, the Fed's lender of
last resort activity functioned as a standing facility with fixed terms.
Through the crisis, the Fed's approach has evolved and changed in
numerous directions, including the direction of credit to particular
market segments and institutions. Beyond winding down its many new
lending vehicles, the Fed will need to make it clear to all market
participants which principles it will follow during future crises.
Reductions in the Fed's credit activities--even in the near
term--do not need to result in monetary contraction, as those programs
can be replaced by asset purchases.
This last point also applies to actions taken beyond those of the
Federal Reserve. Public policies by all agencies must be well
articulated and time consistent so that market actors can make rational
plans regarding their financial and other business affairs. Arguably,
such policy uncertainty did much to prolong the Great Depression in the
United States. (19) In addition, policymakers should be wary about the
potential productivity-dampening effects of ill-considered fiscal and
regulatory policies. There is some evidence that such policies slowed
productivity in the United States during the 1930s (20) and in Japan
during the 1990s. (21) While, as noted earlier, the Federal Reserve
should not be directly involved in appropriating funds, it is not beyond
its bounds to offer thoughts on the relative efficiency of such programs
pursued by the legislative and executive bodies.
5. CONCLUSION
The United States--and, indeed, the whole world--has experienced a
significant financial and economic crisis since late 2007, and
especially since September of 2008. The causes of that crisis are
multifaceted and will require much future research. However,
policymakers must act in real time on the best information available. It
is not surprising that policymakers have taken a very active approach to
the current crisis; after all, the costs of inaction were perceived to
be quite large. The effects of those actions, just like the causes of
the crisis, will no doubt continue to be the subject of much study and
commentary for some time.
This episode has brought a number of particular questions to the
forefront, questions that will be at the center of ongoing efforts to
strengthen our financial system. Among those are questions regarding the
possible sources of incentives for financial market participants to take
excessive risks. One candidate discussed earlier involves the incentive
effects of the federal financial safety net. The significance of this
potential contributor to risk-taking lies in its implications for how we
think about the role of Fed credit in ensuring financial stability.
While the liberal provision of credit can cushion the effects of a
crisis, expectation of such credit availability can dampen incentives to
take actions that may limit the likelihood of a crisis. This tradeoff
lies at the heart of any effort to design a set of policies that
achieves a balance between the roles of government and market forces in
disciplining the incentives of participants in our financial system.
The authors are, respectively, director of publications, and senior
vice president and director of research at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond. They would like to thank Bob Hetzel, Jeff Lacker, Ned
Prescott, and John Walter for helpful comments and suggestions. The
views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve System.
APPENDIX
This timeline appeared in the original publication as a sidebar.
Summer 2007: Markets first respond on a large scale to concerns
that mortgage-backed securities might significantly underperform
expectations
August 10, 2007: Federal Reserve announces that it "will
provide reserves as necessary" amidst strains in money and credit
markets
September 18, 2007: FOMC lowers target federal funds rate 50 basis
points to 4.75 percent, the first of a series of rate cuts
December 12, 2007: Fed announces creation of the Term Auction
Facility (TAF), the first of several new tools designed to provide
liquidity to markets
March 11, 2008: Fed creates Term Securities Lending Facility
(TSLF), which trades banks' illiquid assets, including
mortgage-backed securities, for liquid Treasury securities
March 16, 2008: Fed creates Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF),
allowing it to lend to primary dealers for the first time
March 14-24, 2008: Fed announces it will provide term financing for
JPMorgan Chase to purchase Bear Stearns by taking risky securities off
Bear's balance sheet via the PDCF
September 7, 2008: Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) places
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in government conservatorship following
increasing scrutiny over their soundness
September 15, 2008: Lehman Brothers files for Chapter 11 bankruptcy
protection
October 3, 2008: President Bush signs into law the Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, establishing the $700 billion
Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP)
November 25, 2008: Fed announces creation of the Term Asset-Backed
Securities Loan Facility (TALF), supporting the issuance of asset-backed
securities. Becomes operational in March 2009
November 25, 2008: Fed announces program to purchase direct
obligations of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and mortgage-backed
securities backed by them. Purchases begin January 5, 2009
December 11, 2008: The Business Cycle Dating Committee of the
National Bureau of Economic Research announces that the recession began
in December 2007
December 16, 2008: FOMC votes to establish a range for the fed
funds rate of 0 to 0.25 percent
REFERENCES
Allen, Franklin, and Douglas M. Gale. 1998. "Optimal Financial
Crises." Journal of Finance 53 (4): 1,245-84.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2005. "The Global Saving Glut and the U.S.
Current Account Deficit." Remarks before the Virginia Association
of Economists, Richmond, Va. (March 10).
Cole, Harold L., and Lee E. Ohanian. 2004. "New Deal Policies
and the Persistence of the Great Depression: A General Equilibrium
Analysis." Journal of Political Economy 112 (4): 779-816.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig. 1983. "Bank Runs,
Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity." Journal of Political Economy 91
(3): 401-19.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2009. "The Credit
Crisis: Conjectures About Causes and Remedies." Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14739 (February).
Edward, Franklin R. 1999. "Hedge Funds and the Collapse of
Long-Term Capital Management." Journal of Economic Perspectives 13
(2): 189-210.
Ennis, Huberto M., and Todd Keister. 2007. "Bank Runs and
Institutions: The Perils of Intervention." Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Working Paper 07-02 (March).
Goodfriend, Marvin, and Robert G. King. 1988. "Financial
Deregulation, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking." Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 74 (3): 3-22.
Goodfriend, Marvin, and Jeffrey M. Lacker. 1999. "Limited
Commitment and Central Bank Lending." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 85 (4): 1-27.
Haubrich, Joseph G. 2007. "Some Lessons on the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Policy Discussion Paper 19 (April).
Hayashi, Fumio, and Edward C. Prescott. 2002. "The 1990s in
Japan: A Lost Decade." Review of Economic Dynamics 5 (1): 206-35.
Higgs, Robert. 1997. "Regime Uncertainty: Why the Great
Depression Lasted So Long and Why Prosperity Resumed After the
War." Independent Review 1 (4): 561-90.
Hoshi, Takeo, and Anil Kashyap. 2004. "Japan's Financial
Crisis and Economic Stagnation." Journal of Economic Perspectives
18 (1): 3-26.
Humphrey, Thomas M. 1989. "Lender of Last Resort: The Concept
in History." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 75
(2): 8-16.
Kareken, John H. 1983. "Deposit Insurance Reform or
Deregulation Is the Cart, Not the Horse." Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis Quarterly Review 7 (2): Not numbered.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. 2008. "Financial Stability and Central
Banks." Remarks before the European Economics and Financial Centre,
London, England (June 5).
Meltzer, Allan H. 2009. "The Global Financial Crisis of
2007-2009."American Enterprise Institute, manuscript (January).
Stern, Gary H., and Ron J. Feldman. 2004. Too Big to Fail: The
Hazards of Bank Bailouts. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Taylor, John B. 2008. "The Financial Crisis and the Policy
Responses: An Empirical Analysis of What Went Wrong." Stanford
University, manuscript (November).
Walter, John R., and John A. Weinberg. 2002. "How Large is the
Federal Financial Safety Net?" Cato Journal 21 (3): 369-93.
(1) The term "bank" is used broadly to refer to all
depository institutions--including banks, thrifts, and credit
unions--with routine access to the discount window.
(2) For a comprehensive timeline of the financial crisis, see the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis' website, "The Financial
Crisis: A Timeline of Events and Policy Actions," at
http://www.stlouisfed.org/timeline/default.cfm.
(3) Taylor (2008).
(4) Bernanke (2005).
(5) Meltzer (2009).
(6) Walter and Weinberg (2002).
(7) Such protection does not extend to the financial sector only.
Other industries, such as the airline and automobile industries, have
also received government assistance in the past decade.
(8) Haubrich (2007).
(9) Edward (1999).
(10) Stern and Feldman (2004) argue that too-big-to-fail protection
imposes net costs on society and that the problem has grown in severity
over time.
(11) For instance, Diamond and Rajan (2009) argue that, over short
periods of time, even vigilant creditors may have difficulty monitoring
whether financial managers are engaged in excessive risk-taking,
especially in the case of new products.
(12) Kareken (1983) used this analogy in the slightly different
context of banking deregulation in the 1980s.
(13) Goodfriend and King (1988) argue that with well-functioning
markets to redistribute funds, open market operations are sufficient to
provide liquidity to markets.
(14) Diamond and Dybvig (1983).
(15) Lacker (2008). See also Ennis and Keister (2007).
(16) Allen and Gale (1998) describe the phenomenon of "cash in
the market pricing" in a financial crisis.
(17) Goodfriend and Lacker (1999) discuss how central banks could
build a reputation for limiting their lending commitments, just as
central banks acquired credibility for maintaining price stability.
(18) Humphrey (1989).
(19) Higgs (1997).
(20) Cole and Ohanian (2004).
(21) Hayashi and Prescott (2002) and Hoshi and Kashyap (2004).