A cohort model of labor force participation.
Kudlyak, Marianna
The aggregate labor force participation (LFP) rate measures the
share of the civilian noninstitutionalized population who are either
employed or unemployed (i.e., actively searching for work). From 1963 to
2000, the LFP rate was rising, reaching its peak at 67.1 percent. The
LFP rate has been declining ever since, with the decline accelerating
after 2007. Between December 2007 and December 2012, the LFP rate
declined from 66 percent to 63.6 percent. Prior to 2012, the last year
when the LFP rate was below 65 percent was 1986.
The decline in the LFP rate, which coincided with the Great
Recession, raises the question: Is the LFP rate at the end of 2012 close
to or below its long-run trend? The question is important to
policymakers and economists. If a large portion of the workers who are
currently out of the labor force represents workers who are temporarily
out of the labor force, then the unemployment rate by itself might not
be a good measure of the slack in the economy.
In this article, we discuss the change in the aggregate LFP rate
from 2000 to 2012, with an emphasis on the changes in the age-gender
composition of the population and changes in the LFP rates of different
demographic groups. We then estimate a cohort-based model of the LFP
rates of different age-gender groups and construct the aggregate LFP
rate using the model estimates. The model is a parsimonious version of
the model studied in Aaronson et al. (2006). It contains age-gender
effects, birth-year cohort effects, and the estimated deviations of
employment from its long-run trend as the cyclical indicator. We
estimate the model on the 1976-2007 data and then predict the aggregate
LFP rate for 2008-12.
We find that in 2008-11, the actual LFP rate closely follows the
LFP rate predicted from the model that takes into account the estimated
cyclical deviation of employment from its trend. In 2012, the actual LFP
rate is in fact above the estimated value from the model. The actual LFP
rate in 2012 is close to the estimated trend constructed from the actual
age-gender composition of the population and the age-gender and cohort
effects estimated from the model.
What are the factors behind the LFP rate in 2012 being above the
value predicted from the model with the cyclical indicator? In the
model, we use estimated deviations of employment from its long-run trend
as a cyclical indicator. While it is true that the decline in employment
during the Great Recession contributed to lowering labor force
participation in 2008-12, it also appears that other factors during the
2007-09 recession worked to counteract this effect in 2012. Our model is
silent about these factors. One can speculate that the increase in the
duration of unemployment insurance benefits, or the decline in household
wealth (due to the collapse of stock and housing markets), might have
contributed to workers remaining in the labor force at a larger rate
than predicted by the cyclical component of employment.
This article is related to an active debate in the recent academic
and policy circles. The theoretical models are studied in Veracierto
(2008), Krusell et al. (2012), and Shimer (2013). The empirical
discussions are provided in Kudlyak, Lubik, and Tompkins (2011);
Aaronson, Davis, and Hu (2012); Daly et al. (2012); Hotchkiss, Pitts,
and Rios-Avila (2012); Canon, Kudlyak, and Debbaut (2013); and
Schweitzer and Tasci (2013). The cohort model employed in the modeling
labor force participation rate was originally proposed by Aaronson et
al. (2006). Fallick and Pingle (2006) and Balleer, Gomez-Salvador, and
Turunen (2009) provide extensions to the model.
The findings in the article are consistent with the findings in
Aaronson et al. (2006), whose 2006 projection of the LFP rate in 2012 is
63.7 percent, the number that coincides with the actual rate in 2012.
Other studies find that the LFP rate in 2012 is below its trend
(Aaronson, Davis, and Hu [2012]; Bengali, Daly, and Valletta [2013];
Erceg and Levin [2013]; Hotchkiss and Rios-Avila [2013]).
The rest of the article is structured as follows. The first section
reviews the behavior of the aggregate LFP rate during 2000-12 and
presents counterfactual exercises using an age-gender decomposition of
the aggregate LFP rate. Section 2 describes the cohort model and
presents the empirical results. Section 3 concludes.
1. WHAT COMPONENTS DRIVE THE CHANGES IN THE AGGREGATE LFP RATE
DURING 2000--12?
After reaching its peak of 67.3 percent in the first half of 2000,
the aggregate LFP rate declined from 2000 to Q2:2004, stabilized for a
few years, and then started falling again in 2008. (1) Figure 1 shows
the aggregate LFP rate and the aggregate unemployment rate.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The aggregate LFP rate can be decomposed into the weighted sum of
the LFP rates of different demographic groups i.e.,
[LEP.sub.t] = [summation over (i)]
[s.sub.t.sup.i][LFP.sub.t.sup.i], (1)
where [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] is the labor force participation rate of
group i, [s.sub.t.sup.i] is the population share of group i, i.e.,
[s.sub.t.sup.i] [equivalent to] [Pop.sub.t.sup.i]/[Pop.sub.t], and
[Pop.sub.t.sup.i] is the population of group i.
To understand what forces drove the decline of the LFP rate since
2008, we first examine the change in the demographic composition of the
population and the change in. the LFP rates of different age-gender
groups. Figure 2 shows the population shares by age-gender group.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 3 shows the LFP rates of different age-gender groups. As can
be seen from the figures, the developments that took place between
Q4:2007 and Q4:2012 are a continuation of the developments that have
been taking place since 2000, when the aggregate LFP rate reached its
peak: (2)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
* The composition of the population has been shifting toward older
workers who typically have lower labor force attachment. This is in part
due to the population of baby boomers gradually moving from the prime
working age group with a high LFP rate to older age groups with lower
LFP rates. Also note that the share of older women is larger than the
share of older men, and women typically have lower labor force
attachment than men.
* The LFP rate of 25- to 54-year-old workers, a group with the
highest LFP rate, has been declining. From Q4:2007 to Q4:2012, the rate
declined from 82.9 percent to 81.3 percent.
* The LFP rate of teenagers and young adults has been declining.
* The LFP rate of women has started to decline after increasing
prior to 1999.
* The LFP rate of men has continued its decline which started in
the 1940s.
How Much Change Is Driven by the LFP Rates of Different Demographic
Groups?
To understand the importance of the compositional changes and of
the changes in the labor force participation rates of different
demographic groups, we first present counterfactual exercises to
quantify the impact of these changes on the aggregate labor force
participation rate.
In the exercises, we keep the LFP rate of specific demogTaphic
groups fixed at their Q4:2007 level and allow the LFP rates of all other
groups and the demographic composition of the population to follow their
actual path. We consider four such counterfactual exercises: (1) fixing
the LFP rate of 55+ year-old workers, (2) fixing the LFP rate of 16- to
24-year-old workers, (3) fixing the LFP rate of women, and (4) fixing
the LFP rate of men. These exercises demonstrate the importance of
changes in the LFP rates of different demographic groups for changes in
the aggregate LFP rate. In our fifth counterfactual exercise, we fix the
population shares of age-demographic groups at their Q4:2007 levels and
allow the groups' LFP rates to follow their actual path. The
results of these exercises are shown in Figure 4.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
As can be seen from the figure, the experiment with holding the LFP
rates of 55-64 and 65+ year-old workers fixed (the dashed blue line)
delivers the largest discrepancy between the actual aggregate LFP (the
solid black line) and the counterfactual one. Since the LFP rate of
older workers has increased, the counterfactual rate lies below the
actual LFP rate, and in Q4:2012 stands at 61.7 percent.
The second largest discrepancy (in absolute value) between the
actual aggregate LFP and the counterfactual one is obtained from holding
the population shares fixed at their 2007 levels (the dashed red line).
In this case, the counterfactual LFP rate exceeds the actual one and
stands at almost 65 percent in Q4:2012. We see that between 2007 and
2012 the population composition has shifted toward a composition with
lower labor force attachment.
The results also show that the counterfactual based on the fixed
LFP of 16- to 24-year-old workers (the dashed green line) and the
counterfactual based on the fixed LFP of men (the yellow dashed line)
line up almost perfectly and are both above the actual aggregate LFP
rate.
Finally, the figure shows that the counterfactual LFP rate based on
the fixed LFP by women (the dashed pink line) has declined more than the
one based on the fixed LFP by men (the dashed yellow line), while both
counterfactuals lie above the actual LFP rate.
An Alternative Decomposition of LFP
As an alternative way of gauging how much of the change in the LFP
rate was driven by the change in the population shares of different
demographic groups, we perform the following counterfactual. We fix the
LFP rates of 14 age-gender groups at their respective levels at time to
and construct the counterfactual LFP rate using the actual population
shares of the respective groups, i.e.,[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] In the analysis, we consider the following seven
age groups for each gender: 16-19, 20-24, 25-34, 35-44, 45-54, 55-64,
and 65 and older. The blue lines in Figures 5 and 6 show the
counterfactual LFP for [t.sub.0] equal to Q4:2007 and to equal to
Q4:2000, respectively.
As can be seen from Figure 6, in Q4:2012, the counterfactual LFP
rate constructed from the groups' LFP rates fixed at their levels
in Q4:2000 is 65.5 percent, while from 2000 to 2012 the actual LFP rate
declined from 67 percent to 63.6 percent. The counterfactual LFP rate
constructed from the age-gender LFP rates fixed at their levels in
Q4:2007 is 65 percent, while from 2007 to 2012 the actual LFP rate
declined from 66 percent to 63.6 percent (Figure 5). Thus, the results
suggest that the demographic change of the population is associated with
approximately 40 percent of the decline of the aggregate LFP rate
between 2000 and 2012 and 37 percent of the decline between 2007 and
2012.
For such demographic counterfactuals it is important to consider as
fine a group classification as possible, especially if there are
substantial differences in the LFP rates of workers of different ages
combined into a group. For example, the red lines in Figures 5 and 6
show the counterfactual LFP rate when we consider only six age groups
for each gender (16-19, 20-24, 25-34, 35-44, 45-54, and 55 and older),
i.e., combining ages 55-64 and 65+ into one group, 55+. As can be seen
from the figures, in this case [LFP.sub.t.sup.2000] has declined more
than the counterfactual rate in the seven-age-group exercise (64.4
percent). This is because the share of 55- to 64-year-old workers in the
55+ group, who have much higher labor force attachment than 65+, has
increased between 2000 and 2012 (see Figure 6 for the shares).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The observations above show that the demographic composition of the
population and the changes in the LFP rates of different groups have
played an important role in the change of the aggregate LFP rate. We now
proceed to examine the age-gender and cohort effects in the LFP rates of
different demographic groups on the aggregate LFP rate.
2. A COHORT-BASED MODEL OF LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION
The results in Section 1 show that the time-variation in the LFP
rates of different demographic groups are important for the variation in
the aggregate LFP rate. In this section, we propose a model for the
trend in the LFP rates of different demographic groups. We then estimate
the trend in the aggregate LFP rate using the estimated trends in the
LFP rates of different demographic groups and the actual demographic
composition of the population.
Model
Life-Cycle and Cohort Effects in the LFP Rates of Age-Gender Groups
The LFP rates of different demographic groups reflect life-cycle
and gender effects. In addition to these effects, the year-of-birth
cohort effects can be an important determinant of the labor force
attachment of a demographic group in a particular period. For example,
as noted earlier, the baby boomers typically have higher labor force
attachment. As this cohort ages and moves through the age distribution,
its stronger labor force attachment. carries over to the respective age
group.
We think of the demographic and the cohort effects in the LFP rates
of different demographic groups as the determinants of the long-run
labor force participation trend. To estimate this trend, we specify the
following model: ln [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] = [alpha] + ln [[lapha].sub.i] +
1/n [1996.summation over (b = 1917)] [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.f] ln
[[beta].sub.b.sup.m] + [[epsilon].sub.i,t], (2) where [LEP.sub.t.sup.i]
is the labor force participation rate of age-gender group ai is the
fixed effect of age-gender group i, [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.f] is the dummy
variable that takes value 1 if age-gender group i in period t includes
women born in year b, [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.m] is the dummy variable that
takes value 1 if age-gender group i in period t includes men born in
year b, and n denotes the number of ages in group i. We specify separate
cohort effects for men and women, i.e., [[beta].sub.b.sup.f]
([[beta].sub.b.sup.m]) is the cohort-specific fixed effect of a cohort
of women (men) born in year b. We assume that each cohort has equal
importance in the corresponding age group conditional on the number of
cohorts in the group. For the oldest group, 65+, we set n = 20 (setting
n = 30 does not have a substantial effect on the results). To identify
age-gender and cohort effects, we normalize in [[alpha].sub.1] = 0 and
[[beta].sub.1969.sup.f] = 0. The model is estimated using pooled
quarterly data on the LFP rates of 14 age-gender groups.
The model in equation (2) is a simplified version of a model in
Aaronson et al. (2006). Using the estimates from equation (2), we obtain
the time series of in [LFP.sub.t.sup.i] for the 14 age-gender groups,
[[^.LFP].sub.t.sup.i], and calculate [^.[LFP.sub.t.sup.i]] = exp (in
[[^.LFP].sub.t.sup.i] + [[sigma].sub.[epsilon].sup.2]/2), where
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon].sup.2] is the variance of [^.[[epsilon].sub.i,t]]
We then construct the estimated aggregate LFP rate as [[^.LFP].sub.t] =
[summation over (i)] [s.sub.t.sup.i] [[^.LFP].sub.t.sup.i] (3) where
[s.sub.t.sup.i] denotes the actual population share of group i in
quarter t. Thus, the population shares capture the effect of the change
in the demographic composition of the labor force, while
[[^.LFP].sub.t.sup.i] reflects the age-gender and cohort effects of the
different demographic groups. We refer to [[LFP].sub.t] from model (2)
as the estimated trend in the aggregate LFP rate.
Life-Cycle, Cohort, and Cyclical Effects
To further understand the behavior of the aggregate LFP rate, we
also estimate a model similar to the one in equation (2) with a cyclical
indicator. The cyclical indicator is the percentage deviation of
employment from its trend. The idea behind the indicator is that when
the labor market is weak, the labor force participation declines. (3)
The cohort model with the cyclical indicator is ln
[LFP.sub.t.sup.i] = [alpha] + ln [[alpha].sub.i] + 1/n [1996.summation
over (b = 1917)] [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.f] ln [[beta].sub.b.sup.f] + 1/n
[1996.summation over (b = 1917)] [C.sub.b,i,t.sup.m] ln
[[beta].sub.b.sup.m] ln [[beta].sub.b.sup.m] + [14.summation over (g =
1)] I(i = g) (d ln [E.sub.t] ln [[gamma].sub.g.sup.0] + d ln [E.sub.t-1]
ln [[gamma].sub.g.sup.1] + d ln [E.sub.t-2] ln [[gamma].sub.g.sup.2]) +
[[epsilon].sub.i,t,] (4) where I(*) is the indicator function, and din
[E.sub.t] is the percentage deviation of the employment series from its
Hodrick-Prescott (HP)-filtered trend with a smoothing parameter [lambda]
= [10.sup.5] applied to the quarterly data.
In the estimation, we use the contemporaneous percentage deviation
from employment as well as the first and second lag of the deviation.
Note that we allow the cyclical effects to vary by demographic group i.
Because of the end-of-sample issues associated with HP-filtering the
series, we experiment with using a counterfactual cyclical series, [~.d
ln [E.sub.t]], obtained by calculating the deviations from the
employment series simulated to grow at the 2 percent year-over-year
quarterly rate after Q4:2012. While the cyclical components from the
actual and simulated employment series differ after 2009, the
model-based aggregate LFP rates from the two alternative series are very
similar.
The model is estimated on quarterly data. After estimating equation
(4), we construct the aggregate LFP rate as described in equation (3).
The error term in equation (4), [[epsilon].sub.i,t], captures the
residual between the actual LFP rate of group i in period t and the one
explained by the historical relationship between age-gender, cohort, and
cyclical effects and the LFP rates by group. Thus, the residual captures
two main effects. First, it captures the factors that affect the LFP of
group i that are not modeled explicitly in equation (4). These include
some structural factors (for example, changes in taxes or disability
benefits) and some cyclical factors that are not fully captured by the
changes in aggregate employment (for example, changes in the duration of
unemployment benefits, house prices, and stock prices). Second, the
residual captures potential changes in individuals' behavior (i.e.,
changes in responses of the LFP rates to different structural and
cyclical factors).
Empirical Results
One way to obtain the predictions from the models described in
equations (2) and (4) is to estimate the models using the 1976-2012
data, obtain the trend in the aggregate LFP rate (from equation [3]) and
the model-predicted aggregate LFP rate from the model with a cyclical
indicator, and compare the estimates with the actual LFP rate during
2008-12. Another way is to estimate the model on. the 1976-2007 data and
then use the estimates together with the assumptions on cohort effects
and predict the aggregate LFP rate for 2008-12. The cohort model is
sensitive to which approach is used.
One of the concerns associated with cohort models is the
end-of-the-sample effect. In particular, the young cohorts observed in
the 1976-2012 sample (i.e., those born in 1985-1996) are observed only
during the period of the declining aggregate LFP rate. Thus, the model
identifies these cohorts' propensity to participate from the period
of overall low participation, attributing low LFP to these young cohorts
rather than to the model's residual. Given the severity and the
length of the Great Recession, the effects of the cohorts born prior to
1985 are also, to a large extent, identified from their labor force
participation rates during 2008-2012, the period of the overall low LFP.
This is the case for cohorts for which, for example, at least half of
the observations come from the 2008-12 period.
To avoid the end-of-sample effect on the estimates, we estimate the
models in equations (2) and (4) using the data from 1976-2007. To
construct the prediction of the aggregate LFP rate for 2008-12, we
assign, for cohorts born after 1991, the average cohort effect of the
last 20 cohorts. Figure 7 shows the following series: (1) the actual
aggregate LFP rate, (2) the LFP rate constructed from the model with
only age-gender effects, (3) the LFP rate constructed from the model
with age-gender and cohort effects estimated on 1976-2007 data, and (4)
the LFP rate constructed from the model with age-gender, cohort, and
cyclical effects estimated on 1976-2007 data. (4)
As can be seen from the figure, the aggregate LFP rate estimated
from the model with only age-gender and cohort effects on the 19762007
sample exceeds the actual aggregate LFP rate after 2008, and the two
lines coincide at the end of 2012. This measure constitutes our
preferred measure of the trend in the LFP rate. The aggregate LFP rate
estimated from the model with age-gender, cohort, and cyclical
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED] effects on the 1976-2007 data closely tracks the
actual aggregate LFP rate during 2008-11 and is slightly below it in the
last quarter of 2012.
For comparison, Figure 7 also shows the aggregate LFP rate
estimated from. the models using the 1976-2012 data. As can be seen from
the figure, during 2008-12, the aggregate LFP rate predicted from the
model estimated using the 1976-2007 data exceeds the aggregate LFP rate
predicted from the model estimated using the 1976-2012 data. This is
true for the predictions from the model with age-gender and cohort
effects and for the predictions from the model with age-gender, cohort,
and cyclical effects. It appears that the model estimated using the
1976-2012 data attributes the cyclical effects of the 2008-12 period to
cohort effects. To minimize the end-of-sample effect, we also estimated
the models employing a restriction on cohorts as described in Aaronson
et al. (2006). In particular, we constrain the evolution of the fixed
effects for consecutive pairs of the cohorts born in 1985-96 so that the
difference in the average propensity to participate between one cohort
and the next is the same as for a set of cohorts observed over the last
full business cycle. The aggregate LFP rate based on the models with
restricted and unrestricted cohorts are similar, so the figure shows
only the results without restrictions. (5)
Discussion
In the model, the cohort effect stands for an average effect of all
non-modeled factors (beyond life-cycle, gender, and cyclical effects)
that affect the labor force participation of a cohort (i.e., the workers
born in a particular year) throughout the period the cohort is observed
in the sample. These factors can include both structural and cyclical
variables. For example, the availability of and the rules that govern
Social Security benefits and disability insurance might influence the
decision to look for work versus drop out of the labor force. The wage
premium from higher educational attainment might influence the decision
of younger workers to go to school rather than participate in the labor
force. The availability and cost of child care can influence the
decision of mothers to join the labor force.
Consequently, the cohort effects constitute a black box that
aggregates these influences and serve as a useful device for accounting
exercises. The cohort model, however, might not be the best laboratory
for long-term forecasts. In our estimation, we recognize explicitly that
the effect of young cohorts is to a large degree identified from the few
years during which we observe these cohorts in the data. In particular,
for the youngest cohorts, a low cohort effect can be due to the true low
propensity of these cohorts to participate or due to the model
attributing low cyclical LFP to the cohort effect. In our exercise, we
control for these effects. A forecasting exercise would inevitably
involve assumptions about the cohort effects going forward. It is
possible that, for example, the youngest cohorts who are not
participating currently due to schooling will, in fact, increase their
LFP as they grow older. The cohort model does not provide information to
support or reject such scenarios.
3. CONCLUSION
We find that in the aftermath of the Great Recession, the aggregate
LFP rate closely tracks the one predicted by the historical relationship
between the changes in employment and the labor force participation
rates of different age-gender groups in a cohort-based model. In 2012,
the actual LFP rate is slightly higher than the one predicted by the
model. In 2009-11, the trend component of the labor force participation
rate, which is based entirely on the life-cycle and cohort effects of
the LFP rates of different age-gender groups and the actual age-gender
composition of the population, exceeds the actual LFP rate.
The result that the LFP rate in 2012 is above the level that is
predicted by the historical relationship between labor force
participation and the cyclical indicator is consistent with the recent
findings by Hotchkiss and Rios-Avila (2013), who provide direct evidence
that some changes in behavior took place. (6) What other factors could
have contributed to the estimated deviation of the actual LFP rate from
its model-based prediction? We speculate that the Great Recession was
characterized by unusually wild swings in some economic indicators that
could have affected labor force participation. First, the unemployment
benefits in some states were extended to unusually high levels. The
benefits extension might have kept some workers in the labor force for
up to two years to enable them to collect benefits rather than dropping
out of the labor force. In particular, Farber and Valletta (2013) find
that the effect of the unemployment insurance extensions on unemployment
exits and duration is primarily due to a reduction in exits from the
labor force. (7) Second, the collapse of the stock market led to a
decline in retirement savings, which might have led older workers to
stay in the labor force longer. Third, the collapse of the housing
market lowered the ability of households to borrow against their home
equity, which also might have caused individuals to join and/or remain
in the labor force at higher rates than historically predicted by age,
gender, cohort, and cyclical employment effects. Finally, to understand
the behavior of labor force participation and its trend, more research
is needed that would explicitly model and account for the factors that
influence the labor force participation decision of different
demographic groups.
REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Jonathan Davis, and Luojia Hu. 2012.
"Explaining the Decline in the U.S. Labor Force Participation
Rate." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Chicago Fed Letter no. 296
(March).
Aaronson, Stephanie, Bruce Fallick, Andrew Figura, Jonathan Pingle,
and William Wascher. 2006. "The Recent Decline in the Labor Force
Participation Rate and Its Implications for Potential Labor
Supply." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 37 (Spring): 69-134.
Balleer, Almut, Ramon Gomez-Salvador, and Jarkko Turunen. 2009.
"Labour Force Participation in the Euro Area: A Cohort Based
Analysis." European Central Bank Working Paper 1049 (May).
Bengali, Leila, Mary Daly, and Rob Valletta. 2013. "Will Labor
Force Participation Bounce Back?" Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco Economic Letter 2013-14 (May).
Canon, Maria E., Marianna Kudlyak, and Peter Debbaut. 2013. "A
Closer Look at the Decline in the Labor Force Participation Rate."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis The Regional Economist (October).
Daly, Mary, Early Elia.s, Bart Hobijn, and Oscar Jorda. 2012.
"Will the Jobless Rate Drop Take a Break?" Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter 2012-37 (December).
Elsby, Michael W. L., Bart Hobijn, and Amegill Sahin. 2013.
"On the Importance of the Participation Margin for Labor Market
Fluctuations." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper
2013-05 (February).
Erceg, Christopher J., and Andrew T. Levin. 2013. "Labor Force
Participation and Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Great
Recession." Mimeo.
Fallick, Bruce, and Jonathan Pingle. 2006. "A Cohort-Based
Model of Labor Force Participation." Federal Reserve Board of
Governors Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2007-09 (December).
Farber, Henry S., and Robert G. Valletta. 2013. "Do Extended
Unemployment Benefits Lengthen Unemployment Spells? Evidence from Recent
Cycles in the U.S. Labor Market." Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco Working Paper 13-09 (April).
Fujita, Shigeru. 2010. "Economic Effects of the Unemployment
Insurance Benefit." Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review Q4:20-7.
Fujita, Shigeru. 2011. "Effects of Extended Unemployment
Insurance Benefits: Evidence from the Monthly CPS." Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 10-35/R (January).
Hornstein, Andreas. 2013. "The Cyclicality of the Labor Force
Participation Rate." Mimeo.
Hotchkiss, Julie L., M. Melinda Pitts, and Fernando Rios-Avila.
2012. "A Closer Look at Nonparticipants During and After the Great
Recession." Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 2012-10
(August).
Hotchkiss, Julie L., and Fernando Rios-Avila. 2013.
"Identifying Factors Behind the Decline in the U.S. Labor Force
Participation Rate." Business and Economic Research 3 (March):
257-75.
Krusell, Per, Toshihiko Mukoyama, Richard Rogerson, and Amegtil
Sahin. 2012. "Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle."
Mimeo (December).
Kudlyak, Marianna, Thomas Lubik, and Jonathan Tompkins. 2011.
"Accounting for the Non-Employment of U.S. Men, 1968-2010."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 97 (4):359-87.
Kudlyak, Marianna, and Felipe Schwartzman. 2012. "Accounting
for Unemployment in the Great Recession: Nonparticipation Matters."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 12-04 (June).
Rothstein, Jesse. 2011. "Unemployment Insurance and Job Search
in the Great Recession." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 43
(Fall): 143-213.
Schweitzer, Mark E., and Murat Tasci. 2013. "What Constitutes
Substantial Employment Gains in Today's Labor Market?" Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary 2013-07 (June 7).
Shimer, Robert. 2013. "Job Search, Labor Force Participation,
and Wage Rigidities." In Advances in Economics and Econometrics:
Theory and Applications, Tenth World Congress, Vol. II, Chapter 5,
edited by Daron Acemoglu, Manuel Arellano, and Eddie Dekel. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 197-235.
Toossi, Mitra. 2012a. "Labor Force Projections to 2020: A More
Slowly Growing Workforce." Monthly Labor Review 135 (January):
43-64.
Toossi, Mitra. 2012b. "Projections of the Labor Force to 2050:
A Visual Essay." Monthly Labor Review 135 (October): 3-16.
Veracierto, Marcelo. 2008. "On the Cyclical. Behavior of
Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation." Journal of
Monetary Economics 55 (September): 1,143-57.
(1.) The data reported in the article are from HAVER. (SA), unless
stated otherwise. The last data point at the time of the analysis:
December 2012.
(2.) See Toossi (2012a. 2012b) for a description of the trends and
Canon. Kudlyak, and Debbaut (2013) for a summary of the Bureau of Labor
Siatistics projections.
(3.) See recent evidence in Hotchkiss. Pitts, and Rios-Avila
(2012); Kudlyak and Schwartzman (2012); Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin (2013);
and Hornstein (2013).
(4.) I The estimates are available from the author.
(5.) The result with restrictions is available from the author.
This result motivates estimation of tho benchmark model (i.e., using the
1976-2007 data) without restrictions on cohorts.
(6.) In particular. Hotchkiss and Rios-Avila (2013) use microdata
from the Current Population Survey and estimate the probability of an
individual participating in the labor force as a function of age.
education, and other socioeconomic and demographic characteristics of
the individual as well the aggregate labor market conditions. They find
that the coefficients on the socioeconomic and demographic
characteristics estimated from the post-2008-09 period differ from the
coefficients estimated from the pre-recession period in such a way as to
increase he aggregate LFP rate.
(7.) See also Fujita (2010, 2011) and Rothstein (2011).
The author is grateful, without implicating them in any way, to Bob
Hetzel, And reas Hornstein, Marios Karabarbounis. Steven Sabol, and Alex
Wolman for Iheir comments. The author thanks Peter Debbaut and Samuel
Marshall for excellent research assistance. The views expressed here are
those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
marianna.kudlyak@rich.frb.org.