Introduction to the special issue on modern macroeconomic theory.
Hornstein, Andreas
The great recession of 2007-2009 has generated significant external
criticism of the way economists study and try to understand aggregate
economic outcomes. Modern macroeconomic theory, in particular, has been
criticized for its representation of the economy through highly stylized
environments that abstract from distributional issues, ignore or
minimize linkages between the financial and nonfinancial sectors of the
economy, and, in general, rely too much on highly aggregative
frameworks. This issue collects four articles that describe how modern
macroeconomic research has dealt with some of these issues as part of a
research program that has been ongoing for more than a decade.
The first article by Nobuhiro Kiyotaki provides a short history of
modern business cycle theory and how it has evolved to potentially
address the role of the financial sector in the aggregate economy.
Kiyotaki starts with the neoclassical growth model as a reference point
for most of modern business cycle theory. This modelling framework,
originally known as "real business cycle" theory, starts with
the stark abstraction of one representative household and one
representative producer in a competitive environment without any
frictions on the interactions of consumers and producers. From the
perspective of this model, business cycles are driven by exogenous
shocks, and the dynamics of the cycle essentially reflect the dynamics
of the shocks. In other words, there is only a weak model-internal
mechanism that propagates shocks. Kiyotaki then studies a sequence of
well-defined deviations from this reference point and asks what
deviations are more likely to affect the baseline interpretation of
business cycles. Kiyotaki first shows how heterogeneity in consumption
and production can be easily accommodated in this framework given the
assumption of complete markets. In a second step, Kiyotaki shows how
non-competitive markets, either because of market power or limitations
on the interactions of agents, can be introduced into the baseline
model. Neither of these modifications affect the interpretation of
business cycles as being driven by shocks. Finally, Kiyotaki argues that
restrictions on the set of available financial contracts significantly
affect the way exogenous shocks are propagated in the model economy.
The second article by Vincenzo Quadrini elaborates on the role of
financial frictions for production decisions. Quadrini illustrates these
financial frictions in a simple example where entrepreneurs have to
acquire capital to operate an intertemporal production technology.
Again, financial frictions are introduced relative to the baseline
complete markets framework. Quadrini discusses the two most popular
models of market incompleteness--the costly state verification (CSV)
model and the collateral constraint (CC) model. Both frameworks limit
entrepreneurs to the use of two financial instruments: contingent debt
(equity or net worth) and non-contingent debt. In the CSV model,
non-contingent debt is the optimal response to a limited information
problem, and an entrepreneur's net worth limits his ability to
issue debt and finance investment projects. In the CC model, posting
collateral allows the entrepreneur to obtain credit despite his
inability to credibly commit to the repayment of debt. The main question
then becomes how these financial frictions can amplify the effects of
shocks to the economy or be themselves a source of shocks to the
economy. Quadrini illustrates the basic mechanism for amplification and
propagation in the simple model, and surveys the results from more
"realistic" models.
The third article by Fatih Guvenen surveys recent research on
household heterogeneity in the absence of complete markets. We might be
interested in household heterogeneity for two reasons. First, even
though we assume in the baseline "real business cycle" model
that aggregate consumption and labor supply decisions can be modelled
through a representative household construct, we might worry that
"distributions" of ability, income, or wealth do matter for
the behavior of these aggregate outcomes. Second, observed inequality of
income and wealth often gives rise to attempts to redistribute
resources. In order to address the costs and benefits of such a policy,
one first needs a theory that accounts for the currently observed
inequality across households. If we care about inequality because of
implied differences in "well-being," then we should care about
inequality in consumption and leisure, and we should care about income
inequality only to the extent that it gives rise to consumption
inequality. Much of the research surveyed by Guvenen studies how, in the
absence of complete markets, income inequality gets translated into
consumption and wealth inequality. If the level of income and its
distribution are exogenous, the redistribution problem is simplified
since any attempt to influence consumption and wealth inequality does
not feed back into either the level or the distribution of income. But
economists are always worried about the labor supply effects of tax
policies, that is that at least part of income levels and inequality are
endogenous. In standard models, these labor supply effects show up as
variations in hours worked or labor market participation decisions. In
his survey, Guvenen emphasizes a different labor supply decision, namely
the accumulation of human capital. Overall, Guvenen shows that
accounting for heterogeneity of households in environments with
incomplete markets is feasible, but it also requires the application of
advanced computational tools. In the absence of controlled experiments,
researchers are essentially compelled to construct artificial worlds
with a population of heterogeneous households. Once the consumption and
labor supply decisions of the households in the model mirror the
observed behavior of households, we can ask how changes in the
artificial environment will affect outcomes.
The fourth article by Diego Restuccia deviates somewhat from the
imme-diate concerns of the U.S. economy and studies the issues of output
determi-nation in a global framework. During the "Great
Recession," U.S. real gross domestic product (GDP) declined by 5
percent from 2007 to 2009, and, as of 2011, real GDP is now arguably 10
percent below its long-run trend growth path. While these changes of
real output are large, they pale in comparison to observed cross-country
income differences: In 2005, the average per capita income in the
richest countries was about 65 times that of the poorest coun-tries.
Restuccia first surveys the evidence on cross-country differences in per
capita income. He shows that, although it appears that cross-country per
capita income inequality has been increasing over the last 30 years, for
individual countries there are success stories and then there are
failures. The recent, most prominent examples for countries that have
been catching up with the leading world economy the United States are
China and India. However, there are countries such as Zimbabwe and
Venezuela that have been falling behind the United States more and more.
Restuccia then argues that the process of structural transformation,
that is, the transition from a predominantly agricul-tural economy to an
industrialized economy, and then to a service-oriented economy, can
account for some of these differences. In particular, he points to the
relatively low levels of agricultural productivity in poor countries as
a major source of income differences. Essentially, Restuccia argues that
cross-country differences in aggregate productivity and per capita
income can be attributed to differences in sectoral productivities
resulting in differences in resource allocation. Restuccia then surveys
theories that attribute differences in sectoral productivity to
distortions that lead to the inefficient allocation of resources across
production establishments. Restuccia's survey reflects how the
baseline neoclassical model of production can be modified to account for
heterogeneity in production, first at the industry level, then at the
establish-ment level. These modifications are matched to observations,
and we can see how much they contribute to differences in aggregate
output.
The four articles in this issue represent part of a research
program in macroeconomics that takes the basic stochastic growth model
with complete markets as its point of departure. Work in this research
program then adds various sources of frictions and heterogeneity on the
consumption and production side, including restrictions on the set of
available markets, and the ability of market participants to pledge to
repay debts. This procedure allows macroeconomists to evaluate the
contributions of the various features that allow model economies to
capture more dimensions of available empirical evidence relative to a
common benchmark model. Another line of research that is part of this
program, but is not addressed by these articles, departs from the
baseline growth model by introducing nominal price rigidities in order
to address monetary non-neutrality. (1) In fact, until the Great
Recession, research on the role of nominal price rigidities and monetary
policy institutions in particular, received more attention in
macroeconomics in general than did research on financial market
frictions. This ranking of different lines of research simply reflected
the historical experience with the U.S. economy and other advanced
economies: Apparent inflation-output tradeoffs were considered to be
much more important than financial-market instability. For example, in
the U.S. economy the stock market crash of 1987 had no appreciable
impact on the aggregate economy, and the boom in equity prices in the
1990s, with a subsequent crash in 2001, was followed by one of the
shallowest recessions in post-WWII history. For many macroeconomists,
the Great Recession changed the perception on how important financial
markets might be for the economy. Consequently, attention among
economists has shifted more toward the lines of research that emphasize
financial market frictions and that are described in this special issue.
The fact that economists continue to discuss the causes and consequences
of the Great Depression should, however, give one pause to expect any
time soon a coherent and generally accepted narrative of the Great
Recession and how it relates to the preceding collapse of the housing
bubble and the ensuing financial crisis. (2)
The views expressed do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
andreas.hornstein@rich.frb.org.
REFERENCES
Gali, Jordi. 2008. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business
Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Lo, Andrew W. Forthcoming. "Reading About the Financial
Crisis: A 21-Book Review." Journal of Economic Literature.
(1.) For an introduction, see Gall (2008).
(2.) Lo (forthcoming), in a very instructive survey of the
literature on the financial crisis, both by academics and journalists,
observes that no single narrative has yet emerged from that literature,
and that, even for a number of commonly accepted "stylized
facts" of the financial crisis, there is no clear cut empirical
evidence.