首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月26日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:A regional look at the role of house prices and labor market conditions in mortgage default.
  • 作者:Waddell, Sonya Ravindranath ; Davlin, Anne ; Prescott, Edward Simpson
  • 期刊名称:Economic Quarterly
  • 印刷版ISSN:1069-7225
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
  • 摘要:In the past few years, communities across the United States have witnessed unprecedented growth in the number of homeowners facing mortgage foreclosure. In this article, we take a closer look at default rates in the Fifth District. We use a linear fixed effects model to better understand the role of house price movements and local labor market conditions on prime and subprime foreclosure rates in the metropolitan areas of the Fifth Federal Reserve District. (1) We find that our simple model does a remarkable job of capturing variation in foreclosure rates, and suggests that deteriorating labor and housing conditions explain most of the rising default in our region. Prime foreclosure is particularly well explained in our model, mostly because of the elevated importance of labor conditions in explaining prime default. We also study the regional variation in foreclosure rates by taking a closer look at two localities in our district: Prince William County, Virginia, and Charlotte, North Carolina. Through this analysis, it is easy to see how default rates--and changes in default rates--vary among localities despite the common causes of foreclosure that underlie rising rates across our region and our nation.
  • 关键词:Foreclosure;Mortgages

A regional look at the role of house prices and labor market conditions in mortgage default.


Waddell, Sonya Ravindranath ; Davlin, Anne ; Prescott, Edward Simpson 等


In the past few years, communities across the United States have witnessed unprecedented growth in the number of homeowners facing mortgage foreclosure. In this article, we take a closer look at default rates in the Fifth District. We use a linear fixed effects model to better understand the role of house price movements and local labor market conditions on prime and subprime foreclosure rates in the metropolitan areas of the Fifth Federal Reserve District. (1) We find that our simple model does a remarkable job of capturing variation in foreclosure rates, and suggests that deteriorating labor and housing conditions explain most of the rising default in our region. Prime foreclosure is particularly well explained in our model, mostly because of the elevated importance of labor conditions in explaining prime default. We also study the regional variation in foreclosure rates by taking a closer look at two localities in our district: Prince William County, Virginia, and Charlotte, North Carolina. Through this analysis, it is easy to see how default rates--and changes in default rates--vary among localities despite the common causes of foreclosure that underlie rising rates across our region and our nation.

Although our region has not seen the staggering foreclosure rates of areas in states like Florida, Arizona, or California, we have not been immune to the national "crisis" of foreclosure. From 1979-2006, the rate of serious delinquency (2) in the Fifth District averaged 1.9 percent; by the fourth quarter of 2009, 8.7 percent of all mortgages in the Fifth District were seriously delinquent (compared to 9.7 percent in the nation). (3) Within the Fifth District, conditions vary significantly among states and localities. At the state level, the District of Columbia, Maryland, and Virginia default rates started to rise steeply along with the national rate in 2007, while North and South Carolina default rates lagged about one year. Within states, foreclosure rates are considerably higher, for example, in the Washington, D.C., metropolitan statistical area (MSA) and certain coastal zones in Virginia, North Carolina, and South Carolina, while other localities have maintained consistently lower rates of default.

Theoretical and empirical research has found that house price movements and local economic conditions (in addition to underwriting standards and certain borrower characteristics) affect foreclosure rates in significant ways. There is reason to believe, however, that the causes of foreclosure are different across states and regions. Some areas of the Fifth District--the Washington, D.C., metropolitan area, for example--experienced a boom and bust in house prices that was even greater than that of the nation as a whole. Other areas, like much of North and South Carolina, experienced considerably more muted house price movements. Conversely, Maryland and Virginia labor markets maintained low and relatively steady unemployment rates compared to other parts of the country while the unemployment rates in North and South Carolina have been some of the highest in the nation in recent years.

In addition, although the national rise in foreclosure was initially concentrated in riskier, subprime loans, defaults have become increasingly common among prime borrowers. In the fourth quarter of 2007, 37 percent of all U.S. mortgages in foreclosure were prime loans. That number jumped to 54 percent by the fourth quarter of 2009 and has since increased further. In the Fifth District, prime foreclosures made up 52 percent of the foreclosure inventory by the end of 2009. Although earlier research has examined the factors that lead to subprime default, few have looked carefully at how prime default might differ.

The article is organized as follows. Section 1 provides a brief review of the literature on the theory and empirics of mortgage default. Section 2 describes the data, presents the model, and offers the results of the model. Section 3 examines the fit of the model and its effectiveness at predicting foreclosure rates for certain metro areas. Section 4 presents a more detailed discussion of dynamics in two interesting, and very different, areas in our district: a particularly high foreclosure area of the Washington, D.C., MSA--Prince William County, Va.--and Charlotte, N.C. Section 5 concludes.

This analysis offers a model that captures most of the variation in default rates and provides an in-depth look at some of the variation between localities. In the end, a borrower's decision to default on a home depends not only on national or state conditions, but also on the housing environment of a county, a zip code, or a neighborhood. Therefore, as we move through this crisis, it will be increasingly necessary to examine local dynamics more closely in order to determine the future direction of housing markets.

1. WHAT CAUSES MORTGAGE DEFAULT?

Mortgage valuation and the decision to default are often modeled using option theory. (4) A mortgage default amounts to the borrower effectively "selling" his house to the lender for the current mortgage balance, or exercising his "put" option. The borrower's other choices are to continue to make the scheduled payments through the life of the loan or to prepay the mortgage (the "call" option) either by selling the house or by refinancing into a new loan. The simplest of the option-theoretic mortgage pricing models (e.g., models that don't account for the cost of default to the borrower) predict that the borrower will default immediately when the market value of the mortgage equals or exceeds the value of the house, or when the put option is "in the money" -- a condition known as "negative equity." Many models also incorporate the borrower's prepayment option and a borrower's future choices into the default valuation. (Kau, Keenan, and Kim 1994; Deng, Quigley, and Van Order 2000).

Empirical work on mortgage default has found that borrowers do not default immediately when the value of the collateral property falls below the value of the loan. For example, Foster and Van Order (1984) found default probabilities of less than 10 percent using Federal Housing Administration data even when equity was estimated to be quite negative. Using a large data set of conventional loans originated between 1975-1989, Quigley and Van Order (1995) found that at low levels of negative equity, the option to default is not exercised immediately. More recently, Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2008) estimated that of the roughly 100,000 households in Massachusetts who had negative equity during the early 1990s, fewer than 10 percent lost their homes to foreclosure. Elul et al. (2010) find that, although negative equity is an important predictor of mortgage default, a potentially equally important predictor is the liquidity of the household, as measured by credit card utilization.

One rationale for the lower-than-predicted mortgage default rates is the significant transactions costs associated with default, such as moving costs, the cost of purchasing or renting, and higher future borrowing costs that result from a damaged credit score. In addition, the borrower may face psychological and social costs in the face of default that result from the loss of one's home or a social stigma associated with default. Some individuals may also take moral issue with defaulting on their loan when they can make the monthly payment. Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2009) present survey results that show that people who consider default immoral are 77 percent less likely to declare their intention to do so, while people who know someone who defaulted are 82 percent more likely to declare their intention to default. They also find that the social pressure not to default is weakened when homeowners live in areas with a high frequency of foreclosures or know other people who have defaulted strategically. (5) This implies a cohort or contagion effect of foreclosure.

Another line of research has examined not just a borrower's willingness to stay current on a mortgage but her ability to repay the loan. Crews Cutts and Merrill (2008) find that for conforming, conventional loans, the primary reasons for default given by borrowers are loss of income, financial distress other than loss of income, death or illness in the family, and marital problems. Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2008) provide evidence that, although negative equity is a necessary condition for default--positive equity enables the borrower to sell the house, pay off the mortgage, and keep the difference--it is not a sufficient condition. They illustrate theoretically and empirically that most defaults begin with a trigger event, such as illness, loss of job, divorce, or a health shock. (6) In earlier work, Vandell (1995) summarizes the arguments in favor of a trigger event-based theory.

Although Pennington-Cross and Ho (2006) find that borrowers with lower credit scores are more likely to default on a subprime mortgage, Haughwout, Peach, and Tracy (2008) find that the deteriorating economic conditions--particularly falling house prices--contributed more to the rise in subprime and Alt-A default rates than did the changing risk characteristics of nonprime mortgages. Gerardi, Shapiro, and Willen (2009) also find that house prices played the primary role in rising default rates and that subprime mortgages end up in foreclosure more frequently because of their higher sensitivity to falling house prices.

Methodologically, this article most closely follows Doms, Furlong, and Krainer (2007) who model subprime delinquency rates using data on 309 MS As in 2005 and 2006. They find that borrower risk measures are statistically significant in predicting subprime foreclosure rates, but that those factors have little explanatory power. They find, however, that house price and employment variables are both significant and explanatory. The labor market variables account for 30-40 percent of the variance in the default rates--much more than the risk proxies, but less than the house price effect. Another similar article by Amromin and Paulson (2009) uses a maximum likelihood bivariate probit model with state fixed effects to estimate the probability that a borrower will default within a year of loan origination. It is one of the few empirical papers that explains default rates on subprime and prime loans separately. Their findings suggest that, relative to subprime loans, prime defaults have a weaker relationship with home prices, once key borrower and loan characteristics are taken into account.

2. EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION

Data

Our mortgage data comes from Lender Processing Services (LPS) Applied Analytics (formerly McDash). LPS collects the data from nine of the top 10 mortgage servicers in the country. The mortgage types are self-classified by the participating servicers. LPS claims that its data represent nearly 70 percent of the mortgage market--including information on more than 39 million loans. (7) It is important to note that, compared to other data sources, LPS data include a smaller share of the total subprime market. For example, since 2005, the Mortgage Bankers' Association mortgage sample has included between 9.8 and 14.0 percent subprime loans, while over the same period, LPS has reported a subprime share of between 2.5 and 4.7 percent. Our sample uses monthly data from January 2005-September 2009 on all first-lien loans (approximately 2.5 million) for borrowers living in one of 44 MSAs in the Fifth Federal Reserve District. We define the foreclosure rate as the inventory of loans in foreclosure divided by the total inventory of loans in a given time period. The data is aggregated by MSA and quarter.

For house price data, we use the metropolitan area Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) house price indexes and unemployment/payroll employment data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). The MSAs in our sample are listed in Appendix A. All data spans from the first quarter of 2005 through the third quarter of 2009.

Table 1 summarizes our house price, borrower pool, and labor market variables over the period and Figures 1-3 provide more detail on the relationship between our independent variables and prirne/subprime foreclosure.
Table 1 Summary Statistics of Key Variables

 Number Prime Subprime Percent Percent
 of Foreclosure Foreclosure Subprime Interest-Only
 Loans Rate (%) Rate (%) (%) (%)

2005
 Mean 51,807 0.44 2.18 3.59 2.26
 Std. Dev. 0.32 1.50 1.48 1.86

2006
 Mean 55.803 0.42 2.42 4.23 3.67
 Std. Dev. 0.28 1.54 1.62 2.99

2007
 Mean 60,610 0.45 3.38 4.74 4.56
 Std. Dev. 0.25 1.94 1.68 3.67

2008
 Mean 63,853 0.64 5.12 3.98 4.33
 Std. Dev. 0.30 2.09 1.45 3.59

2009 *
 Mean 63,369 1.12 7.32 3.41 3.84
 Std. Dev. 0.50 2.69 1.29 3.25

 Two-Year Unemployment YoY
 Change Rate Employment
 in
 HPI (%) (%) Growth (%)

2005
 Mean 17.46 5.26 1.47
 Std. Dev. 13.45 1.46 1.74

2006
 Mean 19.10 4.73 1.89
 Std. Dev. 12.42 1.33 2.24

2007
 Mean 13.20 4.50 1.58
 Std. Dev. 7.30 1.11 1.96

2008
 Mean 5.49 5.62 -0.19
 Std. Dev. 6.19 1.59 1.94

2009 *
 Mean -0.05 9.43 -2.75
 Std. Dev. 6.51 2.28 1.90

Notes: Means are averages across quarters and metro areas;
* = through September.


As discussed in Section 1, as house prices fall, borrowers are more likely to face negative equity, which increases the likelihood of foreclosure. Figures lA and 1B illustrate the relationship between the preceding two-year change in house prices and the subprime and prime foreclosure rates, respectively, in our sample. Both figures indicate a negative relationship between the variables, but also indicate a nonlinearity in the relationship that begins to take shape when house price growth is zero percent. As home values appreciate, foreclosure rates fall, but by the time house price growth is around 10 or 15 percent, the effect on foreclosure dies out. In other words, the lower bound on foreclosure rates is above zero (some homeowners will default), no matter how much home values appreciate. We hypothesize that this nonzero bound in foreclosure results from non-uniformity in house price movements among neighborhoods and houses--ultimately, the selling price of a house has not only to do with overall demand for houses, but also the characteristics of the neighborhood and the house. In other words, individuals can see the value of their house fall even in an expanding housing market. Therefore, it is not surprising to see some nonzero level of default no matter the growth in house prices at the MSA level.

A further hypothesized relationship between foreclosure rates and house prices has to do with the volatility of house prices. If housing values are more volatile, that increases the likelihood that default is "in the money," in the language of the option theory literature. This indicates that more volatile house prices should be associated with a greater incidence of default (Elul 2006, Kau and Keenan 1999). However, we did not find a strong relationship between the volatility of house prices and either prime or subprime foreclosure rates.

As discussed in Section 1, the early part of the last decade saw a proliferation of nontraditional loan products, such as the interest-only (I/O) loan. I/O loans are loans for which the borrower starts off paying only the interest portion of the mortgage payment and at some specified "recast" date, the borrower starts to pay the principal as well. At the recast date, a borrower's monthly payment increases, sometimes considerably. Although I/O loans were not a large share of the mortgage market in many areas of the Fifth District, there were pockets of high I/O lending, such as Washington, D.C., and Charleston, S.C., particularly in 2006 and 2007. For example, at the inventory peak in the third quarter of 2007, I/O loans accounted for 17.7 percent of all loans in the Washington, D.C., MSA, 13.1 percent of all loans in the Charleston, S.C., MSA, and 12.9 percent of all loans in the Winchester, Va., MSA. In the LPS data set, I/O loans are almost entirely classified as prime loans. (8) It is likely that at least some share of the rise in prime foreclosure in our district metro areas is the result of an increase in foreclosure among these I/O loans.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The role of I/O loans will also be discussed in more detail in the Section 4 discussion of Prince William County, Va.

Finally, we examine the role of local economic factors in rising foreclosure rates. In line with Doms, Furlong, and Krainer (2007) among others, we use the unemployment rate and employment growth rates at the MSA level to proxy for local economic conditions. An increase in the unemployment rate translates to more households with an unexpected income shock--a "trigger event" discussed in Section 1. We hypothesize a six-month lag between a change in the unemployment rate and a change in the foreclosure rate. Figures 2 and 3 summarize the relationship between foreclosure rates and our employment variables.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

We might expect rises in unemployment to affect subprime borrowers more than prime borrowers because the former are likely to be more vulnerable to income or liquidity shocks that damage their ability to pay a mortgage. However, correlation coefficients between the foreclosure rates and unemployment six months previous indicate a stronger relationship between unemployment and prime default (correlation of 0.69) than between unemployment and subprime default (correlation of 0.53).

In addition, higher unemployment can increase foreclosure through house prices. If unemployment starts to rise in an area, people will move to seek new jobs. This is likely to dampen the demand for homes. Thus, deteriorating labor markets could increase foreclosure rates both as a trigger event and through the subsequent decline in house prices because of a reduced demand for homes. In our sample, the correlation between the change in the unemployment rate and the change in house prices is about 0.55.

The Model

Given the regional nature of housing markets, using pooled ordinary least squares to estimate foreclosure rates will allow static differences among metropolitan areas to introduce bias into our parameter estimates. Indeed, statistical tests indicate heterogeneity among MS As in our sample. Furthermore, when we estimated a simple linear regression model we found, for example, that including or excluding the Washington, D.C., MSA changed both the parameter estimates and the power of our different independent variables to explain the variance in foreclosure rates. The implications of Washington, D.C.'s influence in our estimation are two-fold: First, it indicates the need to recognize--and control for--differences among our MSAs. Second, it potentially brings into question the extent to which the previous default analysis in the boom/bust areas of our nation can be applied to the non-boom/bust areas in the rest of the country.

To control for the time invariant MSA characteristics that could bias our results, we engage the linear fixed effects model defined in equations (1) and (2) for subprime and prime foreclosure rates, respectively:

[f.sub.it.sup.s] = [[beta].sub.0i] + [[beta].sub.1] [DELTA] [E.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.2] [DELTA] [R.sub.it - 6] + [[beta].sub.3] [DELTA] [S.sub.it - 12] + [[beta].sub.4] [DELTA] [H.sub.it] * [delata.sub.it.sup.+] + [[beta].sub.5] [DELTA] [H.sub.it] * [delata.sub.it.sup.-] + [e.sub.it], (1)

[f.sub.it.sup.p] = [[beta].sub.0i] + [[beta].sub.1] [DELTA] [E.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.2] [DELTA] [R.sub.it - 6] + [[beta].sub.3] [DELTA] [S.sub.it - 12] + [[beta].sub.4] [DELTA] [I.sub.it - 12] + [[beta].sub.5] [DELTA] [H.sub.it] * [delata.sub.it.sup.+] + [[beta].sub.6] [DELTA] [H.sub.it] * [delata.sub.it.sup.-] + [e.sub.it], (2)

The subscripts i and t refer to MSA and month, respectively. The variables are defined as follows:

[f.sup.s] = subprime foreclosure rate,

[f.sup.p] = prime foreclosure rate,

[DELTA] E = change in payroll employment over the preceding year,

R = unemployment rate,

S = share of the loan pool that is subprime,

I = share of the prime loan pool that is interest-only,

[DELTA] H = change in house prices over the preceding two years,

[delta.sub.it.sup.+] = 1 if [DELTA] [H.sub.it] [greater than or equal to] 0, 0 otherwise,

[delta.sub.it.sup.-] = 1 if [DELTA] [H.sub.it] < 0, 0 otherwise.

The difference between the fixed effects model and the standard ordinary least squares model lies in the constant term [[beta].sub.0i] that can be broken down into two components: [[beta].sub.0i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.0] The [[alpha].sub.0] term is the MSA-specific parameter. Computationally, this model is estimated by transforming (demeaning) the data. Intuitively, the model is equivalent to including a dummy variable for every MSA in our estimation. The variables [delta.sub.it.sup.+] and [delta.sub.it.sup.-] enable the model to account for the nonlinearity in the relationship between house prices and foreclosure rates discussed earlier in the section and illustrated in Figure 1. Through these dummy variables, we separate the effect of a two-year appreciation in home values from a two-year depreciation.

The results are presented in Tables 2A and 2B. (9) The "within [R.sup.2]" statistic measures how well the model explains the variation in the dependent variable within an MSA. The constant term reported in the tables is the [[beta].sub.0] parameter. The subject-specific parameters are reported in Table 3.
Table 3 MSA Fixed Effects

MSA Subprime Prime
 Fixed Fixed
 Effect Effect

Anderson. S.C. 0.0172 0.0040

Asheville, N.C. 0.0031 -0.0003

Augusta-Richmond County, Ga.-S.C. 0.0153 0.0004

Baltimore-Towson, Md. -0.0023 0.0000

Blacksbum-Christiansburs-Radtbrd, -0.0009 -0.0017
Va.

Burlington, N.C. -0.0047 -0.0008

Charleston, W.Va. -0.0024 0.0003

Charleston-North Charleston, S.C. 0.0295 0.0029

Charlotte-Gastonia-Concord, 0.0109 0.0015
N.C.-S.C.

Charlottesville, Va. 0.0040 -0.0002

Columbia, S.C. 0.0328 0.0033

Cumberland, Md.-W.Va. -0.0093 -0.0005

Danville, Va. -0.0387 -0.0052

Durham, N.C. 0.0148 0.0003

Fayetteville, N.C. -0.0084 -0.0007

Florence, S.C 0.0044 -0.0002

Goldsboro, N.C. 0.0004 0.0009

Greensboro-High Point, N.C. -0.0049 -0.0009

Greenville, N.C. -0.0026 -0.0010

Greenville-Mauldin-Easley, S.C. 0.0363 0.0042

Hagerstown-Martinsburg, Md.-W.Va. -0.0086 0.0006

Harrisonburg, Va. 0.0014 -0.0010

Hickory-Lenoir-Morganton, N.C. -0.0189 -0.0026

Huntington-Ashland, -0.0145 -0.0005
W.Va.-Ky.-Ohio

Jacksonville, N.C. 0.0132 0.0014

Kingsport-Bristol-Bristol, -0.0147 -0.0029
Tenn.-Va.

Lynchburg, Va. -0.0034 -0.0006

Morgantown, W.Va. 0.0182 0.0002

Myrtle BeaclvConway-North Myrtle 0.0373 0.0033
Beach, S.C.

Parkersburg-Marietta-Vienna, 0.0051 0.0001
W.Va.-Ohio

Raleigh-Cary, N.C. 0.0153 0.0005

Richmond, Va. -0.0070 -0.0012

Roanoke, Va. -0.0026 -0.0009

Rocky Mount N.C. -0.0349 -0.0025

Salisbury, Md. -0.0050 0.0000

Spartanburg, S.C. 0.0241 0.0037

Sumter, S.C. 0.0157 0.0014

Virginia Beach-Norfolk-Newport -0.0065 -0.0006
News, Va.-N.C.

Washington-Arlington-Alcxandria, -0.0041 0.0009
D.C.-Va.-Md.-W.Va.

Weirton-Steubenville, W.Va.-Ohio -0.0438 -0.0018

Wheeling W.Va. -0.0399 -0.0032

Wilmington, N.C. 0.0035 0.0004

Winchester, Va.-W.Va. -0.0215 -0.0009

Winston-Salem, N.C. -0.0030 0.0001


Both labor market conditions and house price movements are statistically and economically important predictors of foreclosure rates. Using the parameter estimates in Tables 2A and 2B, column (5), a one-percentage-point increase in unemployment rate will increase the subprime foreclosure rate by almost 0.5 percentage point and the prime foreclosure rate by about 0.1 percentage point. For illustrative purposes, we calculate that in the Washington, D.C., MSA, a one-percentage-point increase in the unemployment rate would translate (six months later) into about 100 additional subprime foreclosures and about 775 new prime foreclosures. As another example, the Charlotte MSA would see almost 30 new subprime foreclosures and around 220 new prime foreclosures.
Table 2 MSA Fixed Effects Models of Subprime and Prime Foreclosures

2A: MSA Fixed Effects Models of Subprime Foreclosure

 (1) (2) (3) (4)

Employment -0.473
Growth ***

(One-Year % (0.0622)
Change)

Unemployment 0.356 ***
Rate

(Six-Month Lag) (0.0719)

Percent 0.746 ***
Subprime

(One-Year Lag) (0.184)

House Price -0.141
Growth ***

(Two-Year % (0.0124)
Change)

House Price -0.117
 ***

Growth * (0.0143)
Positive

House Price -0.295
 ***

Growth * (0.0519)
Negative

Constant 0.0230 * 0.0127 0.0556 0.0518
 *** ***
 (0.00385) (0.00767) (0.00144) (0.00177)

Observations 836 660 836 836

Within [R.sup.2] 0.385 0.039 0.501 0.518
(Adj)

2B: MSA Fixed Effects Models of Prime Foreclosure

Employment -0.0546
Growth ***

(One-Year % (0.0103)
Change)

Unemployment 0.108 ***
Rate

(Six-Month (0.0103)
Lag)

Percent -0.107 **
Subprime

(One-Year (0.0386)
Lag)

Percent 0.147 ***
Interest-Only

(One-Year (0.0155)
Lag)

House Price -0.-204
Growth

(Two-Year % (0.00199)
Change)

House Price -0.0130
 ***

Growth * (0.00180)
Positive

House Price -0.0675
 ***

Growth * (0.0 111)
Neeative

Constant 0.000482 0.00512 0.00824 0.00707
 *** *** ***
 (0.000535) (0.00144) (0.000231) (0.000225)

Observations 836 660 836 836

Within 0.513 0.311 0.510 0.593
[R.sup.2]
(Adj)

2A: MSA Fixed Effects Models
of Subprime Foreclosure

 (5)

Employment -0.118
Growth **

(One-Year % (0.0427)
Change)

Unemployment 0.465 ***
Rate

(Six-Month Lag) (0.0660)

Percent 0.705 ***
Subprime

(One-Year Lag) (0.174)

House Price
Growth

(Two-Year %
Change)

House Price -0.0765
 ***

Growth * (0.0147)
Positive

House Price -0.276
 ***

Growth * (0.0416)
Negative

Constant -0.00341
 (0.0102)

Observations 660

Within [R.sup.2] 0.677
(Adj)

2B: MSA Fixed Effects Models
of Prime Foreclosure

Employment -0.0201
Growth **

(One-Year % (0.00604)
Change)

Unemployment 0.0987
Rate ***

(Six-Month (0.00855)
Lag)

Percent 0.0630 **
Subprime

(One-Year (0.0217)
Lag)

Percent -0.0171
Interest-Only

(One-Year (0.0167)
Lag)

House Price
Growth

(Two-Year %
Change)

House Price -0.00899
 **

Growth * (0.00289)
Positive

House Price -0.0580
 ***

Growth * (0.00778)
Neeative

Constant -0.000273
 (0.00)34)

Observations 660

Within 0.797
[R.sup.2]
(Adj)

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** = significant at the
1 percent level, ** = significant at the 5 percent level
* = significant at the 10 percent level.


The effect of house price movements on foreclosure rates in our model is generally in line with the literature. In columns (4) and (5), we specify a piece-wise linear relationship between house prices and foreclosure rates such that the effect of a drop in house prices could be different from the effect of an increase. For illustrative purposes, suppose that house price movements are virtually stagnant and the two-year growth in house prices is slightly below zero, say -- 0.1 percent. Then, suppose that over the subsequent two years, house prices fell 7.4 percent, which amounts to a one standard deviation additional depreciation. (10) According to the coefficient estimates in column (5), this increased depreciation will increase the subprime foreclosure rate by more than two percentage points and increase the prime foreclosure rate by 0.4 percentage point. Alternatively, suppose that initially, the two-year change in house prices is 7.4 percent. Then, over the subsequent two years, house price appreciation falls to 0.1 percent. This decreased appreciation will increase the subprime foreclosure rate by 0.28 percentage point and the prime foreclosure rate by 0.03 percentage point. The result that changes in depreciating house values have a larger effect on foreclosure rates than changes in appreciating values is consistent with the theory that negative equity plays a significant role in the decision to default. (11)

In addition to statistically and economically significant coefficients, the R2 values in the prime and subprime estimations are quite large. This simple model of labor market conditions and house prices explains almost 70 percent of the variation in subprime foreclosure rates and almost 80 percent of the variation in prime foreclosure rates across our region's MS As. In addition, house price conditions alone explain over 50 percent of the variation in subprime and prime foreclosure rates (column [4]). Labor market conditions account for almost 40 percent of the variation (column [1]) in subprime foreclosure rates and over 50 percent of the variation in prime foreclosure rates. These results are somewhat higher, but generally consistent, with existing literature.

The fixed effect is a way to control for any characteristic of an MSA that leads to a permanently higher foreclosure rate in an area. In the pooled ordinary least squares model, we found that a high share of subprime loans does not necessarily engender a higher subprime foreclosure rate. This makes intuitive sense since, for example, many South Carolina metro areas have always had relatively high subprime foreclosure rates, but, particularly in recent years, a low share of subprime loans compared to other markets. However, when we include a fixed effect, we find a statistically significant (and economically significant) relationship between the two variables. The "within" effect of subprime's share of the market on subprime default is statistically more robust than the "between" effect; as the share of subprime within a metro area rises, the subprime foreclosure rate is likely to rise as well. A similar effect was found in the prime estimation.

The MSA fixed effect also influenced the explanatory power of the model. Labor market factors explained more of the variation in foreclosure rates within MSAs than between MSAs while house price movements explained more of the variation between MSAs than within MSAs. More intuitively, a MSA with a higher unemployment rate will not necessarily have a higher foreclosure rate, but as unemployment rates rise, foreclosure rates tend to rise. In addition, although house price declines do lead to higher foreclosure rates within a MSA, it is even more the case that areas with softer housing markets tend to have higher foreclosure rates.

Robustness of the Results

In this model, we examined the role of house price movements and employment on mortgage default, using the inventory of loans in foreclosure as our measure of default. Whether or not a home enters foreclosure, however, also depends on federal and state regulatory systems and the incentives/situation of the mortgage lender. Many states, for example, have declared moratoriums on foreclosure at various points in the past few years. Furthermore, there are stories of borrowers who stopped paying their mortgage months, or even years, before the lender initiated foreclosure proceedings. To ensure the quality of our results, therefore, we ran our model using a metro area's 90-day delinquency rate as the dependent variable. This is in line with much of the existing literature, which models delinquency rates instead of foreclosure rates. Our results held. We found little change in the signs of the coefficients or in their statistical significance and found that the magnitude of every key variable increased for both prime and subprime models. The [R.sup.2] value on the full subprime model rises to 80 percent, and the [R.sup.2] value on the prime model remains at about 80 percent.

In addition to looking at the role of appreciation or depreciation in homes, we also considered including a measure of the volatility of house prices. Option theory suggests that increased house price volatility could lead to increased foreclosure rates. In our estimation, this variable--when measured by the quarterly change in the year-over-year house price growth--does not appear to have a significant effect, on either prime or subprime foreclosure rates, that is robust to even slight changes in the estimation strategy. In other words, the coefficient might have been statistically significant under certain circumstances, but the significance showed little resilience to controlling for more/fewer variables, using robust standard errors, or controlling for MSA fixed effects. (12)

3. WHAT DO THESE RESULTS MEAN?

The fixed effects model does a good job of predicting foreclosure rates in our district. To better understand the implications of the results, we take a closer look at two metro areas in our district: the Washington, D.C., MSA and the Charlotte, N.C., MSA. We choose these two metro areas both because they are driving forces in their respective regions of the Fifth District and because we will explore the Charlotte, N.C., MSA and one county in the Washington, D.C., MSA more closely in the next section. Figures 5 and 6 plot the realized foreclosure rates against the predictions from the fixed effects models for the Washington, D.C., and Charlotte, N.C., metro areas. Our fixed effects model generally overpredicts default rates on both prime and subprime loans in the Washington, D.C., MSA before 2009, but begins to underpredict in 2009. For the Charlotte MSA, our model predicted a much sharper increase in foreclosure rates in the third quarter of 2009 than actually occurred. On the whole, though, the predictive power of the model is quite strong.

Intuitively, it makes sense that our model underpredicts for Washington, D.C., but overpredicts for Charlotte toward the end of 2009. The coefficient on the unemployment variable was estimated based on the effect of unemployment in every Fifth District metro area. But it is possible that borrowers in the Washington, D.C., MSA react more to increases in unemployment than do borrowers in, say, Charlotte, N.C., or Danville, Va. If the trigger event in a soft housing market is the primary mechanism through which unemployment affects foreclosure, then an increase in unemployment would affect borrowers in Washington, D.C., more because of how far house prices have dropped. The third quarter of 2008 marked the largest decline in house prices in the Washington, D.C., MSA. In that quarter, year-over-year house prices fell 13.1 percent. By the third quarter of 2009, house prices fell only 5.6 percent on a year-over-year basis. The third quarter of 2008 is when the model estimates begin to track below actual foreclosure rates. Furthermore, from the third quarter of 2008 to the third quarter of 2009, unemployment in the Washington, D.C., MSA increased from 4.1 percent to 6.3 percent--a sizeable jump, but far smaller than the increase in most of our other sample metro areas. As will be discussed in the next section, the unemployment rate in the Charlotte MSA increased from 6.7 percent to 11.8 percent over the same period. With diminishing house price declines and unemployment rates that rose far less than in other metro areas in our sample (not to mention a falling share of subprime), it makes sense to think that our model would expect foreclosure rates to begin to flatten in Washington, D.C., toward the end of our sample period.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

However, we also underpredict for many of our other Mb As. As house price declines and increases in unemployment diminish, our model predicts the rise in default to moderate more than it did. Figures 4A and 4B offer a summary of how our predictions fared across MSAs. The variable is our predicted foreclosure rate minus the realized rate. A value of zero, then, is a perfect prediction. Although the predicted values bounce around the realized values, we never underpredict subprime foreclosure rates across MS As as notably as we do in 2009.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

Forecasting Foreclosure Rates in Washington, D.C., and Charlotte, N.C.

Figures 5 and 6 offer predictions about the movement of foreclosure in the next few years, given some assumptions about what will happen to payroll employment, unemployment rates, and house prices in Charlotte and Washington, D.C. (13) The assumptions are laid out in Appendix B; in short, we assume that payroll growth and house prices will resume pre-boom trends and that the unemployment rate in each MSA will fall at the same rate that it did coming out of the recession of the early 1990s.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

Given these assumptions, we predict that foreclosure rates in the Charlotte MSA will peak in the fourth quarter of 2010. The results for the Washington, D.C., MSA are more volatile, driven by the predicted path of house prices in that MSA. Nonetheless, our model predicts that foreclosure rates have already peaked (third quarter 2009) in Washington, D.C. One caveat of this prediction is that our model is designed such that as two-year house price growth increases, default rates should fall. In Washington, D.C, two-year house price growth turned negative in the first quarter of 2008. Therefore, in the second quarter of 2010, the typical homeowner will have experienced more than two years of depreciation. This could present a problem in our model. For example, from the third quarter of 2006 through the third quarter of 2008, house prices fell almost 18 percent. From the third quarter of 2008 through the third quarter of 2010, we predict house prices to fall a further 11 percent. Our model suggests that foreclosure rates should be lower in the third quarter of 2010 than in the third quarter of 2008 because the depreciation rate is lower; however, if the negative equity argument is true, then a homeowner is more likely to experience deeper negative equity and therefore more likely to default after four years of depreciation. In other words, our model does not take into account compounding house price declines. Therefore, even if our predictions are accurate and all other assumptions hold, we are likely to underestimate default rates starting in the first quarter of 2010 and, in fact, we do. In the second quarter of 2010, for example, we predict a subprime foreclosure rate of 7.5 percent in Washington, D.C., and a prime foreclosure rate of 1.3 percent, when the actual rates are 9.1 percent and 1.8 percent, respectively. In the Charlotte MSA--where house price declines have been much more moderate--we actually overpredict foreclosure rates. We predict a subprime foreclosure rate of 10.7 percent in the second quarter of 2010 and a prime foreclosure rate of 1.9 percent, while the real rates are 8.8 percent and 1.8 percent, respectively.

The next section offers a more in-depth look at foreclosure rates and the causes of foreclosure in specific areas of our district. Through this next analysis, we offer some local insight that is critical to understanding housing markets and the rising default rates across our district and the nation.

4. A CLOSER LOOK AT HIGH FORECLOSURE AREAS IN OUR DISTRICT

In the previous section, our MSA fixed effect captured the time-invariant, unobservable characteristics of a metro area that could shift its foreclosure rate. Although outside the scope of the model, some of the characteristics that comprise a metro area's fixed effect could interact with other variables to affect the direction and magnitude of foreclosure rate movements. This section takes a closer look at two areas of our district that have seen higher default rates than surrounding areas--Prince William County, Va., and Charlotte, N.C.--and builds a story to better understand the situation in those two areas.

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

Prince William County, Va.

Prince William County, Manassas City, and Manassas Park City are Virginia suburbs in the Washington, D.C., MSA. As we have already briefly discussed, the boom-bust in the Washington, D.C., MSA housing market was considerably sharper than in other areas of our district. The Northern Virginia suburbs of the MSA--and Prince William County (and Manassas) in particular -- experienced stark rises in default rates beginning in 2007. There is no question that in this part of the Fifth District, a large portion of the subprime and prime foreclosure story was the steep rise and subsequent fall in house prices. But as we illustrated in Section 3, there is more to the story than that. This section will shed light on this small part of our district where a large number of borrowers continue to default on their mortgages.

Figure 7 shows the rise in default rates on first-lien loans in Prince William County/Manassas City/Manassas Park City (PWC/Manassas), Northern Virginia not including PWC/Manassas, and Virginia excluding all of Northern Virginia. (14) Clearly, foreclosure rates were considerably higher in PWC/ Manassas than they were even in the rest of Northern Virginia, which itself was one of the highest default areas of our region. By the middle of 2009, the total foreclosure rate had peaked at 3.0 percent in PWC/Manassas, while the peak rates in Northern Virginia and in the rest of Virginia were 1.5 percent and 1.1 percent, respectively. Data on originations by year indicate that the loans originated in PWC/Manassas in 2005, 2006, and 2007 performed the worst of all.

House Price Boom and Bust

As illustrated in Figure 8, house prices in PWC/Manassas tripled from 1997 to the middle of 2005. From 2005 through the third quarter of 2009, however, houses in the area lost half of their value.15 The house price boom and bust in PWC/Manassas is consistent with the experience in the neighboring Fairfax County/Alexandria City/Arlington County area, and in the Washington, D.C., MSA as a whole, but the movements were far more dramatic in PWC/Manassas.16 There can be no question that this was a huge driver of the area's rise in foreclosure rates. Clearly, a number of homeowners in that area must be facing negative equity, especially given the relaxation in underwriting criteria and the rise in junior lien borrowing and cash-out refinancing that characterized the lending environment in the early part of the decade.

Loan Composition and Borrower Characteristics

Subprime borrowers have higher default rates than prime borrowers. Similarly, the default rates among Alt-A mortgages--"near-prime" mortgages made to borrowers with good credit scores but for which there are other risk factors, such as relaxed underwriting, or risky loan characteristics--tend to be higher than those for regular prime mortgages. Here, we look most closely at one kind of Alt-A loan--the interest-only loan--that was described in Section 2 and was particularly prevalent in Northern Virginia generally and PWC/Manassas in particular. (As noted earlier, these I/O loans are primarily categorized as prime loans in the LPS data set.) Here, we evaluate the role of both market loan composition and the quality of the average borrower in PWC/Manassas in the rising foreclosure rate.

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

Looking at borrower characteristics, the LPS data indicate that PWC/ Manassas did not have lending standards that differed notably from the rest of the state. Loan-to-value ratios and FTCO scores in PWC/Manassas were both steady and comparable to the rest of Virginia throughout the decade. On the other hand, as illustrated in Figure 9, PWC/Manassas had a much higher share of I/O loans and a slightly higher share of subprime loans than the rest of Virginia.

The composition of loans is important mostly because of differing foreclosure rates. Subprime foreclosure rates are considerably higher than I/O foreclosure rates, which are, in turn quite a bit higher than prime, non-I/O foreclosure rates (Figure 10). It is possible that if PWC/Manassas had Virs composition of loans, their total foreclosure rate would have been considerably lower. In order to test the role of composition, we calculated what the PWC/Manassas total foreclosure rate would have been if the area had its own foreclosure rates by product, but Northern Virginia's composition. The results are in Figure 11. We show that changing the composition of PWC/Manassas to Northern Virginia's reduces the foreclosure rate by only 0.1 percentage point, at most. Changing the PWC/Manassas composition to Virginia's composition accounts for slightly more of the difference in foreclosure rates, but still only reduces the foreclosure rate by 0.25 percentage point, at most. Therefore, loan composition alone cannot explain the considerably higher rate of default in PWC/Manassas. The high share of foreclosures in PWC/Manassas must be because of higher foreclosure rates.

[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]

In fact, the foreclosure rate on each type of loan has been higher in PWC/ Manassas (Figure 10) for some time. In particular, the PWC/Manassas I/O foreclosure rate was much higher than the rates in the rest of Northern Virginia and Virginia. In the end of 2009, approximately 50 percent of the inventory of loans in default in PWC/Manassas were I/O loans, 40 percent were prime non-I/O loans, and 10 percent were subprime loans. This is largely similar to the rest of Northern Virginia, but quite different from the state as a whole. In the rest of Virginia, only around 15 percent of defaults were on I/O loans, 68 percent were prime non-I/O loans, and about 17 percent were subprime loans.

Employment Conditions

Did unemployment contribute to the increased foreclosure rates in PWC/ Manassas? A look at unemployment data from the BLS indicates that changes in the PWC/Manassas unemployment rate closely track movements in state unemployment and that area unemployment continues to be well below that of the state and the nation. Unemployment in PWC/Manassas peaked at almost 6 percent in 2009--well below the 7 percent unemployment peak in Virginia as a whole (Figure 12).

[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]

This is not to say that rises in unemployment have played no role in the rising foreclosure in PWC/Manassas. First, as discussed in the previous section, small increases in unemployment in places with steep house price declines can have a larger effect than those in places without much depreciation of house values. Second, it is possible that intra-industry unemployment changes had a large effect in PWC/Manassas. As house prices fell in Prince William County, housing starts declined and the construction industry suffered. Construction employment declined in Prince William County by more than 6,300 net jobs (-39.8 percent) between September 2005-March 2009. (17) Figure 13 illustrates the sharp decline in the percent of workers in PWC/Manassas who were in the construction industry over the past few years. Since a notable portion of the construction workers in this area were legal and illegal immigrants, it is possible that the construction decline in PWC/Manassas had a disproportionate effect on the immigrant population.

[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]

According to the Pew Hispanic Center, national increases in unemployment have, in fact, disproportionately affected the U.S. Hispanic population and, more particularly, Hispanic immigrants. Nationally, Hispanic workers account for one-fourth of employment in construction and these workers benefited greatly from the housing boom that began in mid-2003. By the end of 2006, the U.S. Hispanic unemployment rate was at a historic low of 4.4 percent. But then, according to the Pew Hispanic Center, rising interest rates, home price depreciation, rising foreclosures, and a drop in new home starts affected Hispanic workers more than non-Hispanic workers because of the population's reliance on the construction industry and a widespread lack of skills required to immediately move into a different industry. The national Hispanic unemployment rate rose to 6.5 percent in the first quarter of 2008--well above the non-Hispanic unemployment rate of 4.7 percent Weekly earnings for Hispanic workers also fell in 2007 (Kochhar 2008).

[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]

It is clear from Figure 14 that Prince William County has a higher share of Hispanic residents than other areas of Northern Virginia and Virginia and Table 4 illustrates the higher growth of the Hispanic population in PWC from 2003-2008. Furthermore, Figure 15 indicates that a disproportionately large share of borrowers in Prince William County were Hispanic. Tf it is true that a large share of the Hispanic population of Prince William County was employed in the construction industry, and that employment in the construction industry declined more steeply in Prince William County, then it follows that more Hispanic borrowers than non-Hispanic borrowers in the county would have been affected by declining employment. Since much of the Hispanic population purchased homes in 2004-2006 (Figure 15), house price declines in the area make it likely that they were living in "underwater" properties when the construction industry decline sharpened and they became unemployed. In other words, this is a "trigger event" story transmitted through a minority population that is disproportionately employed in an industry that suffered particularly during this downturn. It could explain at least some of the exceptionally high default rates in PWC/Manassas.
Table 4 Change in Population 2003-2008

Locality Total Hispanic Ratio of
 Population Population Hispanic
 Growth Growth Growth to
 Total
 Growth

Prince 13.76% 53.86% 3.9
William
County

Manassas -4.00% 39.40% 9.9
City

Manassas 4.05% 33.62% 8.3
Park
City

Virginia 5.51% 31.07% 5.6

Source: Population Division, U.S. Census Bureau.


[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]

If this story is true (or even if it isn't), it is possible that the Hispanic population in Prince William County was a vulnerable population to begin with. Mayer and Pence (2008) document that, even controlling for credit scores and other zip code characteristics, race and ethnicity appear to be strongly and statistically related to the proportion of subprime loans throughout the country. They find that a 5.4 percentage point increase in the percent of non-Hispanic blacks is associated with an 8.3 percent increase in the share of subprime originations in the zip code and the same increase in the percent of Hispanics is associated with a 6.8 percent increase in the proportion of subprime loans.

These area-specific stories are difficult to incorporate into a broader estimation strategy, but they undoubtedly play a role in the unexplained portion of the model that we highlighted in the previous section.

Charlotte, N.C.

The story in Charlotte, N.C, is very different from that of PWC/Manassas. Although Charlotte has seen foreclosure rates rise notably faster than those in the rest of North Carolina, house price movements have been far more subdued than those in Northern Virginia. The story of Charlotte default rates cannot primarily be a house price story. On the other hand, unemployment rates in the MSA have risen much faster, and to much higher levels, than in other parts of the Fifth District.

Default rates in Charlotte did not start to rise until the end of 2008. From 2005 through the fall of 2008, foreclosure rates in Charlotte and the state of North Carolina were steady, varying from 0.6-0.8 percent in Charlotte and 0.4-0.6 percent in North Carolina. In November of 2008, however, foreclosure rates began to increase dramatically and over the subsequent year, default rates in Charlotte more than doubled. As is clear from Figure 16, the total foreclosure rate in Charlotte grew at a faster pace and to much higher levels than the rate in North Carolina.

House Price Movement

Unlike many areas of the country (including PWC/Manassas), Charlotte did not have a large appreciation in house prices. As is clear from Figure 17, house price movements have been far less dramatic in Charlotte than in the United States as a whole (which, in itself, hides some of the more extreme house price movements in other areas of the country). Although the Case-Shiller Home Price Index suggests that house prices started to decline in the middle of 2008, the FHFA house price index that we use in our MSA estimation in Section 2 does not show house value depreciation in the MSA until the second quarter of 2009. (18) Either way, the decline in Charlotte house prices through the third quarter of 2009 was mild compared to other parts of our District and our country.

[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]

Loan Composition and Borrower Characteristics

Similar to PWC/Manassas, the quality of the borrowers in Charlotte--as measured by loan-to-value ratios and FICO scores--was steady and did not differ notably from the state overall. Furthermore, at their peak, I/O loans accounted for only about 14 percent of first-lien, purchase-only originations in Charlotte (as compared to a peak of 53 percent in PWC/Manassas). Subprime lending accounted for just over 5 percent of lending. In other words, Charlotte had a high share of prime loans compared to other regions. Figure 18 illustrates the breakdown of lending by loan type in Charlotte.

[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]

It seems unlikely that the composition of loans had much effect on the total foreclosure rate in Charlotte, as such a high share of the loans were prime and non-l/O. Nonetheless, Figure 19 depicts the foreclosure rates by loan type in Charlotte. As expected, subprime loans have the highest foreclosure rates, followed by interest-only loans, and finally prime non-I/O loans. Default rates in Charlotte on all types of loans are higher than those in the state as a whole. At the end of 2009, approximately 10 percent of the Charlotte inventory of loans in foreclosure were interest-only, 77 percent were prime, and 13 percent were subprime--a composition very similar to the loan composition in the rest of North Carolina.

[FIGURE 17 OMITTED]

Employment Conditions

Although subprime and Alt-A loans were not a large part of the Charlotte market and house price movements were nowhere near as dramatic as in other areas, employment conditions in the MSA deteriorated considerably in 2008 and 2009. As a major U.S. financial center, the financial crisis that intensified following the collapse of Lehman Brothers affected Charlotte more than many other metro areas. Bank of America--which announced significant job cuts nationwide in December 2008 (19) --is headquartered in Charlotte. Wachovia Corporation was also headquartered in Charlotte before it was bought by Wells Fargo, a transaction that was estimated to cost the city at least 1,500 jobs. (20) In fact, of the 47,800 jobs lost from September 2008-September 2009, almost 10 percent were in the financial activities sector and a further 25 percent were in the professional and business services sector. The Charlotte manufacturing sector also saw notable job cuts in the period (about 20 percent of total losses), as did manufacturing sectors across North Carolina, the Fifth District, and the nation.

[FIGURE 18 OMITTED]

The spike in the Charlotte and North Carolina unemployment rates that was particularly dramatic after the fall of Lehman Brothers is illustrated in Figure 20. In just over a year, the unemployment rate in Charlotte doubled from around 6 percent to around 12 percent. Deteriorating employment conditions were very likely a key factor in rising default rates among Charlotte borrowers. Figure 16 marks the collapse of Lehman Brothers right at the beginning of the rise in foreclosure rates. The correlation between the total foreclosure rate and the unemployment rate across MSAs in the Fifth District is 0.72. The correlation for Charlotte is 0.90. Most of the loans in default in Charlotte are conventional prime loans, and we have already shown that the effect of labor market deterioration is more explanatory for prime default than for subprime default. In fact, the correlation between the subprime foreclosure rate and unemployment in Charlotte is high (0.83), but still smaller than that between the prime foreclosure rate and unemployment (0.90).

[FIGURE 19 OMITTED]

Of course, job loss does not necessarily lead to foreclosure; in most cases, it is better for the borrower to sell the house than to default. However, demand for housing has clearly dampened in the Charlotte MSA--a phenomenon clear from the recent fall in house prices. In our entire sample of MSAs, the correlation between the change in the unemployment rate and the change in house prices is around -0.55; for the Charlotte MSA that correlation is -0.93. (21) So what is one likely story for Charlotte? Unemployment rose more steeply and to higher levels than in other areas of the state. This fall dampened demand for housing, which has led to the recent (and continued) decline in house prices. The combination of the two has led to high default rates in the MSA. This is a story that is much more consistent with the variables in our Section 1 estimation than the story in PWC/Manassas and, therefore, the Washington, D.C., metro area.

[FIGURE 20 OMITTED]

5. CONCLUSION AND LOOKING FORWARD

The sharp rise in foreclosure rates in recent years has attracted the notice of policymakers and community development practitioners. Foreclosed and vacant houses remain an issue in many communities across the nation. In this article, we build a model of MSA fixed effects to tease apart the role of house prices and employment conditions in regional default rates.

We find, like many before us, that house price declines are a key factor in escalating foreclosure rates. Together with labor market conditions, we can explain most of the variation in both prime and subprime foreclosure. The variation in prime default is slightly better understood than the variation in subprime default, mostly because of the larger role of employment conditions in prime foreclosure rates. Given the rising share of prime mortgages in the foreclosure pool, this result means that strengthening labor markets will be particularly important to stemming the rise of delinquency and default. On the other hand, although we explain much of the variation, our estimation misses some important local characteristics that can influence default rates considerably. In many of our MS As, subprime default rates are rising beyond what would be a "standard" reaction to movement in house prices and unemployment. This is likely to be the result of local dynamics such as those we documented for Prince William County, Va., and Charlotte, N.C.

The goal of this work was to better understand the macrodynamics of foreclosure in our region. Going forward, we will want to drill down to the borrower level to better understand the effects of certain characteristics--such as lien status, underwriting criteria, or occupancy status--on the probability of borrower default in the Fifth District. Since examining housing markets at the MSA or county level is still a relatively macro look at housing activity, we will also seek to better understand smaller neighborhood dynamics in a borrower's decision to default.

(1.) The Fifth District of the Federal Reserve System comprises the District of Columbia, Maryland, North Carolina, South Carolina, Virginia, and most of West Virginia.

(2.) The term "seriously delinquent" refers to loans 90 or more days delinquent and those in the foreclosure process.

(3.) Source: Mortgage Bankers' Association.

(4.) For a review of the literature on option theory, see Vandell (1995), Deng, Quiglcy, and Van Order (2000), or, more recently, Elul (2006).

(5.) "Strategic default" refers to a borrower choosing to default despite having the financial means to continue to pay the mortgage. It is also sometimes referred to as "ruthless default."

(6.) Both theoretical and empirical work suggest a difference between mortgages on investorowned properties versus those on owner-occupied properties. For more detail on the role of investors in the rise of default, see Robinson and Todd (2010). Coleman, LaCour-Little, and Vandell (2008) also explore the connection between lending patterns and house price increases over 1998-2006 and find that the surge in non-owner-occupied lending is of greater importance than the growth in subprime. Haughwout, Peach, and Tracy (2008) also find that, for borrowers with negative equity, investors are much more likely than owners to default.

(7.) www.lpsvcs.com/IndustryExpertise/Articles/Pages/AAI0-17-l.aspx.

(8.) The "prime" category in the LPS data includes both prime and "near prime" loans. Almost all Alt-A loans are classified as "prime" in LPS.

(9.) We run this analysis on all first-lien loans in the MSAs. Restricting the sample to singlefamily homes changes the results only slightly (and in no statistically or economically significant way). If we restrict ourselves to purchase-only loans, we see larger, but still not dramatic, differences in results. For example, there is an increase in the magnitude of the coefficients on unemployment and both of the house price variables in the subprime model (5). There were similar--but notably smaller--changes to the prime model (5).

(10.) Standard deviation in 2007; see Table 1.

(11.) We tested the extent to which this difference is due to the dying out of the house price effect at around 10 percent house price growth (see Figures 1A and IB). We find that although the difference between negative and positive price growth is diminished when eliminating some of the higher house price growth observations, the results hold--increased (or decreased) depreciation has a stronger effect on foreclosure rates than decreased (or increased) appreciation.

(12.) Other robustness checks also included examining the effect of changes in our independent variables on changes in our dependent variable, including dummy variables to control for timing (both for every year included in our data and for before and after the financial crisis in the fall of 2008), and including dummy variables to control for geographic location (state and region) of the MSA. Our resulls are also robust to the same estimation on a national sample.

(13.) Our model is estimated through the third quarter of 2009. We use actual data and our model to predict foreclosure rates in the fourth quarter of 2009 and the first and second quarters of 2010. Our predictions after the second quarter of 2010 are based on assumptions about the movements of our model inputs that are laid out in Appendix B.

(14.) The counties and cities in all of Northern Virginia are: Arlington County, Clarke County, Fairfax County, Fauquier County, Loudoun County, Prince William County, Spotsylvania County, Stafford County, Warren County, Alexandria City, Fairfax City, Falls Church City, Fredericksburg City, Manassas City, and Manassas Park City.

(15.) MRIS data tracks home sales and listings so that their reported average price is affected by the composition of homes for sale at any given time.

(16.) Interestingly. Prince William County is also an "exurb" of D.C., with a lot more undeveloped land than more centrally located suburbs.

(17.) Prince William County Demographic Fact Sheet, 3rd Quarter 2009 (www.pwcgov.org/demographics).

(18.) Although both the FHFA and the S&P/Case-Shiller home price indexes are both developed from a repeat-valuations approach, there are a number of data and methodological differences. For one, the Case-Shiller index uses only purchase price data while FHFA also includes refinance appraisals. Second, FHFA's valuation data are derived from conforming, conventional mortgages (from Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) while Case-Shiller includes conforming and nonconforming mortgages. Finally, the Case-Shiller indexes are value-weighted, so that price trends for more expensive homes have greater influence on estimated price changes than those for other homes. FHFA weights price trends equally for all properties.

(19.) http://newsroom.bankofamcri.ca.com/index.php?s=43&ilem=8420.

(20.) www2.timesdispatch.com/rtd/business/banking/article/B-WACH30_20090929-212603/296328/.

(21.) The other metro areas with correlations above 0.90 were: Kingsport-Bristol-Bristol, Tenn.-Va.; Durham, N.C.; and Raleigh-Cary, N.C.

APPENDIX A:

Fifth District metropolitan statistical areas in the sample: Anderson, S.C.

Asheville, N.C.

Augusta-Richmond County, S.C. (Ga.)

Baltimore, Md.

Blacksburg, Va.

Burlington, N.C.

Charleston, W.Va.

Charleston, S.C.

Charlotte, N.C.

Charlottesville, Va.

Columbia, S.C.

Cumberland, Md.

Danville, Va.

Durham, N.C.

Fayetteville, N.C.

Florence, S.C.

Goldsboro, N.C.

Greensboro-High Point, N.C.

Greenville, N.C.

Greenville, S.C.

Hagerstown, Md.-W.Va.

Harrisonburg, Va.

Hickory, N.C.

Huntington-Ashland, W.Va. (Ky., Ohio)

Jacksonville, N.C.

Kingsport-Bristol-Bristol, Va. (Tenn.)

Lynchburg, Va.

Morgantown, W.Va.

Myrtle Beach, S.C.

Parkers burg, W.Va.

Raleigh-Cary, N.C.

Richmond, Va.

Roanoke, Va.

Rocky Mount, N.C.

Salisbury, Md.

Spartanburg, S.C.

Sumter, S.C.

Virginia Beach, Va.

Washington-Arlington-Alexandria, D.C.-Va.-Md.-W.Va.

Weirton-Steubenville, W.Va. (Ohio)

Wheeling, W.Va.

Wilmington, N.C.

Winchester, Va.-W.Va.

Winston-Salem, N.C.

For definitions of the nation's metropolitan statistical areas, see the Office of Management and Budget: www.whitehouse.gov/omb/assets/omb/bulletins/fy2009/09-0l.pdf.

APPENDIX B:

To develop the forecasts used to predict foreclosure rates (Tables 6A, 6B, 7A, and 7B) we used the following methodology.

Payroll employment:

(1) Calculate the mean of nonrecession year-over-year employment growth for Charlotte and Washington, D.C. (Charlotte: 2.0 percent; Washington, D.C: 1.5 percent) from 1990-2009.

(2) Assume that year-over-year growth rates increase at the same rate that they have been increasing for the past few quarters, until they reach their nonrecession mean year-over-year employment growth rate at which point the growth rate stays at its mean.

Unemployment rate:

(1)Calculate a "natural" rate of unemployment for Charlotte and Washington, D.C., by taking its 1990-2009 average. (Charlotte: 5.1 percent; Washington, D.C.: 3.8 percent).

(2)Assume that the unemployment rate declines at the same rate it de clined from 1992-1994 (coming out of the last big recession). Regress the unemployment rate on time from Ql:1992-Q4:1994. Take the coefficient and apply to unemployment now until unemployment rate reaches its "natural" rate. Then, allow unemployment rate to flatten.

House prices:

Charlotte:

(1) Calculate the average quarterly growth rate from Q1:1984 -- Q4:2005.

(2) Let prices fall at the rate they have been falling since Q 1:2009 until they reach their approximate level in Q4:2005 (156.74). Then, assume that they grow at the average quarterly rate calculated in (1).

Washington, D.C.:

(1) Calculate the average quarterly growth rate from QL1984-Q2:2004.

(2) Let prices fall at the rate they have been falling since Q 1:2009 until they reach their approximate level in Q2.2004 (191.93). Then, assume that they grow at the average quarterly rate calculated in (1).

Subprime and I/O shares:

The shares have been trending downward steadily. We simply extend the line at the same pace.

REFERENCES

Amrorain, Gene, and Anna L. Paulson. 2009. "Comparing Patterns of Default among Prime and Subprime Mortgages." Economic Perspectives 2Q: 18-37.

Coleman IV, Major, Michael LaCour-Little, and Kerry D. Vandell. 2008. "Subprime Lending and the Housing Bubble: Tail Wags Dog?" Journal of Housing Economics 17 (December): 272-90.

Crews Cutts, Amy, and William A. Merrill. 2008. "Interventions in Mortgage Default: Policies and Practices to Prevent Home Loss and Lower Costs." Freddie Mac Working Paper 08-01.

Deng, Yongheng, John M. Quigley, and Robert Van Order. 2000. "Mortgage Terminations, Heterogeneity, and the Exercise of Mortgage Options." Econometric a 68 (March): 275-308.

Doms, Mark, Fred Furlong, and John Krainer. 2007. "Subprime Mortgage Delinquency Rates." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2007-33.

Elul, Ronel. 2006. "Residential Mortgage Default." Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review Q3: 21-30.

Elul, Ronel, Nicholas S. Souleles, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Dennis Glennon, and Robert Hunt. 2010. "What 'Triggers' Mortgage Default?" Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 10-13 (April).

Foote, Christopher L., Kristopher Gerardi, and Paul S. Willen. 2008. "Negative Equity and Foreclosure: Theory and Evidence." Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Public Policy Discussion Paper 08-3.

Foster, C, and R. Van Order. 1984. "An Options-Based Model of Mortgage Default." Housing Finance Review 3 (4): 351-72.

Gerardi, Kristopher, Adam Hale Shapiro, and Paul S. Willen. 2009. "Decomposing the Foreclosure Crisis: House Price Depreciation versus Bad Underwriting." Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 2009-25.

Ghent, Andra C, and Marianna Kudlyak. 2009. "Recourse and Residential Mortgage Default: Theory and Evidence from U.S. States." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 09-10.

Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2009. "Moral and Social Constraints to Strategic Default on Mortgages." Working Paper 15145. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (July).

Haughwout, Andrew, Richard Peach, and Joseph Tracy. 2008. "Juvenile Delinquent Mortgages: Bad Credit or Bad Economy?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 341.

Kochhar, Rakesh. 2008. Latino Labor Report, 2008: Construction Reverses Job Growth for Latinos. Washington, D.C.: Pew Hispanic Center (June). http://pewhispanic.org/files/reports/88.pdf.

Mayer, Christopher J., and Karen Pence. 2008. "Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom?" Federal Reserve Board of Governors Finance and Economic Discussion Series Paper 2008-29.

Pennington-Cross, Anthony, and Giang Ho. 2006. "The Termination of Subprime Hybrid and Fixed Rate Mortgages." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2006-042A.

Quigley, John M., and Robert Van Order. 1995. "Explicit Tests of Contingent Claims Models of Mortgage Default." Journal of Real Estate Finance & Economics 11 (September): 99-117.

Robinson, Breck L., and Richard M. Todd. 2010. "The Role of Non-Owner-Occupied Homes in the Current Housing and Foreclosure Cycle." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 10-11.

Vandell, Kerry D. 1995. "How Ruthless is Mortgage Default? A Review and Synthesis of the Evidence." Journal of Housing Research 6 (2): 245-64.

The authors would like to thank Brian Gaines, Nika Lazaryan, Pierre Sarte, John Weinberg, and Kim Zeuli for their helpful comments. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. The data reported is from staff calculations based on data provided by LPS Applied Analytics. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. E-mails: sonya.waddell@ rich.frb.org, edward.prescott@rich.frb.org, anne.davlin@rich.frb.org.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有