Sectoral disturbances and aggregate economic activity.
Malysheva, Nadezhda ; Sarte, Pierre-Daniel G.
A key topic in the literature on business cycles concerns the
origins of shocks underlying fluctuations in economic activity. One
dimension of this topic focuses on whether we should think of aggregate
economic fluctuations as being driven by disturbances that affect all
areas of the economy simultaneously, or whether these movements are
instead better thought of as arising from shocks to different sectors
that affect economic activity by way of production complementarities
such as input-output linkages. To the extent that sources of
fluctuations include sectoral shocks, another key consideration then is
the manner in which sectoral shocks potentially become amplified and
propagate throughout the economy for a given degree of disaggregation.
A conventional wisdom argues that shocks to different sectors of
the economy are unlikely to matter for aggregate fluctuations because
they tend to average out in aggregation. Thus, positive shocks in some
sectors will generally be offset by negative shocks in other sectors.
This notion has in part led the bulk of the literature on business
cycles to concentrate on the effects of different types of aggregate
shocks. However, whether or not idiosyncratic sectoral shocks do average
out in aggregation depends on various aspects of the economic
environment. In particular, Gabaix (2011) describes how, when the
economy comprises a handful of very large sectors, sectoral disturbances
will not average out and contribute nontrivially to aggregate
fluctuations. Horvath (1998) also makes the point that because of
input-output linkages, shocks to particular sectors feed back into other
sectors in a way that leads to significant amplification and propagation of those shocks. This idea is further developed and analyzed from a
network perspective in Carvalho (2007), and Acemoglu, Ozdaglar, and
Tahbaz-Salehi (2010).
This article provides an overview of some key dimensions related to
the effects of sectoral shocks on aggregate economic activity. It
describes how the entire distribution of sectoral shares, or the weight
of different sectors in aggregate activity, generally matters for the
measured contribution of a sector to aggregate variability. It also
illustrates how intersectoral linkages affect the propagation and
amplification of sectoral idiosyncratic shocks. In particular, it
summarizes sufficient conditions, carefully articulated in Dupor (1999),
under which aggregate outcomes are invariant to sectoral disturbances,
even in the presence of input-output linkages across sectors. A key
condition requires that the matrix describing input-output linkages
satisfies a particular structure according to which all sectors serve as
equally important material providers to all other sectors.
To the degree that input-output linkages descriptive of U.S.
production depart from Dupor's (1999) sufficient conditions for the
irrelevance of sectoral shocks, it is generally not straightforward to
characterize how this departure translates into sectoral contributions
to aggregate variability. (1) As shown in Foerster, Sarte, and Watson
(2011), the contribution of sectoral shocks to aggregate fluctuations is
generally model-dependent and cannot be analytically characterized.
Thus, using an actual input use matrix obtained from the Bureau of
Economic Analysis (BEA) for 1997, and a two-digit level disaggregation
of gross domestic product (GDP), this article describes key aspects of
this calculation and provides estimates of the relative contribution of
different sectors to aggregate variations given each sector's share
in aggregate output. By and large, the manufacturing sector and the
sector related to real estate, rental, and leasing tend to contribute
the most to aggregate variations.
Given this article's emphasis on sectoral shocks, it also
examines how these shocks propagate to other sectors and become
amplified as a result of feedback effects resulting from intersectoral
linkages. Using two canonical multisector growth models in the
literature, specifically the foundational work of Long and Plosser
(1983) and, its descendant, Horvath (1998), it illustrates how the
propagation and amplification of sectoral shocks depend importantly on
the details of the economic environment in which intersectoral linkages
operate. Thus, it explains why using the share of the sector in which a
disturbance occurs as a gauge of its effect on aggregate output
constitutes, in general, a poor approximation. The article also shows
that the effects of a given sectoral shock both on other sectors and on
aggregate output will typically extend well beyond the life of the shock
itself. In some sectors, because of feedback effects, things can get
worse before improving even though the shock has already dissipated.
This article is not strictly concerned with accounting for the
actual volatility of output because of sectoral co-movement (that is the
main thrust of Foerster, Sarte, and Watson [2011]). Rather, this article
deals with the way in which sectoral weights and input-output
considerations affect the amplification and propagation of shocks.
Therefore, unless otherwise noted, we use a stylized version of sectoral
shocks, namely i.i.d. and uncorrelated across industries.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows. In Section 1, we
describe how sectoral size relates to aggregate variability absent any
complementarities in production. Section 2 provides an overview of how
sectoral linkages influence the effects of sectoral shocks using the
canonical multisector growth models of Long and Plosser (1983) and
Horvath (1998). In Section 3, we use an unanticipated one-time decline
in manufacturing total factor productivity (TFP) to illustrate how
sectoral shocks propagate to other sectors, as well as their ultimate
impact on aggregate output. Section 4 concludes.
1. SECTORAL SIZE AND AGGREGATE VARIABILITY
As a first approximation, it is natural to conjecture that sectoral
shocks should not matter for aggregate economic activity because they
will "average out." However, Gabaix (2011) carefully
articulates the idea that this intuition does not hold if some sectors
play a large role in economic activity, which he refers to as the
"granular" hypothesis. In this view, idiosyncratic shocks to
sectors with large shares have the potential to generate nontrivial disturbances in aggregate output. In particular, Gabaix (2011) shows
that idiosyncratic i.i.d. shocks fail to average out in aggregation when
the size distribution of sectors is sufficiently leptokurtic, or has
"fat tails," as characterized for instance by the power law
distribution. The nature of Gabaix's (2011) arguments relies on
asymptotic calculations where the number of sectors, N, is large. In
practice, however, N may not necessarily be very large if we think, for
example, that real estate or manufacturing as a whole are being
disrupted. The question then becomes: How do sectoral shares affect
aggregate variability in practice?
Table 1 gives the two-digit sectoral decomposition of GDP with the
industry code in the first column. The second column of Table 1 gives
the value-added shares of each sector, as a percent of GDP, associated
with this decomposition. To get an idea of how sectoral shares, or
weights [[omega].sub.i] affect aggregate variability, observe that
aggregate output growth, denoted [[DELTA]y.sub.t] at date t, can be
(approximately) written as the following weighted average of sectoral
output growth,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
Table 1 Sectoral Shares and Contributions to
the Variability of GDP,
1988-2010
Industry Name NAICS GDP Share, [[lambda].sub.i](Percent)
Code [w.sub.i]
(Percent)
Agriculture. 11 1.22 0.18
Forestry,
Fishing, and
Hunting
Mining 21 1.34 0.22
Utilities 22 2.05 0.51
Construction 23 4.29 2.23
Manufacturing 31-33 14.27 24.72
Wholesale Trade 42 5.98 4.33
Retail Trade 44-45 6.76 5.54
Transportation 48-49 2.99 1.09
and Warehousing
Information 51 4.37 2.31
Finance and 52 7.26 6.40
Insurance
Real Estate, 53 12.44 18.79
Rental, and
Leasing
Professional, 54 6.32 4.85
Scientific, and
Technical
Services
Management of 55 1.58 0.30
Companies and
Enterprises
Administrative 56 2.55 0.79
and Support
Management
Educational 61 0.87 0.09
Services
Health Care and 62 6.35 4.89
Social
Assistance
Arts, 71 0.90 0.10
Entertainment,
and Recreation
Accommodation 72 2.73 0.91
and Food
Services
Other Services 81 2.60 0.82
(except Public
Administration)
Government 92 13.13 20.92
Industry Name [[lambda].sub.i](Percent)
Agriculture. 1.37
Forestry,
Fishing, and
Hunting
Mining 1.88
Utilities 1.55
Construction 6.08
Manufacturing 43.81
Wholesale Trade 5.83
Retail Trade 7.57
Transportation 2.42
and Warehousing
Information 4.03
Finance and 9.35
Insurance
Real Estate, 5.21
Rental, and
Leasing
Professional, 4.04
Scientific, and
Technical
Services
Management of 0.40
Companies and
Enterprises
Administrative 1.73
and Support
Management
Educational 0.03
Services
Health Care and 0.76
Social
Assistance
Arts, 0.23
Entertainment,
and Recreation
Accommodation 1.17
and Food
Services
Other Services 1.26
(except Public
Administration)
Government 1.28
where [DELTA][y.sub.it],-, represents output growth in sector i at
t, N is the number of sectors, and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)Suppose for now that output growth in each
sector results directly from cross-sectionally unrelated i.i.d. shocks,
[[epsilon].sub.it] with identical variance,
[[DELTA].sub.[epsilon].sup.2], so that
[[DELTA]y.sub.it] = [[epsilon].sub.it], where [summation over
(term)] [epsilon] [epsilon] = [[DELTA].sub.[epsilon].sup.2]I, (2)
and [summation over (term)] [epsilon] [epsilon] denotes the
variance-covariance matrix of sectoral shocks. What can we say about the
contribution of a given sector to the variance of aggregate output
growth in this case?
Under the maintained assumptions, the variance of aggregate output
is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Let
[[lambda].sub.i] denote the contribution to aggregate variance from
sector /. Then, it follows that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
Observe that the size of the denominator in the above equation
depends on the distribution of the [[omga].sub.i]'s. Therefore,
while we have assumed away the role of idiosyncratic volatility by
assuming that all sectors are characterized by the same shocks, the
entire sectoral size distribution nevertheless matters for the
contribution of a given sector to aggregate volatility. The denominator
in (3) is minimized when [[omga].sub.i] = 1/N [A.sub.i], so that the
closer the [[omga].sub.i]'s are to being evenly distributed, the
lower the denominator will be. When [[omga].sub.i] = 1/N [A.sub.i], all
sectors play an equally important role in aggregate output,
[[lambda].sub.i] = 1/N [A.sub.i] and each sector's contribution to
aggregate variance is equal to its share. In that case, sectoral
disruptions will not be important for aggregate considerations as N
becomes large.
Given the data in Table 1, where N = 20, we have that [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. The third column of Table 1 gives
the contribution to aggregate variance of each sector under the
assumption that idiosyncratic shocks are identically and independently
distributed across sectors. For example, in the case of the construction
sector, denoted by [[lambda].sub.c], we have that
[[lambda].sub.c] = [0.043.sup.2]/0.082 = 0.022 (4)
Therefore, under the maintained assumptions, construction
contributes about 2 percent to the variability of aggregate GDP. For
comparison, if all sectors were the same size, the contribution to
aggregate variability from any one sector would be
[[lambda.sub.i] = [(1/20).sup.2]/20[(1/20).sup.2] = 1/20 = 0.05 (5)
Although construction is actually close to 1/20 of GDP, its
contribution to aggregate variability in this example is less than half
of its share in GDP.3 Put another way, the actual size distribution of
sectors is such that it reduces the importance of construction relative
to a distribution where all sectors have the same size. The reverse will
be true for sectors that have large shares in GDP. For example, in the
manufacturing sector, the contribution to aggregate variability,
[[lambda].sub.m], implied by the share in Table 1 is
[[lambda].sub.m] = [0.143.sup.2]/0.082 = 0.25 (6)
Hence, although manufacturing represents 14 percent of GDP, when
all sectors are subject to the same shocks, its contribution to
aggregate variability is almost double its share. This gives one measure
of the sense in which manufacturing might represent a key component of
an economic recovery.
The basic calculations we have just outlined have ignored two
important considerations. First, the size of sectoral shocks may be
sector-dependent. Second, idiosyncratic shocks may be correlated across
sectors. When the size of idiosyncratic shocks differs across sectors,
the contribution of a given sector to aggregate variability also takes
into account the volatility of that sector's output,
[[DELTA].sub.[[epsilon].sub.i].sup.2], relative to that of all other
sectors,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
Given equation (2), we have that
[[DELTA].sub.[[epsilon].sub.i].sup.2] = var([DELTA]y.sub.it). The fourth
column of Table 1 then gives the contribution to aggregate variability
from each sector implied by equation (7). Importantly, this calculation
continues to assume that idiosyn-cractic shocks are uncorrected across
sectors. Note that the contribution of the construction sector to
aggregate variability now almost triples, from 2.2 percent to 6.1
percent. This contribution now exceeds construction's share of GDP.
Similarly, manufacturing sees its contribution to aggregate variability
jump from 25 percent to 44 percent. At the other extreme, the government
sector's contribution to aggregate volatility falls dramatically
from 21 percent, in the third column of Table 1, to just 1.3 percent in
the fourth column. This result stems from the fact that while government
is a relatively large share of GDP, its output is very smooth relative
to that of other sectors.
While we have thus far ignored the fact that sectoral shocks may be
cross-sectionally correlated, it is important to recognize that the
presence of input-output linkages between sectors is likely to create
some degree of cross-sectional dependence. In Table 1 for example,
mining is likely to use the output of manufacturing, utilities, and
construction as inputs. In general, the effect of a shock to a given
sector on aggregate output will reflect not only that sector's
share, [[omega].sub.i], but also its degree of connection to all other
sectors. In particular, all else equal, a shock to a sector that
produces inputs for many other sectors will have a larger effect on
aggregate output. Put differently, the presence of input-output linkages
creates additional propagation from sectoral disturbances that amplify
their effect on aggregate output. The next section addresses key aspects
of the mechanisms by which this additional amplification and propagation
takes place.
2. SECTORAL SHOCKS AND SECTORAL LINKAGES: IMPLICATIONS FOR
AGGREGATE ACTIVITY
This section explores the role of sectoral linkages in amplifying
and propagating sector-specific shocks. In other words, these linkages
may, effectively, transform shocks that are specific to a particular
sector into shocks that affect all sectors and, therefore, amplify
variations in aggregate output. Because this analysis requires a model
that incorporates linkages between sectors, this section uses two
canonical models in the literature. The first model reflects the
foundational work of Long and Plosser (1983), which explicitly considers
each sector as potentially using materials produced in other sectors.
The second model is that of Horvath (1998), also discussed in Dupor
(1999), which allows the effects of sectoral shocks to be propagated
over time through capital accumulation. A key lesson in this section is
that, conditional on a given set of sectoral linkages, conclusions about
the effects of sectoral shocks may differ depending on other aspects of
the model in which these linkages operate.
Long and Plosser (1983)
Consider an economy composed of N distinct sectors of production
indexed by j = 1, ..., N. Each sector j produces the quantity [Y.sub.j,
t] of good j at date t using labor, [L.sub.j, t-1], and materials
produced in sector i = 1, ..., N, [M.sub.i, j, t-1] according to the
Cobb-Douglas technology
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
where [A.sub.j, t] is a productivity index for sector j. Note that
the technology features a version of time-to-build in the sense that
production is subject to a one-period lag.
The fact that each sector potentially uses materials produced in
other sectors represents a source of interconnectedness in the model. An
input-output matrix for this economy is an N x N matrix T with typical
element [Y.sub.ij]. The column sums of [GAMMA] give the degree of
returns to scale in materials in each sector. The row sums of [GAMMA]
measure the importance of each sector's output as materials to all
other sectors. Put simply, one can think of the rows and columns of
[GAMMA] as "sell to" and "buy from," respectively,
for each sector.
Let [A.sub.t], = [([A.sub.1, t], [A.sub.2, t], ..., [A.sub.N,
t]).sup.T] denote a vector of productivity indices that follow a random
walk,
Ln [A.sub.t] = ln[A.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (9)
where [[epsilon].sub.t] = [[[epsilon].sub.1, t], [[epsilon].sub.2,
t], ..., [[epsilon].sub.N, t]].sup.T has covariance matrix [summation
over (term)] [epsilon] [epsilon],
A representative household derives utility from the consumption of
these N goods and leisure, [Z.sub.t], according to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
In addition, each sector is subject to the following resource
constraints,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
Let [[DELTA]y.sub.t], denote the vector of sectoral output growth,
[([[DELTA]y.sub.1, t], [[DELTA]y.sub.2, t], ...,
[[DELTA]y.sub.N,t]).sup.T]. Then, Long and Plosser (1983) show that the
solution to the planner's problem is given by
[[DELTA]y.sub.t] = [[GAMMA].sup.T][[DELTA]y.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]. (13)
Letting [omega] = [([[omega].sub.1], [[omega].sub.2], ...,
[[omega].sub.N]).sup.T] represent the vector of sectoral shares in Table
1, an expression for aggregate output growth is
[[DELTA]y.sub.t] = [[omega].sub.T][[DELTA]y.sub.t] (14)
Let [[sigma].sub.y.sup.2] denote the variance of aggregate output
growth. Then, given equation (14), we have that
[[sigma].sub.y.sup.2] = [[omega].sub.T] [summation over
(term)]yy[omega], (15)
where [summation over (term)]yy is the variance-covariance matrix
of sectoral output growth.
For given N, and given equation (13), an analytical expression for
the variance of output growth in the Long and Plosser (1983) model is
given by (15) where (4)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (16)
For the purpose of calibration, the matrix T in this article is
based on estimates of the 1997 Input-Output use table constructed by the
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The BEA constructs the use table
based on data from the Economic Census conducted by the Bureau of the
Census every five years. The table shows the value of commodities (given
by commodity codes) used as inputs by intermediate and final users
(represented by industry codes). By matching commodity and industry
codes for the 20 industries, we create an input use table showing the
value of commodities from each industry used by all other industries. A
row sum of the use table represents the total value of materials
provided by a given industry to all 20 industries. A column sum of the
use table shows the total expenses of a given industry on the inputs
from all sectors. Input shares, [[gamma].sub.ij], are the payments from
sector j to sector i as a fraction of the total value of production in
sector j.
We saw earlier that when sectoral shocks have unit variance, the
variance of aggregate output growth absent sectoral linkages is
[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] = 0.082, slightly larger that [N.sub.-1] = (1/20)
predicted under uniform sectoral shares. When sectoral linkages are
taken into account in the model of Long and Plosser (1983), and using
the input-output matrix corresponding to the sectoral decomposition in
Table 1, the variance of aggregate output growth is approximately 0.12
or about one and a half times larger.
One can also obtain some measure of the contribution of individual
sectors to aggregate variability. To calculate the relative effect of
sector i on [[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2], let [summation over (term)][epsilon]
[epsilon] denote a diagonal matrix whose diagonal is (0, 0, ..., 1, ...,
0) where the "1" is located in the [i.sup.th] position. Then,
we can calculate what the variance of output growth would be with
sectoral linkages if the model were driven exclusively by shocks to
sector i:
[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] = [[omega].sub.T] [summation over
(term)yy[omega],
Where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (17)
In that case, the contribution of sector i to aggregate
variability, [[lambda].sub.i], is
[[lambda.sub,i] = [[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2]/[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] (18)
Table 2 shows [[lambda].sub.i], for the sectors considered in this
paper using both the Long and Plosser (1983) and the Horvath (1998)
frameworks. Under the maintained assumptions, the only difference
between the third column in Table 1 and the second column in Table 2
relates to input linkages across sectors. In both cases, shares are
taken into account in the calculations and sectors have homogenous variances. (5) Although input-output linkages generally increase overall
variance by slowing down the averaging that takes place in aggregation,
Table 2 indicates that the relative importance of any one sector may
increase or decrease depending in part on how important it is as an
input provider to other sectors. For example, manufacturing contributes
25 percent of aggregate variability absent input-output linkages.
However, when input-output linkages are taken into account, this
contribution increases to 35 percent using the Long and Plosser (1983)
framework. Manufacturing, therefore, plays an important role as an input
provider to other sectors. In contrast, retail trade explains roughly 6
percent of aggregate variations based solely on its share in total
output. Once input-output linkages are considered, the contribution of
retail trade to aggregate variability falls to 4 percent. Thus, linkages
of retail trade to other sectors play somewhat minor roles relative to
those of other sectors.
Table 2 Input-Output and Contributions to the Variability
of GDP, 1988-2010
Industry Name NAICS [[lambda].sub.i.sup.LP] [[lambda].sub.i.sup.HD]
NAICS Code Code
Agriculture, 11 0.32 0.60
Forestry,
Fishing, and
Hunting
Mining 21 0.33 0.51
Utilities 22 0.50 0.56
Construction 23 1.71 0.69
Manufacturing 31-33 35.31 42.77
Wholesale Trade 42 3.69 2.66
Retail Trade 44-45 4.18 1.49
Transportation 48-49 1.34 1.48
and Warehousing
Information 51 2.11 1.87
Finance and 52 6.16 6.06
Insurance
Real Estate, 53 15.77 25.51
Rental, and
Leasing
Professional, 54 5.80 6.80
Scientific, and
Technical
Services
Management of 55 0.63 0.72
Companies and
Enterprises
Administrative 56 1.15 1.37
and Support
Management
Educational 61 0.07 0.02
Services
Health Care and 62 3.66 1.02
Social
Assistance
Arts, 71 0.08 0.05
Entertainment,
and Recreation
Accommodation 72 0.72 0.38
and Food
Services
Other Services 81 0.71 0.53
(except Public
Administration)
Government 92 15.68 4.90
Notes: [[lambda].sub.i.sup.LP] is computed using Long
and Plosser (1983) and uncorrected sectoral shocks
with unit variance. Similarly, [[lambda].sub.i.sup.HD]
is computed using Horvath (1998) or Dupor (1999).
Horvath (1998)
The model in Horvath (1998) is very similar to that of Long and
Plosser (1983) but adds sectoral capital. Specifically, production in
sector / now takes the form
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
while each sector's resource constraint now reads as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (20)
Horvath's (1998) model makes two key concessions to realism
for the sake of analytical tractability. First, capital is assumed to
depreciate entirely within the period. In that sense, the distinction
between materials and capital is more one of timing than any other
consideration. Second, each sector produces its own capital. Under these
assumptions, the solution for sectoral output growth is now given by
[[DELTA]y.sub.t] =
[Z.sub.T][[alpha].sub.d][[DELTA]y.sub.t-1]+[Z.sub.T][[epsilon].sub.t] [
(21)
where [[alpha].sub.d] is a diagonal matrix with the vector of
sectoral capital shares, ([[alpha].sub.1][[alpha].sub.2], ...,
[[alpha].sub.N]) along its diagonal and Z = [(I-[GAMMA]).sub.-1]. This
vector is based on the estimates of other value added (rents on capital)
from the BEA's use table.
Similar to Long and Plosser (1983), an analytical expression for
the variance of aggregate output growth is given by equation (15):
[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] = [[omega].sub.T][summation over]yy[omega],
where [summation over (term)]yy now satisfies
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (22)
There are two key differences that distinguish Horvath's
(1998) framework from that of Long and Plosser (1983). First, a shock to
sector i immediately propagates to other sectors by way of input-output
linkages, as captured by the term [Z.sub.T][[epsilon].sub.t], in (21)
rather than just [[epsilon].sub.t] in (13). This follows from the fact
that Horvath's (1998) model loses the one-period time-to-build
feature of Long and Plosser (1983). Second, sectoral shocks propagate
through time by way of capital accumulation and thus are scaled by the
matrix of capital shares, as captured by the autoregressive coefficient [Z.sub.T][[alpha].sub.d] Both of these features will change the variance
decompositions carried out earlier as well as the nature of the
propagation of sector-specific shocks.
Recall that under Long and Plosser (1983) and unit variance
sectoral shocks, aggregate variability was amplified one and a half
times relative to the case without sectoral linkages. Under Horvath
(1998), aggregate output variance increases to 0.42 or a five-time
increase relative to the case with-out sectoral linkages. The third
column of Table 2 shows [lambda] the contribution from different sectors
to aggregate variability using the Horvath (1998) model. By and large,
the sectors that contribute most to aggregate variability are the same
as those in the first column of the table using the Long and Plosser
(1983) framework. However, the importance of the sectors with extensive
sectoral linkages is amplified in Horvath (1998). Thus,
manufacturing's share of aggregate variability increases from 35
percent to 43 percent. Similarly, real estate, rental, and leasing sees
its contribution to aggregate variance increase from 16 percent to
roughly 26 percent. As we shall see below, intersectoral linkages take
on a greater role in Horvath (1998) because sectoral shocks get
propagated by way of not only the input-output matrix but also internal
capital accumulation, [Z.sub.T][[alpha].sub.d], where [[alpha].sub.d] is
the matrix of capital shares.
Some Key Assumptions and the Irrelevance of Sectoral Shocks
We suggested earlier that sectoral shocks can fail to average out
as N becomes large when the distribution of sectoral shares is
sufficiently leptokurtic. Aside from this consideration, one might also
ask whether sectoral linkages necessarily prevent sectoral shocks from
being irrelevant at the aggregate level. To that end, Dupor (1999) uses
Horvath's (1998) framework to analyze the conditions under which
sectoral shocks average out even in the presence of sectoral linkages.
In particular, Dupor's work relies on three key conditions:
(A1) [omega] = [N.sup.-1]h, where h is a vector of ones, [(1,1,
..., 1).sup.T].
(A2) [GAMMA]h = [kappa]h, where [kappa] is a positive scalar. Put
another way, h is an eigenvector of the N x N matrix [GAMMA] with
corresponding eigenvalue, k. This assumption implies that all rows of
[GAMMA] sum up to [kappa], so that all sectors serve as equally intense
material input providers to all other sectors.
(A3) [summation over (term)] [epsilon] [epsilon] = I.
It turns out that under these assumptions, the role of sectoral
shocks vanishes in aggregation not only in the environment studied by
Dupor (1999), but also in other canonical versions of the multisector
growth model including Long and Plosser (1983) and, more recently,
Carvalho (2007).
In the case of Long and Plosser (1983), assumption (Al) and
equation (13) imply that the variance of aggregate output growth (15)
can be expressed as
[[sigma].sub.y.sup.2] = [N.sup.-2][h.sup.T] [[summation over
(term)].sup.yy][GAMMA]h + [N.sup.-2][h.sup.T] [[summation over
(term)].sup. [epsilon][epsilon]]h.
=[N.sup.-2][h.sup.T][[GAMMA].sup.T] [[summation over].sup.yy]h
When (A2) and (A3) hold, the first term on the right-hand side of
this last equation simplifies as follows,
[N.sup.-2][h.sup.T] [[summation over].sup.yy][GAMMA]h =
[N.sup.-2][[kappa].sup.2][h.sup.T] [[summation over].sup.yy]h
while the second term becomes
[N.sup.-2][h.sup.T][[summation over].sup. [epsilon][epsilon]]h =
[N.sup.-2][h.sup.T]h
=[N.sup.-1]
It immediately follows that
[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] = [N.sup.-1][(1-[[kappa].sup.2]).sup.-1],
(23)
which indeed converges to zero at rate N.
Using the same assumptions, and by following similar steps, the
variance of aggregate output growth in Horvath (1998) becomes
[[DELTA].sub.y.sup.2] =
[N.sup.-1][[(1-[kappa]-[alpha])(1-[kappa]+[alpha])].sup.-1] (24)
which also converges to zero at rate N.
Several observations are worth noting with respect to equations
(23) and (24). Under the maintained assumptions, the irrelevance of
sectoral shocks holds in the limit. Hence, a question arises as to what
the relevant level of disaggregation is in practice. To us, this
question is mainly one that relates to technology and the nature of
shocks under consideration. In particular, it is likely befitting that
manufacturing and retail trade should be thought of as characterized by
fundamentally different technologies, and hence affected by
fundamentally different shocks, but it may also be the case that within
manufacturing, "iron and steel products" should be treated
differently than "metalworking machinery."
In general, the Census uses two criteria for making industry
classifications. The first is the economic significance of the industry,
which refers to the size of an industry at the highest level of
disaggregation relative to the average size of industries in its
particular division. For example, breaking up "iron and steel
products" within manufacturing into two separate industries,
"iron products" and "steel products" would involve
comparing the size of each industry individually to the average
manufacturing industry size. The notion of size, or economic
significance, considers five main characteristics: the number of
establishments in the industry, the industry's number of employees,
its payroll, its value added, and its value of shipments. A weighted
average is then constructed from these five measurements, which are
expressed relative to a similarly computed measure of the average size
of existing industries in the pertinent division. Once a given economic
significance score is reached, the industry potentially qualifies as a
new classification at the highest level of disaggregation. The second
criterion is based on specialization and coverage ratios. These ratios
combine to measure the share of production and shipments of an
industry's primary products in the economy. Conditional on meeting
the first criterion, an industry is then recognized only if each of
these ratios reaches a threshold level.
In an exercise that focuses on U.S. industrial production,
Foerster, Sarte, and Watson (2011) consider up to 117 sectors, the
highest level of disaggregation for which input-output tables from the
BEA can be matched to sectoral output data. Interestingly, the authors
find that the relevance of sectoral shocks for aggregate variability
appear robust to the level of disaggregation. This finding arises in
part because, as an empirical matter, sectoral variability increases
with the level of disaggregation, thus offsetting the "averaging
out" effect of [N.sup.-1] in equations (23) and (24).
The conclusions in this section rely crucially on assumption (A2),
[GAMMA]h =[kappa]h, so that all rows of T must sum up to the same
scalar. Put differently, this condition requires the input-output matrix
to be such that all sectors serve as equally important material input
providers to all other sectors. Figure 1 shows the row sums of the
input-output matrix, [GAMMA], associated with our two-digit
decomposition. The figure indicates that the row sums, [GAMMA]h, can
differ considerably from one another in practice. Using a four-digit
decomposition of industrial production, Foerster, Sarte, and Watson
(2011) show that when output is disaggregated further, [GAMMA]h further
displays pronounced skewness. This skewness is consistent with the
notion emphasized in Carvalho (2007) that a few sectors play crucial
roles as input providers. Thus, the key step that allows for aggregation
despite sectoral linkages, assumption (A2), does not appear to be
consistent with our sectoral data.
That said, one should be clear that the assumptions outlined in
this section represent sufficient conditions for the asymptotic
irrelevance of sectoral shocks. To the degree that [GAMMA]h differs from
[kappa]h, so that not all sectors serve as equally important material
providers to other sectors, the implications of this difference for the
contribution of sectoral shocks to aggregate variability is not
immediately clear. In particular, the way in which a given sectoral
shock becomes amplified and propagates to other sectors, and thus
affects aggregate output, generally needs to be computed numerically for
a given input-output matrix, [GAMMA], and sectoral shares, [omega]. It
is to this consideration that we next turn our attention.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
3. SECTORAL SHOCK PROPAGATION WITH SECTORAL LINKAGES
Given the Long and Plosser (1983) model solution in (13), the
effects of sectoral shocks arising at t, [[epsilon].sub.t], on sectoral
output growth at date t + j are given by
E[[DELTA]y.sub.t+j]/e[[epsilon].sub.t] = [[[GAMMA].sup.T].sup.j],
(25)
and the resulting change in aggregate output growth is
[[omega].sup.Te[[DELTA]y.sub.t+j/e[[epsilon].sub.t] =
[[epsilon].sup.T][([[GAMMA].sup.T]).sup.j].
Consider the effects of a negative shock to a given sector, say
manufacturing, denoted by [[epsilon].sub.mt],so that [[epsilon].sub.t] =
[(0, 0, ..., [[epsilon].sub.mt], ..., 0).sup.T]. Two noteworthy
observations arise. (6)
First, because [([[GAMMA].sup.T]).sup.0]=I, the shock to
manufacturing will only affect itself in the period in which the shock
occurs. In other words e[[DELTA]y.sub.t]/e[[epsilon].sub.it] for all
sectors that are not manufacturing. There is no propagation of the shock
to other sectors in the period in which the shock occurs. Hence, the
contemporaneous effect of the manufacturing shock on aggregate output
growth is simply c[[omega].sub.me[[DELTA]y.sub.t]/e[[epsilon].sub.mt],
where [[omega].sub.m] is the share of the manufacturing sector in GDP.
This result may be interpreted as the formal justification for the
notion that the aggregate effects of sectoral shocks can be judged from
the output share of the sector in which the shock occurs. As we shall
see shortly, however, this is generally not the case.
Second, the effect of the shock to manufacturing on any other
sector j in the following period is given by
E[[DELTA]y.sub.j, t+1]/e[[epsilon].sub.m,t] = [gamma].sub.mj] (26)
In other words, in Long and Plosser (1983), a shock to the
manufacturing sector begins to propagate to another sector j, in the
period after the shock, by exactly [[gamma].sub.mj], the amount that
sector j spends on materials produced in the manufacturing sector as a
fraction of sector j's total spending on inputs. Therefore, the
less sector j spends on materials from sector m, the lower will be the
effect of a shock to sector m on sector j.
Figure 2 depicts impulse responses to an unanticipated exogenous onetime 5 percent fall in manufacturing total factor productivity (TFP)
in the Long and Plosser (1983) economy. The solid line in the top
left-hand panel of Figure 2 shows the time path of the shock. The dashed
line in that panel shows the response in output growth in the
manufacturing sector. By design, the shock to manufacturing TFP has
dissipated after one period. As discussed above, because the shock does
not propagate to other sectors contemporaneously, thus also preventing a
feedback effect from those sectors back into manufacturing, the initial
decline in manufacturing output growth is exactly equal to the size of
the decline in TFP, or 5 percent. Moreover, we can see that the effect
of the shock on manufacturing output growth is considerably longer lived
than the shock itself. The top right-hand panel of Figure 2 explains
why. That panel depicts the effects of the fall in TFP in manufacturing
on all other sectors. As suggested above, the initial effect of the
manufacturing TFP decline on all other sectors is zero. However, in the
period after the manufacturing disturbance occurs, the shock has spread
to all other sectors by way of input-output linkages so that these all
experience a decline in output growth. The size of this decline in the
different sectors reflects the degree to which they rely on
manufacturing as an input provider, [[gamma].sub.mj] <0, which then
feeds back into manufacturing in so far as it uses the output of those
sectors as inputs, [[gamma].sub.im] 0. In the top right-hand panel of
Figure 2, the largest decline in output in the period following the
manufacturing TFP shock occurs in the construction sector at -1.4
percent.
The bottom left-hand panel of Figure 2 illustrates the aggregate
effect of the manufacturing shock on output. As indicated above, because
the share of manufacturing in GDP is approximately 0.14, the initial
effect of the shock on aggregate output in the Long and Plosser (1983)
model is roughly 0.14 x 5 or a 0.7 percent decline in GDP. In addition,
note that this aggregate effect is considerably more persistent than the
initial one-time decline in manufacturing TFP. As before, this feature
arises mainly from the propagation of the shock to other sectors which,
by way of a feedback effect, induces persistence in the output decline
of all sectors and, therefore, at the aggregate level as well. (7) For
comparison, the bottom right-hand panel of Figure 2 shows the effect on
aggregate output of an unanticipated one-time decline in TFP in all
sectors, which may be interpreted as an unanticipated aggregate TFP
shock. As in the case of sectoral shocks, the effect on aggregate output
is considerably longer lived than the shock itself. However, because the
5 percent fall in TFP now applies to all sectors, the size of the output
decline is considerably more pronounced.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In Horvath (1998), the effects of sectoral shocks arising at t,
[[epsilon].sub.t], on sectoral output growth at date t + j are given by
e[DELTA]=[y.sub.]+j/e[[epsilon].sub.t]=[([Z.sup.T][[alpha].sub.d])..sup.j[Z.sup.T]. (27) In this case, a negative shock to the manufacturing
sector immediately propagates to other sectors by way of input-output
linkages, as embodied in [Z.sup.T]=[(I-[[GAMMA].sup.T])].sup.-1],
because materials are used within the period. This is the source of the
notable amplification of sectoral shocks in Horvath (1998) relative to
one without input-output linkages. In particular, the
variance-covariance matrix of sectoral output growth (absent any
propagation) is [Z.sup.T][[SIGMA].sub.[epsilon][epsilon]]Z rather than
just [[SIGMA].sub.[epsilon] [epsilon]]. In addition, sectoral shocks
further propagate over time through their effects of capital
accumulation by way of input-output linkages, [Z.sup.T][[alpha].sub.d]
In other words, the model contains an internal propagation mechanism
that potentially extends the life of the original shock on aggregate
economic activity.
Analogous to Figure 2, Figure 3 shows the effects of a 5 percent
unanticipated one-time decline in manufacturing TFP, but this time in
the Horvath (1998) economy. The impulse responses in Figure 3 highlight
several key differences with those that obtain in the Long and Plosser
(1983) model. First, the effect of the fall in manufacturing TFP is
immediately amplified through input-output linkages. In particular,
while TFP falls by 5 percent in the top left-hand panel of Figure 3,
manufacturing output growth falls by 9 percent or nearly double the size
of the shock. This stems from the fact that materials are used within
the period in Horvath (1998). As pointed out earlier, in the solution
for sectoral output growth (21), output growth at time t reflects the
effects of contemporaneous sectoral links, (1
-[[[GAMMA].sup.T].sup.-1][[epsilon].sub.t], instead of the effects of
sectoral disturbances alone, e,, in the solution to the Long and Plosser
(1983) model, (13). The top right-hand panel of Figure 3 illustrates
this feature and, unlike Figure 2, shows that output growth falls in all
sectors at the time that manufacturing TFP declines. In addition,
observe that the output decline in all sectors is considerably larger
than that in the period after the shock in the Long and Plosser (1983)
economy in Figure 2. Second, the top right-hand panel of Figure 3
suggests that impulse responses in some sectors are slightly
non-monotonic so that, in those sectors, the outlook gets worse before
it gets better even though the manufacturing TFP shock itself has
already dissipated. (8) Third, and related to this last observation, the
effects of the one-time decline in TFP is somewhat more persistent than
in the Long and Plosser (1983) framework. Finally, because of
contemporaneous intersectoral linkages, the effect of the decline in
manufacturing TFP on aggregate output is now noticeably more pronounced
than in Figure 2. Specifically, aggregate output growth declines by 2
percent on impact and continues to be below its steady state well after
the shock has dissipated. We saw earlier that the contribution of
manufacturing's share to the fall in aggregate output is roughly
0.7 percent in the bottom left-hand panel of Figure 2. Therefore, in
this case, contemporaneous input-output links add about 1.3 percent to
the decline in aggregate output on impact.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The basic lesson of this section is that input-output linkages, and
potentially other forms of complementarities in production, propagate
and amplify the effects of sectoral disturbances. Therefore, using the
share of the sector in which a disturbance occurs as a gauge of its
effect on aggregate output constitutes, in general, a relatively poor
approximation. However, the extent of the amplification and propagation
mechanism that results from intersectoral linkages depends on the
particular economic environment in which these linkages operate. In
their recent article, Foerster, Sarte, and Watson (2011) extend the
analysis in this section to include intersectoral linkages in investment
goods (so that some sectors produce new capital goods for other
sectors), less than full capital depreciation within the period, and
allow for aggregate shocks. They find that the importance of sectoral
disturbances in explaining aggregate fluctuations has noticeably
increased over time and that, over the period 1984-2007, these
disturbances explain half the variation in U.S. industrial production.
However, although the nature of intersectoral production has changed
over time, the authors also find that changes in the input-output matrix
reflecting new sectoral links has not led to greater propagation of
shocks.
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This article has provided an overview of some key aspects of the
effects of sectoral shocks on aggregate economic activity. It discussed
the role of sectoral shares in determining each sector's
contribution to aggregate variations. It also illustrated how
input-output linkages in production influenced the amplification and
propagation of sectoral shocks. The mechanisms by which this
amplification and propagation take place depend importantly on the
details of the economic environment in which intersectoral linkages
operate. In general, because of input-output linkages across sectors,
using the share of the sector in which a disturbance occurs as a gauge
of its effect on aggregate output constitutes a poor approximation. In
addition, the key condition required of the input-output matrix that
lead sectoral shocks to average out in aggregation, carefully
articulated in Dupor (1999), does not appear to apply in practice. Using
an input use matrix obtained from the BEA for 1997, as well as a
two-digit level disaggregation of GDP, suggests that manufacturing and
real estate, rental, and leasing contribute the most to aggregate
variations.
(1) Carvalho (2007), as well as Acemoglu, Ozdaglar, and
Tahbaz-Salehi (2010) make considerable progress along this dimension.
(2) To be specific, [[omega].sub.i] in this case represents the
mean share of sector [iota] output as a percent of GDP over a given
sample period.
(3) Table 1 distinguishes between construction and real estate,
rental, and leasing. The construction sector is comprised of
establishments that are primarily engaged in the construction of
buildings or engineering projects. Construction work may include new
work, additions, alterations, or maintenance and repairs. The real
estate, rental, and leasing sector is comprised of establishments that
are primarily engaged in leasing and renting, and establishments
providing related services. Also included are establishments primarily
engaged in appraising real estate and the management of real estate for
others (e.g., renting, selling, or buying real estate), as well as
owner-occupied real estate.
(4) This result follows from the fact that for any matrices A, B,
and C, such that the product ABC exists, vec(ABC) = ([C.sup.T]xA)
vec(B).
(5) This calculation highlights the importance of input-output
linkages only. As shown in Foerster, Sarte, and Watson (2011), in
practice, the relative magniture of shocks across sectors also matters.
(6) Observe that under conditions (Al) and (A2) in the previous
section, or {[[omega].sup.T]xe[DELTA][y.sub.t]+j}/e[member
of]t=[N.sub.-1][kappa] which goes to zero as N becomes large.
(7) Recall that the model in Long and Plosser (1983) contains no
internal propagation mechanism, such as might occur through capital
accumulation, other than the one-period delivery lag in materials.
Strictly speaking, the induced persistence in the impulse responses to a
one-time sectoral shock in Figure 2 stems from the combination of that
lag with sectoral linkages.
(8) Given our calibration of [GAMMA] and [[alpha].sub.d] based on
the input use tables from the BEA, [Z.sup.T] [[alpha].sub.d]has complex
eigenvalues.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, Daron, Asuman Ozdaglar, and Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi. 2010.
"Cascades in Networks and Aggregate Volatility." MIT Working
Paper (October).
Carvalho, Vasco M. 2007. "Aggregate Fluctuations and the
Network Structure of Intersectoral Trade." Manuscript, University
of Chicago.
Dupor, Bill. 1999. "Aggregation and Irrelevance in
Multi-sector Models." Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (April):
391-409.
Foerster, Andrew T., Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte, and Mark W. Watson.
2011. "Sectoral versus Aggregate Shocks: A Structural Analysis of
Industrial Production." Journal of Political Economy 119
(February): 1-38.
Gabaix, Xavier. 2011. "The Granular Origins of Aggregate
Fluctuations." Econometrica 79 (May): 733-72.
Horvath, Michael. 1998. "Cyclically and Sectoral Linkages:
Aggregate Fluctuations from Independent Sectoral Shocks." Review of
Economic Dynamics 1 (October): 781-808.
Long, John B., Jr., and Charles I. Plosser. 1983. "Real
Business Cycles." Journal of Political Economy 91 (February):
39-69.
We wish to thank Kartik Athreya, Andreas Hornstein, Nika Lazaryan,
and Zhu Wang for helpful comments. The views expressed in this article
are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. All
errors are our own. E-mail: pierre.sarte@rich.frb.org.