A cohort model of labor force participation.
Kudlyak, Marianna
The aggregate labor force participation (LFP) rate measures the
share of the civilian noninstitutionalized population who are either
employed or unemployed (i.e., actively searching for work). Prom 1963 to
2000, the LFP rate was rising, reaching its peak at 67.1 percent. The
LFP rate has been declining ever since, with the decline accelerating
after 2007. Between December 2007 and December 2012, the LFP rate
declined from 66 percent to 63.6 percent. Prior to 2012, the last year
when the LFP rate was below 65 percent was 1986.
The decline in the LFP rate, which coincided with the Great
Recession, raises the question: Is the LFP rate at the end of 2012 close
to or below its long-run trend? The question is important to
policymakers and economists. If a large portion of the workers who are
currently out of the labor force represents workers who are temporarily
out of the labor force, then the unemployment rate by itself might not
be a good measure of the slack in the economy.
In this article, we discuss the change in the aggregate LFP rate
from 2000 to 2012, with an emphasis on the changes in the age-gender
composition of the population and changes in the LFP rates of different
demographic groups. We then estimate a cohort-based model of the LFP
rates of different age-gender groups and construct the aggregate LFP
rate using the model estimates. The model is a parsimonious version of
the model studied in Aaronson et al. (2006). It contains age-gender
effects, birth-year cohort effects, and the estimated deviations of
employment from its long-run trend as the cyclical indicator. We Content
not available due to copyright restrictions.
1. WHAT COMPONENTS DRIVE THE CHANGES IN THE AGGREGATE LFP RATE
DURING 2000-12?
After reaching its peak of 67.3 percent in the first half of 2000,
the aggregate LFP rate declined from 2000 to Q2:2004, stabilized for a
few years, and then started falling again in 2008. (1) Figure 1 shows
the aggregate LFP rate and the aggregate unemployment rate.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The aggregate LFP rate can be decomposed into the weighted sum of
the LFP rates of different demographic groups, i.e.,
[LFP.sub.t] = [summation over (i)]
[s.sub.t.sup.i][LFP.sub.t.sup.i], (1)
where [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] is the labor force participation rate of
group i, [s.sub.t.sup.i] is the population share of group i, i.e.,
[s.sub.t.sup.i] [equivalent to] [Pop.sub.t.sup.i]/[Pop.sub.t], and
[Pop.sub.t.sup.i] is the population of group i.
Content not available due to copyright restrictions. Figure 3 shows
the LFP rates of different age-gender groups. As can be seen from the
figures, the developments that took place between Q4:2007 and Q4:2012
are a continuation of the developments that have
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
As can be seen from the figure, the experiment with holding the LFP
rates of 55-64 and 65+ year-old workers fixed (the dashed blue line)
delivers the largest discrepancy between the actual aggregate LFP (the
solid black line) and the counterfactual one. Since the LFP rate of
older workers has increased, the counterfactual rate lies below the
actual LFP rate, and in Q4:2012 stands at 61.7 percent.
The second largest discrepancy (in absolute value) between the
actual aggregate LFP and the counterfactual one is obtained from holding
the population shares fixed at their 2007 levels (the dashed red line).
In this case, the counterfactual LFP rate exceeds the actual one and
stands at almost 65 percent in Q4:2012. We see that between 2007 and
2012 the population composition has shifted toward a composition with
lower labor force attachment.
The results also show that the counterfactual based on the fixed
LFP of 16- to 24-year-old workers (the dashed green line) Content not
available due to copyright restrictions. Content not available due to
copyright restrictions. and the counterfactual based on the fixed LFP of
men (the yellow dashed line)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The observations above show that the demographic composition of the
population and the changes in the LFP rates of different groups have
played an important role in the change of the aggregate LFP rate. We now
proceed to examine the age-gender and cohort effects in the LFP rates of
different demographic groups on the aggregate LFP rate.
2. A COHORT-BASED MODEL OF LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION
The results in Section 1 show that the time-variation in the LFP
rates of different demographic groups are important for the variation in
the aggregate LFP rate. In this section, we propose a model for the
trend in the LFP rates of different demographic groups. We then estimate
the trend in the aggregate LFP rate using the estimated trends in the
Content not available due to copyright restrictions.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
As this cohort ages and moves through the age distribution, its
stronger labor force attachment carries over to the respective age
group.
We think of the demographic and the cohort effects in the LFP rates
of different demographic groups as the determinants of the long-run
labor force participation trend. To estimate this trend, we specify the
following model:
In [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] = [alpha] + in [[alpha].sub.n] [1996.summation
over (b=1917)] [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.f] In [[bata].sub.b.sup.f] + 1/n
[1996.summation over (b=1917)] [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.m] In
[[beta].sub.b.sup.m] + [[epsilon].sub.i,t], (2)
where [LFP.sub.t.sup.t] is the labor force participation rate of
age-gender group i, [[alpha].sub.i] is the fixed effect of age-gender
group i, [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.m] is the dummy variable that takes value 1 if
age-gender group i in period t includes women born in year b,
[C.sub.b,i,t.sup.f] is the dummy variable that takes value 1 if
age-gender group i in period t includes men born in year b, and n
denotes the number of ages in group i. We specify separate cohort
effects for men and women, i.e., [[beta].sub.b.sup.f]
([[beta].sub.b.sup.m]) is the cohort-specific fixed effect of a cohort
of women (men) born in year b. We assume that each cohort has equal
importance in the corresponding age group conditional on the number of
cohorts in the group. For the oldest group, 65+, we set n = 20 (setting
n = 30 does not have a substantial effect on the results). To identify
age-gender and cohort effects, we normalize in ai = 0 and ln
[[beta].sub.1969.sup.f] = 0. The model is estimated using pooled
quarterly data on the LFP rates of 14 age-gender groups.
The model in equation (2) is a simplified version of a model in
Aaronson et al. (2006). Using the estimates from equation (2), we obtain
the time series of in [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] for the 14 age-gender groups,
[^.[ln [LFP.sub.t.sup.i]]] and calculate [^.[LFP.sub.t.sup.i]] = exp
([^.[ln [LFP.sub.t.sup.i].sub.t.sup.i]] + [[sigma].sub.e.sup.2/2]),
where [[sigma].sub.e.sup.2/2] is the variance of
[^.[[epsilon].sub.i,t]]. We then construct the estimated aggregate LFP
rate as
[^[LFP.sub.t]] = [summation over (i)] [s.sub.t.sup.t]
[^.[LFP.sub.t.sup.i]], (3)
where [s.sub.t.sup.i] denotes the actual population share of group
i in quarter t. Thus, the population shares capture the effect of the
change in the demographic composition of the labor force, while
[^.[LFP.sub.t.sup.i]] reflects the age-gender and cohort effects of the
different demographic groups. We refer to [^.[LFP.sub.t]] from model (2)
as the estimated trend in the aggregate LFP rate.
Life-Cycle, Cohort, and Cyclical Effects
To further understand the behavior of the aggregate LFP rate, we
also estimate a model similar to the one in equation (2) with a cyclical
indi- Content not available due to copyright restrictions.
Empirical Results
One way to obtain the predictions from the models described in
equations (2) and (4) is to estimate the models using the 1976-2012
data, obtain the trend in the aggregate LFP rate (from equation [3]) and
the model-predicted aggregate LFP rate from the model with a cyclical
indicator, and compare the estimates with the actual LFP rate during
2008-12. Another way is to estimate the model on the 1976-2007 data and
then use the estimates together with the assumptions on cohort effects
and predict the aggregate LFP rate for 2008-12. The cohort model is
sensitive to which approach is used.
One of the concerns associated with cohort models is the
end-of-the-sample effect. In particular, the young cohorts observed in
the 1976-2012 sample (i.e., those born in 1985-1996) are observed only
during the period of the declining aggregate LFP rate. Thus, the model
identifies these cohorts' propensity to participate from the period
of overall low participation, attributing low LFP to these young cohorts
rather than to the model's residual. Given the severity and the
length of the Great Recession, the effects of the cohorts born prior to
1985 are also, to a large extent, identified from their labor force
participation rates during 2008-2012, the period of the overall low LFP.
This is the case for cohorts for which, for example, at least half of
the observations come from the 2008-12 period.
To avoid the end-of-sample effect on the estimates, we estimate the
models in equations (2) and (4) using the data from 1976-2007. To
construct the prediction of the aggregate LFP rate for 2008-12, we
assign, for cohorts born after 1991, the average cohort effect of the
last 20 cohorts. Figure 7 shows the following series: (1) the actual
aggregate LFP rate, (2) the LFP rate constructed from the model with
only age-gender effects, (3) the LFP rate constructed from the model
with age-gender and cohort effects estimated on 1976-2007 data, and (4)
the LFP rate constructed from the model with age-gender, cohort, and
cyclical effects estimated on 1976-2007 data. (4)
As can be seen from the figure, the aggregate LFP rate estimated
from the model with only age-gender and cohort effects on the 19762007
sample exceeds the actual aggregate LFP rate after 2008, and the two
lines coincide at the end of 2012. This measure constitutes our
preferred measure of the trend in the LFP rate. The aggregate LFP rate
estimated from the model with age-gender, cohort, and cyclical Content
not available due to copyright restrictions.
Content not available due to copyright restrictions. cohort and the
next is the same as for a set of cohorts observed over the last full
business cycle. The aggregate LFP rate based on the models with
restricted and unrestricted cohorts are similar, so the figure shows
only the results without restrictions. (5)
Discussion
In the model, the cohort effect stands for an average effect of all
non-modeled factors (beyond life-cycle, gender, and cyclical effects)
that affect the labor force participation of a cohort (i.e., the workers
born in a particular year) throughout the period the cohort is observed
in the sample. These factors can include both structural and cyclical
variables. For example, the availability of and the rules that govern
Social Security benefits and disability insurance might influence the
decision to look for work versus drop out of the labor force. The wage
premium from higher educational attainment might influence the decision
of younger workers to go to school rather than participate in the labor
force. The availability and cost of child care can influence the
decision of mothers to join the labor force.
Consequently, the cohort effects constitute a black box that
aggregates these influences and serve as a useful device for accounting
exercises. The cohort model, however, might not be the best laboratory
for long-term forecasts. In our estimation, we recognize explicitly that
the effect of young cohorts is to a large degree identified from the few
years during which we observe these cohorts in the data. In particular,
for the youngest cohorts, a low cohort effect can be due to the true low
propensity of these cohorts to participate or due to the model
attributing low cyclical LFP to the cohort effect. In our exercise, we
control for these effects. A forecasting exercise would inevitably
involve assumptions about the cohort effects going forward. It is
possible that, for example, the youngest cohorts who are not
participating currently due to schooling will, in fact, increase their
LFP as they grow older. The cohort model does not provide information to
support or reject such scenarios.
Content not available due to copyright restrictions. influence the
labor force participation decision of different demographic groups.
The author is grateful, without implicating them in any way, to Bob
Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein. Marios Karabarbounis, Steven Sabol, and Alex
Wolman for their comments. The author thanks Peter Debbaut and Samuel
Marshall for excellent research assistance. The views expressed here are
those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of R ichmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
marianna.kudlyak@rich.frb.org.
REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Jonathan Davis, and Luojia Hu. 2012.
"Explaining the Decline in the U.S. Labor Force Participation
Rate." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Chicago Fed Letter no. 296
(March).
Aaronson, Stephanie, Bruce FaHick, Andrew Figura, Jonathan Pingle,
and William Wascher. 2006. "The Recent Decline in the Labor Force
Participation Rate and Its Implications for Potential Labor
Supply." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 37 (Spring): 69-134.
Balleer, Ahnut, Ramon Gomez-Salvador, and Jarkko Turunen. 2009.
"Labour Force Participation in the Euro Area: A Cohort Based
Analysis." European Central Bank Working Paper 1049 (May).
Bengali, Leila, Mary Daly, and Rob Valletta. 2013. "Will Labor
Force Participation Bounce Back?" Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco Economic Letter 2013-14 (May).
Canon, Maria E., Marianna Kudlyak, and Peter Debbaut. 2013. "A
Closer Look at the Decline in the Labor Force Participation Rate."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The Regional Economist (October).
Daly, Mary, Early Elias, Bart Hobijn, and Oscar Jorda. 2012.
"Will the Jobless Rate Drop Take a Break?" Federal Reserve
Bank of San Prancisco Economic Letter 2012-37 (December).
Elsby, Michael W. L., Bart Hobijn, and Ay[section]egill Sa,hin.
2013. "On the Importance of the Participation Margin for Labor
Market Fluctuations." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working
Paper 2013-05 (February).
Erceg, Christopher J., and Andrew T. Levin. 2013. "Labor Force
Participation and Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Great
Recession." Mimeo.
FaHick, Bruce, and Jonathan Pingle. 2006. "A Cohort-Based
Model of Labor Force Participation." Federal Reserve Board of
Governors Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2007-09 (December).
Content not available due to copyright restrictions.
Shirner, Robert. 2013. "Job Search, Labor Force Participation,
and Wage Rigidities." In Advances in Economics and Econometrics:
Theory and Applications, Tenth World Congress, Vol. II, Chapter 5,
edited by Daron Acemoglu, Manuel Arenano, and Eddie Dekel. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 197-235.
Toossi, Mitra. 2012a. "Labor Force Projections to 2020: A More
Slowly Growing Workforce." Monthly Labor Review 135 (January):
43-64.
Toossi, Mitra. 2012b. "Projections of the Labor Force to 2050:
A Visual Essay." Monthly Labor Review 135 (October): 3-16.
Veracierto, Marcelo. 2008. "On the Cyclical Behavior of
Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation." Journal of
Monetary Economics 55 (September): 1,143-57.
(1.) The data reported in the article are from HAVER (SA), unless
stated otherwise. The last data point at the time of the analysis:
December 2012.
(4.) The estimates are available from the author.
(5.) The result with restrictions is available from the author.
This result motivates estimation of the benchmark model (i.e., using the
197&2007 data) without restrictions on cohorts.