Strategic behavior in the tri-party repo market.
Ennis, Huberto M.
Repo contracts are a kind of collateralized loan that has become
predominant in the United States among large cash investors. There are
several types of repo contracts, such as bilateral
delivery-versuspayment repos, interdealer repos, and tri-party repos. A
significant portion of repo transactions in the United States take the
form of tri-party repos, where a third party (a clearing bank) provides
collateral management and settlement services to the borrower and the
lender. The tri-party segment of the U.S. repo market is the subject of
this article.
The tri-party repo market played a significant role during the
2007-2009 global financial crisis. Tri-party repos were, for example, a
major source of secured funding for Bear Sterns prior to its demise. In
March 2008, repo lenders in general, and tri-party repo counterparties
in particular, lost confidence in their ability to recoup loans to Bear
Stearns and, hence, refused to renew them, asking instead for immediate
repayment (Bernanke 2008). To avoid a failure, the Federal Reserve
facilitated the acquisition of Bear Stearns by the bank J.P. Morgan
Chase. The withdrawal of tri-party repo funding also played a role in
the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. As a result of the
events during the crisis, it is now widely believed that the tri-party
repo market is subject to serious vulnerability (see, for example,
Dudley [2009]). Attesting to this is the fact that in 2009 the New York
Fed asked a group of senior private U.S. bank officials to form a task
force "to address the weaknesses" in the infrastructure of the
tri-party repo market (Federal Reserve Bank of New York 2010). A broad
set of reforms are currently under way. (1)
In this article, we study a simple model of the tri-party repo
arrangement that allows us to capture in a parsimonious way some of the
strategic interactions that arise in this market. In our analysis, we
use standard non-cooperative game theory to uncover the basic mechanisms
that can create some of the vulnerabilities commonly attributed to the
tri-party repo market. We will show that a change in perceptions can
create a sudden coordinated withdrawal of lenders from this market.
Also, we will highlight the crucial role that the clearing bank plays in
this game of "withdrawing before the rest," which appears to
be a good representation of the situation that was present in the
tri-party repo market during the recent financial crisis.
A repo (repurchase agreement) transaction is a sale of an asset
that is combined with an agreement to repurchase the asset at a
pre-specified price on a later day. Effectively, it is equivalent to a
collateralized loan, where the loan is the amount paid for the initial
sale and the asset plays the role of collateral. Repayment of the loan
takes place at the repurchase time, with the interest rate being
implicit in the repurchase price. In a tri-party repo, a third
party--the tri-party agent--facilitates the transaction between the two
main parties, the lender (a cash investor such as a money market mutual
fund) and the borrower (a securities dealer such as the broker-dealer
arm of an investment bank). The tri-party agent provides custodial and
other services to the lender and efficient collateral assignment and
allocation tools to the borrower. Settlement happens entirely in the
books of the tri-party agent where both the borrower and the lender have
cash and securities accounts. Also, in many cases, the tri-party agent
(via the so-called "morning unwind") extends intraday credit
to the borrowers to give them access, during the day, to the securities
used as collateral overnight. In the United States, the tri-party agents
are the two clearing banks, Bank of New York Mellon and J.P. Morgan
Chase. (2)
The volume of repo transactions in the United States is large.
There are no official data covering the entire market but Gorton and
Metrick (forthcoming) estimate that its size peaked before the crisis at
a level that is in the same order of magnitude as the value of all the
assets held by U.S. commercial banks (approximately $12 trillion). The
tri-party repo segment of the market is large as well. The value of
securities financed in this way was around $1.7 trillion at the end of
2011, down from about $2.8 trillion in early 2008 (Federal Reserve Bank
of New York 2010). Furthermore, some large broker dealers, arguably of
systemic importance, finance large portions of their portfolios in this
market. While U.S. Treasury securities and agency mortgage-backed
securities (considered virtually riskless) are the most common class of
assets used as collateral in tri-party repos, equities and other fixed
income securities are also sometimes used. According to some estimates,
at its peak in early 2008, about 30 percent of the assets used as
collateral were subject to non-negligible liquidity risk (Federal
Reserve Bank of New York 2010). (3)
The amount of the loan in a repo transaction is often lower than
the value of the posted collateral. In other words, the value of the
collateral gets discounted and this discount is commonly referred to as
a "haircut." Haircuts are aimed at reducing the exposure of
the lending side to liquidation costs in case the borrower defaults (see
Gorton and Metrick 2010). In principle, choosing the appropriate haircut
would leave the repo transaction free of virtually any repayment risk.
This is the case because repo transactions are generally exempt from the
automatic stay that applies to debt under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code. This
implies that the lender side in a repo transaction can take possession
of the collateral immediately upon failure of the borrower. (4)
Data on haircuts for different types of repos is limited. However,
the available evidence suggests that the level and sensitivity of
haircuts depend on the kind of repo transaction being considered. Gorton
and Metrick (2010, forthcoming), for example, study a sample of
interdealer repo transactions and show that the average haircut
increased significantly during the crisis. This is the manifestation of
what they call "the run on repos." Repos were used to finance
portfolios of securities and, as the haircuts increased, the capacity to
borrow against those securities decreased. The owners of the securities,
then, had to find alternative sources of funding or sell the securities
in the market. This deleveraging is tantamount to the liquidation of
loans that takes place in traditional bank runs.
In contrast, Copeland, Martin, and Walker (2010) show that
collateral haircuts in the tri-party repo market did not appear to
adjust in any meaningful way to changes in the riskiness of the
borrowers. The infrastructure that made tri-party repos attractive to
investors seems to have made it less convenient for them to adjust
collateral haircuts on a per-transaction basis. Instead, when the
financial conditions of a given dealer deteriorated, cash investors
tended to withdraw from dealing with such a dealer (PRC Task Force
2010). Evidence suggests that this behavior was predominant during the
events that led to the failure of Lehman Brothers (Copeland, Martin, and
Walker 2010). This way of reacting to counterparty credit risk in the
tri-party repo market is taken as a premise in this article and plays an
important role in the theoretical arguments advanced later. In
particular, we will investigate the problems that can arise in the
strategic interaction between the main players in this market given that
withdrawal from lending (and not adjustments of haircuts) constitutes
the typical reaction to a change in perceptions about the viability of
the borrowing side in the transaction.
Policymakers believe that a breakdown of the repo market can have
systemic consequences. In March 2008, after the collapse of Bear
Stearns, the Federal Reserve created the Primary Dealer Credit Facility
(PDCF) on the premise that "unusual and exigent" circumstances
justified the provision of emergency (collateralized) lending to large
securities dealers. The idea be?hind the PDCF was to provide backup
liquidity to dealers to give them time to arrange other sources of
funding if repo lenders were to suddenly withdraw from the market. The
program was designed as a backstop facility, charging a penalty rate on
tri-party repo transactions in which the Fed took the lending side (see
Adrian, Burke, and McAndrews 2009). Initially, only high-quality
collateral (investment-grade securities) was accepted in the PDCF. At
the time of the failure of Lehman Brothers, the Fed expanded collateral
acceptability to a broader set of assets and usage of the PDCF soared.
We will use our model to illustrate one possible role for a lending
facility such as the PDCF. However, a more careful assessment of the
suitable policy responses to the type of vulnerabilities highlighted in
this article is left for future research.
The article is organized as follows. In the rest of this section,
we describe the "morning unwind," a feature of the tri-party
repo market that is crucial for understanding the main strategic
interaction explored in this article. In Section 1, we set up a simple
model of the tri-party repo market and proceed to study the induced
strategic interaction between investors and the clearing bank using
standard tools in non-cooperative game theory. In Section 2, we discuss
some related issues that pertain to the functioning of the tri-party
repo market as presented in this article. Finally, Section 3 concludes.
The Morning Unwind
The maturity of most tri-party repo contracts is overnight, but
there are also contracts being arranged for a week, 30 days, and even
longer periods of time. A common practice in this market, however, is
that the clearing bank "unwinds" all repos, regardless of
maturity, at the beginning of each day (at around 8:00 a.m. EST).
The process of unwinding takes place as follows. Overnight, the
cash investor has the securities in its account at the clearing bank. As
part of an implicit arrangement, early in the morning (before the open
of Fedwire securities at 8:30 a.m. EST), the clearing bank transfers the
securities back from the investor's account to the dealer's
account, and transfers the corresponding cash to the investor (much like
in a cancellation of the repo). To finance the transfer of cash, the
clearing bank (normally) extends intraday credit to the dealer. In other
words, the investor gets a credit in its cash account at the bank and
the dealer gets a debit, which usually results in an intraday overdraft
of its cash account.
There are several reasons why it is convenient for investors and
dealers to have the repos unwound in the morning. Investors benefit from
having their cash available to make various payments and to satisfy
withdrawal demands placed by their clients during the day. Dealers
benefit from having access to the securities for the purpose of trading.
In fact, as a result of the trading activities of dealers, the
composition of their portfolio of securities changes during the day. If
some of the securities being used as collateral in outstanding repos are
sold, then they need to be substituted with new securities. This process
of collateral substitution is simpler if all the securities are
transferred to the dealer's account in the morning and only
reallocated back to repo contracts at the end of the day.
With the morning unwind, the tri-party repo contract constitutes a
loan based on the combination of two sources of funding: investors
covering the night and the clearing bank covering the day. As with the
overnight credit provided by investors, the intraday credit provided by
the clearing bank is secured by the securities held by the dealer in its
account at the bank. (5) In other words, if the dealer were to fail
during the day, after the unwind has occurred, then the clearing bank
would get ownership of the securities as a way to cancel the
dealer's overdraft. If, instead, the failure of the dealer were to
occur during the night, then investors would retain ownership of the
securities that served as collateral for the tri-party repo transaction.
The morning unwind, then, to the extent that it is financed with
the provision of intraday credit to dealers, exposes the clearing bank
to the risk of receiving ownership of a batch of securities upon the
failure of one (or more) of those dealers. (6) This unplanned increase
in assets of the clearing bank may create some extra costs associated
with balance sheet capacity (capital constraints, for example).
Furthermore, it is possible that part of the overdraft extended to the
dealer by the clearing bank is, in turn, being financed by an intraday
overdraft of the clearing bank on its account at the Fed. If the dealer
fails and the clearing bank cannot resell the securities by the end of
the day, it may incur an overnight overdraft at the Fed, which is much
more expensive, or it may need to borrow at the discount window. Aside
from being provided at a penalty rate, discount window borrowing may
also be associated with a stigma effect that can make such an activity
very costly for the clearing bank. (7) The risk of incurring these costs
is likely to be a crucial determinant of the willingness of the clearing
bank to unwind the repos every morning. The clearing bank retains the
right to refuse to unwind the repos of any particular dealer.
At the end of the day, tri-party repos are "rewound" and
cash investors are the party exposed to the risk of failure of the
dealer during the night. It is common for cash investors in tri-party
repos to accept certain securities that they are not allowed to hold
permanently in their portfolios. If the dealer were to fail during the
night, then, the cash investor would receive a batch of securities that
they would need to sell as soon as possible. Rush sales may result in
unfavorable prices (beyond the haircut applied to the collateral),
effectively exposing cash investors to financial losses.
It is important to realize here that the reason why the clearing
bank is (potentially) exposed to credit risk during the day is not
because of the process of unwinding the repos in the morning itself, but
because such unwinding is generally financed with intraday credit (an
overdraft) extended by the clearing bank to the dealer. If, every
morning, the dealer were to have enough cash in its account at the
clearing bank, then the unwinding would make the repo essentially a
secured debt contract with a half-day maturity. The only exposure in
that case would be on the lending side (cash investors) and only to the
extent that the haircut on the collateral is not enough to cover any
discount associated with selling the assets.
1. A SIMPLE MODEL
The tri-party repo market in the United States is a complex system.
There are multiple participants facing diverse situations. Some of them
are always there, day after day, and some only participate occasionally.
The clearing banks, the main broker dealers, and some of the large cash
investors participate every day; one can suspect, then, that implicit
relationships and reputation, for example, play a significant role in
determining outcomes (Copeland, Martin, and Walker 2010). Dealing with
all these different dimensions formally is a challenging task and it may
not be the most illuminating approach. Instead, here, we will provide a
very simple environment that captures only some of the forces at play in
this market and we will use standard non-cooperative game theory to
analyze the strategic component associated with such a situation. (8)
The model is very simple. There are two time periods, t = 1, 2, and
three types of agents, a clearing bank, a securities dealer, and N cash
investors. At the beginning of period 1, each cash investor has an
endowment of c dollars and the dealer has the opportunity to invest 1
dollar in securities, which will pay 1 + [rho] at the end of period 2.
We allow for [rho] to be a random variable and consider the natural case
in which [rho] has a positive expected value. We also assume that Nc
> 1.
At the beginning of period 1, cash investors deposit (some of)
their cash at the clearing bank. Also at that time, the dealer can
request a 1 dollar intraday overdraft at the clearing bank to buy the
securities. The clearing bank may or may not agree to grant the
dealer's overdraft request.
At the end of period 1, the dealer needs to close the overdraft in
its account at the clearing bank. We assume that overnight overdrafts
are expensive enough to give the dealer incentives to do this. In order
to obtain the cash needed to fund the overdraft position, the dealer
arranges tri-party repos with cash investors using the securities as
collateral. The interest rate on the repos is taken parametrically and
denoted by r. (9)
If the dealer is not able to repo the securities, then it has to
sell the securities to pay back as much of the overdraft as possible. We
assume that securities sold before the end of period 2 only return a
portion of what was invested. In such a situation, then, the dealer gets
no return and the clearing bank experiences a loss equal to [y.sub.B]
> 0.
If the dealer is able to repo the securities, it closes the
overdraft at the bank, and the next morning the bank has to decide
whether or not to unwind the repos. If the bank decides not to unwind
the repos, then the dealer has no funding for the securities, it fails,
and investors take possession of the collateral. We also assume that
investors cannot hold the securities and need to sell them at a loss at
the beginning of period 2. In such a case, again, the dealer gets no
return and investors experience a loss equal to [y.sub.1] > 0. The
dealer stops being a customer of the bank at that point and the bank
gets no payoff from the transaction.
If the bank agrees to unwind the repos instead, the dealer gets a
new daylight overdraft in its bank account and investors get their cash
and interest back. At the end of the day, the securities pay off and the
revenue is used by the dealer to close the overdraft and pay a fee
[empty set] to the bank.
Note that the initial overdraft could be thought of as the result
of the unwinding of a (set of) pre-existing repo contract(s). In that
sense, we could think that our simple framework is able to handle two
rounds of unwinding, to the extent that the decision to unwind, in this
model, will be exclusively driven by forward-looking considerations.
This interpretation of the initial overdraft will be useful when we
discuss some of the results.
Since we are assuming that Nc > I, investors' initial
endowment would be enough to (fully) fund the investment opportunity of
the dealer. The way this funding is channeled from investors to dealers
is via the clearing bank. The clearing bank receives an initial deposit
d [less than or equal to] Nc from investors and then grants a daylight
overdraft to the dealer. If d > 1, then, on the books of the clearing
bank, the overdraft (loan) to the dealer is (fully) funded by the
deposit of investors. However, if investors do not deposit all of their
endowment at the bank and d < 1, then initial funding for the dealer
could still be available. At the beginning of period 1, the bank obtains
daylight credit from the central bank in the amount 1 - d. Later in the
period, when (and if) the dealer secures repo funding from investors,
the corresponding cash that closes the negative position of the dealer
can be used by the bank to close its negative position with the central
bank. In this way, the bank can avoid a more expensive overnight
overdraft at the central bank.
Finally, notice that we have simplified the dealer's side of
the problem by assuming that whenever funding is not forthcoming, the
dealer fails. This strategy allows us to concentrate our attention on
the interaction between investors and the clearing bank. (10)
Furthermore, when the dealer fails and the securities need to be
liquidated before the end of period 2, the proceeds from the sale are
not enough to cover the total value of the loan--the lender suffers
losses. In effect, this is a direct counterpart of postulating that
insufficient haircuts are applied to the collateral. As discussed in the
introduction, the evidence described in Copeland, Martin, and Walker
(2010) suggests that this is a reasonable approach to take.
The Non-Cooperative Game
The key strategic interaction in the model is between the clearing
bank and the set of investors. To study the outcome from this
interaction we can use the tools of non-cooperative game theory. In
particular, we will concentrate our attention here on the implied formal
game played between the bank and investors.
Let us start with the case when N = 1 and [rho] = H [member of]
[R.sub.+] (i.e., p is a given number greater than zero, not a random
variable). Assume that H > [empty set] + r. The extensive form
representation of this game, which we call Game 1, appears in Figure 1.
The game starts in node 1 (represented by an open circle in the figure)
with the move by the clearing bank, who has to decide whether to grant
the dealer a daylight overdraft (O) or not (NO). After that, if an
overdraft is granted, the investor has to decide whether to enter a repo
contract with the dealer (R) or not (NR). This is the decision presented
in node 2. Finally, if a repo contract is arranged, then the bank has to
decide, in node 4, whether to unwind the repo (U) or not (NU) the next
morning. In each of the terminal nodes (nodes 3, 5, 6, and 7) the
payoffs of the players are listed in a column, with the top element
representing the payoff for the clearing bank (the first player to move)
and the bottom element representing the payoff of the investor. We use
the variables [x.sub.i] with i = B, I to represent the payoffs to the
bank (B) and the investor (I) in the case where an unwinding of the repo
happens on the morning of date 2. From our description of the model
above, we know that [x.sub.B] = [empty set] and [x.sub.I] = r. In a less
stylized setup, xi could be equal to something more complicated, but the
basic results from the strategic interaction will be the same as long as
the conditions on xi and .vi established below still hold.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
We look for a subgame perfect Nash (SPN) equilibrium of this game.
Since Game 1 is a finite game of perfect information, an equilibrium
always exists, and, given the payoffs, it is easy to see that the
equilibrium is actually unique (see, for example, Osborne and Rubinstein
[1994]).
Proposition 1 There is a unique SPN equilibrium of Game 1 for which
the equilibrium actions are (0, R, U).
Proof. As is standard with dynamic games, we proceed by solving
backward. First, consider the decision of the bank in the subgame that
starts at node 4, that is, after investors have agreed to repo the
securities. If the bank unwinds the repos, then it gets a payoff equal
to [x.sub.B], which is greater than the payoff of zero obtained from not
unwinding. Then, the bank will agree to unwind the repos. We can now
write an auxiliary game tree that takes this result into account. This
is the tree represented in the left-hand side of Figure 2. Following the
same logic, we can now solve backward in this game to find that the
investor will agree to repo the securities because [x.sub.B] >
[-Y.sub.B]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Finally, we can draw an auxiliary tree that incorporates this last
result (on the right-hand side of Figure 2) and find that the bank will
agree to grant an overdraft since [x.sub.b] > 0. Hence, we have that
the bank will always play 0, then the investor will always play R, and
lastly the bank will always play U, which completes the proof of the
proposition.
When there is no uncertainty with respect to the long-term solvency
of the dealer and there is only one cash investor (or a well-coordinated
group of them), the dealer always receives funding from the clearing
bank (via daylight overdraft) and from the investor (via repo
transactions). There is no instability associated with the tri-party
repo contract in this case.
Uncertainty over the Dealer's Solvency
Suppose now that [rho] is, in fact, a random variable that can take
value H > 1 with probability [xi] and-L with probability 1 -[xi] We
associate the outcome [rho] = -L with a situation where the dealer
experiences a solvency problem not triggered by the actions of the
participants in the tri-party repo market. (11) We will consider two
cases: one where the game is played without the investor or the bank
knowing the realization of the random variable [rho], and the other
where the bank gets to know the realization of [rho] before deciding
whether or not to unwind the repos the morning of date 2.
Uninformed clearing bank
In this first case, both the bank and the investor, when making
decisions, share the same degree of uncertainty about the expected
performance of the dealer. The structure of the game is almost exactly
the same as in Game 1, except that the payoff to the bank in terminal
node 6 is now given by [xi][x.sub.B] + (1 - [xi])(-[f.sub.b]) where
[f.sub.B] is the loss to the exposed bank when the dealer fails. We call
this Game 2a. Note that the payoff to the repo investor in node 6 is
still equal to [x.sub.1] since the unwinding of the repos occurs as in
normal circumstances in that branch of the tree. Basically, the idea is
that with some probability, the bank finds out that the dealer is
insolvent after unwinding the repos and hence is left with a loss equal
to [f.sub.B] = L + r in our mode1. (12)
Proposition 2 Define fit [bar.[[xi].sub.a]] [equivalent to]
[f.sub.B]/([x.sub.B] + [f.sub.B]). If [xi] > [bar.[[xi].sub.a]], then
there is a unique SPN equilibrium of Game 2a for which the equilibrium
actions are (0, R, U).
The proof of the proposition follows the same logic as the proof of
Proposition 1, so we do not repeat it here. If the probability of the
dealer not experiencing a solvency problem is high enough (i.e., if [xi]
is high enough), then the dealer will get funding from the bank and from
the cash investor. However, if the probability is below the threshold
value [bar.[[xi].sub.a]], then the unique SPN equilibrium has the bank
playing NO in node 1 and the dealer does not obtain funding in such a
situation. (13) We could summarize this result as saying that those
dealers who are perceived as "fragile" will not get funded.
It is interesting to note that the bank plays NO when [xi] <
[bar.[[xi].sub.a]], because it anticipates that the investor will not be
willing to enter into a repo agreement at the end of the day to finance
the dealer. The investor, in turn, does not agree to participate in the
repo because it anticipates that the bank will not be willing to unwind
the repos the next morning if the repos were outstanding. (14) This
anticipation game makes the tri-party repo market very sensitive to
changes in perceptions, not just about actual weaknesses of the dealer
being funded, but also about the perceptions of other players about
those weaknesses.
If we interpret the initial overdraft as (possibly) the result of
an unwinding of previously arranged repos, then the model says that if
the clearing bank places a high probability on the eventual failure of
the dealer the next day, the refusal to unwind will take place
immediately. This result suggests that the situation can potentially
unravel long before the actual failure of the dealer is expected to
occur, even if such failure is only regarded as a possibility (and not a
certainty).
A crucial issue left unexplored here is how the perception of the
probability of failure gets determined and how it changes over time.
What the theory here makes clear is that, once such probability has
crossed a certain threshold, the whole tri-party repo arrangement is
bound to immediately collapse.
Informed clearing bank
The second case we would like to consider in this section is the
case when the bank gets to know the realization of [rho] before deciding
whether or not to unwind the repos on the morning of date 2. We refer to
this game as Game 2b. The extensive form representation of this game is
provided in Figure 3 where nature moves at node 4. We denote by NF the
situation when the realized state of nature is such that [rho] = H, and
by F the situation when [rho] = -L. (15) The other new piece of notation
in Figure 3 is the payoff [f.sub.1], which is the loss experienced by
the repo investor when the repo is not unwound by the bank and [rho] =
-L. In principle, [f.sub.1] could be different than [y.sub.1] because
the liquidation value of the securities may depend on the state of
nature.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Proposition 3 Define,[bar.[[xi].sub.b]] = [f.sub.1]/([x.sub.1] +
[f.sub.1]). If [xi] >,[bar.[[xi].sub.b]], then there is a unique SPN
equilibrium of Game 2b for which the equilibrium actions are (O, R, U if
[rho] = R, NU if [rho] = L).
Proof. First note that in the proper subgame that starts at node 6,
the bank should agree to unwind the repos, and in the one that starts in
node 7, the bank should not unwind the repos. Now, using backward
induction, we can construct the reduced game where nodes 6 and 7 are
terminal nodes and the payoffs are the ones associated with nodes 8 and
11 in the full game. Given that nature moves according to the
probability [xi], we have that the payoff for the investor from playing
R is equal to [xi]-[x.sub.1] + (1 - [xi])(-[f.sub.1]). Also, the payoff
for the bank after playing O and given that the investor is playing R is
[xi][x.sub.B]. Now, again, using backward induction, we can construct a
reduced game with node 4 as a terminal node and the associated payoffs
being {[xi][x.sub.B], [xi][x.sub.1] + (1 - [xi])([-f.sub.1])}. Clearly,
if [xi] >, [bar.[[xi].sub.b]], the investor wants to play R and,
given this, the bank wants to play O (since [xi][x.sub.B] > 0).
If [xi] < [bar.[[xi].sub.b]], the investor will want to play NR
when node 2 is reached and, anticipating this, the bank will want to
play NO. Thus, if[xi] < [bar.[[xi].sub.b]], the dealer will not
obtain the initial overdraft funding from the bank and no repo will be
ultimately arranged.
The logic behind these results is clear. The cash investor
anticipates that the bank will be able to infer somehow, before the
unwinding of the repos, the future performance of the dealer. If the
investor believes that it is very likely that the bank will find out
that the dealer is bound to fail (and hence that the bank will not
unwind the repos), then the investor will not be willing to agree to the
repo transaction. In turn, anticipating this, the bank will not grant an
initial overdraft to the dealer and the whole tri-party repo arrangement
collapses.
Here, again, we can loosely interpret the initial overdraft as the
result of unwinding previously arranged tri-party repos. In this
informal interpretation, the crucial element for such a story to work is
that there must have been a change in perceptions about the situation of
the dealer after repo contracts were arranged prior to the beginning of
Game 2b. In particular, right at the beginning of Game 2b, it must be
the case that all the participants in the tri-party repo arrangement
realized that the dealer actually has a probability of success (the next
day) smaller than the threshold [bar.[[xi].sub.b]] and that the bank
will be able to find out whether or not the dealer will fail before the
unwinding takes place the following day. If this is the case, then the
tri-party repo arrangement immediately collapses, not at the time when
the failure of the dealer is expected to occur but when the perceptions
about that failure actually change (which could very well be much
sooner, as the game illustrates).
Discussion
It is interesting to compare the results in Propositions 2 and 3.
Note that the thresholds are increasing in the size of the loss if the
dealer fails, and they are decreasing in the size of the gain if funding
is granted and the dealer does not fail. This is true for both
thresholds, although in Proposition 2 the relevant payoffs are those of
the bank and in Proposition 3, those of the cash investor. The reason
for this difference is the fact that in Game 2a the bank is playing the
role of creditor at the time when the dealer fails, while in the case of
Game 2b the bank finds out whether or not the dealer will fail before
unwinding the repos, and if the dealer is actually expected to fail,
then investors will be the party exposed to losses.
This difference in the threshold values has implications for the
relationship between fragility and information flows in the tri-party
repo market. We can interpret a situation with a lower threshold value
as a situation where the tri-party repo arrangement is more likely to
survive shifts in participants' perceptions. The idea is that the
creditor will accept to stay in the transaction even after larger
increases in the perceived probability of failure 1 - [xi] when the
threshold value is lower. Then, if we think that cash investors have
less to gain from the repo contract and more to lose relative to the
bank--so that the threshold [bar.[[xi].sub.a]] >
[bar.[[xi].sub.b]]--a situation where everybody anticipates that the
bank will be able to obtain information about the solvency conditions of
the dealer before the morning unwind (as in Proposition 3) would result
in a more fragile tri-party repo market. In such a situation, it is
worth noticing, increasing the haircuts applied to the collateral will
tend to reduce the loss [f.sub.1], reduce the threshold value
[bar.[[xi].sub.b]], and, in this way, improve the stability of the repo
market.
In the simple formal game we have studied in this section, the
initial perceptions about the probability 4-are shared by all
participants and are correct in the sense of being equal to the actual
objective probability associated with the random variable [rho]. This
stark information structure hides the fact that the crucial driver of
behavior in this strategic situation is the perception that the bank has
about the perception of investors about the probability of failure of
the dealer. Notice that, in fact, the bank would be willing to grant the
initial overdraft to the dealer regardless of the bank's perception
of the probability [xi], as long as the bank expects that investors will
be willing to repo the securities later in the day. Whether or not
investors will be willing to repo the securities depends only on the
perception that those investors (and not the bank) have about [xi]. So,
if the bank thinks that investors are optimistic about the dealer, then,
even if the bank is not, the bank will be willing to grant the initial
overdraft. This is the case because the bank will get to know whether or
not the dealer will fail before unwinding the repos in the morning of
the second date and, hence, can effectively get out of the deal without
experiencing any losses.
We have considered here the case of only one cash investor with no
interim information. However, it would be more realistic to have many
investors, each getting some partial information about the solvency
condition of the dealer. Because the clearing bank observes the actions
of investors in the tri-party repo market, it has a vantage point to
aggregate all the dispersed information available to investors and
hence, to some degree, anticipate the potential failure of the
particular dealer. In other words, after the round of repos during the
day, the bank is likely to become better informed about the situation of
the dealer. The structure of Game 2b attempts to capture the gist of
this situation by having the bank become perfectly informed before
deciding whether or not to undertake the morning unwind.
Having more than one investor makes the game more complicated and
can produce other interesting insights. In particular, the issue of
coordination among multiple investors is key to understanding the
sources of possible fragility in the tri-party repo market. We discuss
some of those issues in the following sections. The analysis in this
section applies to a situation where investors can (somehow) perfectly
coordinate their actions and play R whenever such a move benefits all of
them.
Before we move on to discuss potential coordination issues, it is
worth mentioning an interesting implication coming out of the structure
of Game 2b. In situations such as the one captured by the timing in that
game, any measure aimed at reducing the potential losses of a clearing
bank will not change the resiliency of the tri-party repo market. If the
clearing bank (by obtaining independent information or by inferring
information from the behavior of investors) can (fully) anticipate the
failure of any particular dealer before the morning unwind, then the
bank is effectively not exposed to actual losses (i.e., the value of
[f.sub.B] is irrelevant for equilibrium, as long as it is positive).
Hence, any attempt at reducing a clearing bank's potential losses
will not have a material effect on the behavior of the market.
Coordination in the Repo Market
Suppose that there are N = 2 cash investors and that, at the
beginning of date 2, these investors play a simultaneous move game to
decide whether or not to agree to enter repo contracts with the dealer.
Also assume that if only one of the two investors agrees to a repo, then
the dealer stops operations and the investor that entered the repo
agreement experiences a loss equal to [z.sub.1]. The extensive form
representation of this game, which we call Game 3, is given in Figure 4.
(16)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The encircled decision nodes 4 and 5 constitute a single
information set for the investor moving in those nodes. This is the
result of the fact that investors play simultaneously and, hence, each
investor does not know if the other investor has played R or NR at the
time that he has to decide what to play (that is, the investor does not
know if he is in node 4 or in node 5, respectively). As before, we look
for a SPN equilibrium of Game 3.
Proposition 4 There are two pure-strategy SPN equilibria of Game 3;
in one the dealer gets funded and in the other it does not.
Proof. Note that the branch of the game tree that starts at node 6
is indeed a proper subgame of this game. Clearly, if play reaches node
6, then the bank should agree to unwind the repos (i.e., play U) at that
point. Using backward induction, we can substitute the payoff from node
10 at node 6 and consider the reduced game that results after this first
iteration. In this reduced game (and in the complete game), there is one
proper subgame that starts at node 2. In fact, this subgame has the
structure of a coordination game between investors and has two
pure-strategy Nash equilibria: (R, R) and (NR, NR) (Figure 5 depicts the
normal-form representation of this coordination game).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
As a result of this multiplicity, the full game actually has two
pure-strategy SPN equilibria, one where investors play (R, R) if the
proper subgame starting at node 2 is reached, and another where
investors play (NR, NR) if this subgame is reached. In the first case,
when both investors agree to enter repo transactions, the bank will be
willing to grant an overdraft (i.e., play 0) in node 1. The equilibrium
actions will then be (0, {R, R}, U) and the equilibrium payoffs will be
([x.sub.B], [x.sub.1], [x.sub.1]).
In the other case, when investors play (NR,NR), we have that the
bank will not agree to initially grant the overdraft and the equilibrium
payoffs are equal to zero for all players since the dealer does not get
funded from the outset.
The equilibrium in which the bank does not agree to grant the
dealer an overdraft in node 1 captures in a stylized way a source of
potential fragility in the tri-party repo market. If the clearing bank
expects that, because of what amounts to a coordination failure, cash
investors in the afternoon will not be willing to fund the securities
dealer via repo transactions, then the bank will not be willing to grant
an overdraft to the dealer in the morning. Recall that, for all
practical purposes, the overdraft could originate on an initial request
for funding by a dealer or as the result of the unwinding of outstanding
repo transactions. In this sense, then, the model underscores the
fragility associated with the daily unwinding of repo transactions that
are financed with daylight overdrafts on the accounts that securities
dealers have at their clearing banks.
Note here that all agents in the model prefer that the equilibrium
in which the dealer gets funded be played at all times. However, because
of the possibility of a coordination failure among investors, it is
consistent with rational play and equilibrium that the dealer not be
funded. Martin, Skeie, and von Thadden (2010) call such a situation a
repo run. One way to deal with this problem would be to have the central
bank provide backstop liquidity in the repo market, as the Federal
Reserve did with the PDCF. In such a situation, investors would get
payoff xi from choosing R, independent of what the other investor is
choosing. This change in the structure of payoffs makes (R, R) the
unique equilibrium of the game, and the dealer always gets funded. The
key to this result is that the policy intervention changes the game
among investors so that it is no longer a coordination game. (17)
Interestingly, in the model, the PDCF would not be tapped by investors
in equilibrium, even though it is essential for ruling out the
possibility of coordination failures and, in this way, stabilizing the
market.
Martin, Skeie, and von Thadden (2010) (see, also, Copeland, Martin,
and Walker I 2010J) consider the game played by investors in the case
when there is no "morning unwind." In the context of their
model, they show that the investors' game is no longer a
coordination game and, hence, runs can no longer happen. Their model is
different, yet related to the model presented here. In particular, they
consider the case where there are old and new investors playing the
game. Then, the result relies on the assumption that, without the
unwind, the dealer gets to observe whether or not it will fail before
making any payments to existing (old) investors. This removes the
incentives of existing investors to run, even if no new investor is
willing to fund the dealer. But, when existing investors do not run, the
dealer can withstand a run by new investors, which removes the
incentives for new investors to run.
One way to obtain a similar result in our setup is by assuming
that, barring daylight credit from the clearing bank, the dealer needs
to arrange repo funding before making any investments. Also, let us
assume that the dealer goes ahead with the investment only if it is able
to convince both investors to fund the operation. In this situation, the
payoff to an investor that agrees to enter a repo contract, when the
other investor does not, is the same as the payoff from not entering a
repo contract; i.e., it is equal to zero. Assuming, as Martin, Skeie,
and von Thadden (2010) do, that in case of indifference an investor
agrees to repo, we have that the "unique" equilibrium in the
investors' game is to play (R, R), and the dealer always gets
funded.
Correlated Equilibrium
In the SPN equilibria of Proposition 4, the clearing bank in the
morning has no doubts about the events that will take place during the
afternoon when the cash investors have to decide whether or not to fund
the securities dealer: Either the bank anticipates that funding from
cash investors will be broadly available or it anticipates that no
investor will be accepting repo requests. In principle, however, the
bank may not be sure about the availability of funding in the afternoon.
A simple representation of this uncertainty can be accomplished by using
the alternative equilibrium concept of correlated equilibrium. (18)
In particular, suppose that at the time when investors have to
decide whether or not to fund the dealer in the afternoon of the first
date, they observe a public signal that can take two possible values:
[alpha] with probability [pi], and [beta] with probability 1 - [pi].
Suppose also that, when investors observe a, they play the equilibrium
with actions (R, R), and when they observe [beta], they play the
equilibrium with actions (NR, NR). The bank, instead, does not observe
the public signal at the time when it has to decide whether or not to
allow the dealer to incur an overdraft on its account at the bank.
Proposition 5 Define [bar.[pi]] [equivalent to] [y.sub.B]
([x.sub.B] + [y.sub.B]). If [pi] [greater than or equal to] [bar.[pi]],
then there is a correlated equilibrium in which the bank plays 0 in node
I of Game 3. If [pi] < [bar.[pi]] then there is a correlated
equilibrium in which the bank plays NO in node I.
The proof of the proposition is very similar to the other proofs
and is not included here. We can interpret it as the clearing
bank's perception of the likelihood that the dealer will obtain
funding in the afternoon. If the probability is high enough, above the
threshold [bar.[pi]], then the bank will agree to grant an overdraft.
Note that, after the bank allows for the overdraft, with probability 1 -
[pi], investors do not agree to fund the dealer in the afternoon and the
clearing bank is stuck with the securities that served as collateral for
the overdraft. In such case, the bank suffers a loss given by [y.sub.B].
Note that, as the loss increases, the threshold value [bar.[pi]]
increases and gets closer to unity. In other words, as the loss for the
clearing bank becomes larger, the bank needs to be more and more certain
that investors will fund the dealer in the afternoon if an overdraft is
to be granted in the morning. We can think that a lower [pi] represents
a situation where confidence in the ability of the dealer to participate
in the repo market decreases. If the situation deteriorates enough, to
the point when [pi] gets below the threshold [bar.[pi]], then the
clearing bank will not agree to grant an overdraft (or unwind previously
arranged repo transactions by granting the dealer daylight credit).
Note that, in contrast to the situation described in the previous
subsection, here the payoff of the bank in case the dealer defaults
after the morning unwind is relevant for the outcomes of the game. In
the equilibrium of Proposition 5, the clearing bank retains some
uncertainty about the ability of the dealer to obtain repo funding in
the afternoon of date 1. The key to this result is that the public
signal is only observed after the morning unwind and, hence, it creates
the potential for a sudden shift in the behavior of investors in the
afternoon repo market. Coordination failures are, perhaps, more likely
to happen abruptly since they are based only on changes in the beliefs
of market participants about the behavior of other market participants.
Instead, changes in behavior driven by fundamentals, such as the ones
studied in Propositions 2 and 3, are more likely to happen gradually
over time, allowing the clearing bank to potentially exploit its
informational advantage.
For concreteness, we have considered here a situation with only two
investors. However, in general, there could be many more cash investors.
(19) An alternative formalization would be to have a continuum of
investors deciding at the end of date 1 whether or not to fund the
dealer via repo transactions. In such case, it is clear that the
decision of any one investor will not have a material consequence on the
overall ability of the dealer to fund itself. In other words, if an
investor enters a repo contract with a dealer when all the other
investors do not, then the dealer will indeed fail and the investor with
the repo contract will be stuck with the securities. The structure of
payoffs that implies a coordination game arises more naturally in this
case, relative to the case where there are only two investors. However,
given our assumptions on payoffs, the results would be basically the
same in both cases.
2. DISCUSSION
From the perspective of cash investors, the tri-party repo contract
is almost equivalent to an interest-bearing demand deposit. Because of
the daily unwind, investors have access to their cash during the day (on
demand). During the night, the cash is locked in with the repo
transaction. The next morning, the contract entitles the investor to a
positive interest payment. In an uninsured demand deposit contract,
investors are exposed to counterparty credit risk. In contrast, the
tri-party repo contract could be considered, in principle, a form of
secured lending since there is collateral pledged to address default
risk. Haircuts on the collateral could be set so as to leave the lender
with virtually no exposure to credit risk. However, in reality, evidence
suggests that cash investors still perceive themselves as being exposed
to some risk of losses when the borrower defaults (see, for example,
Copeland, Martin, and Walker [2010] and PRC Task Force [2010]). We have
taken the possibility of losses as a premise for our model, without
trying to explain the fundamental reasons for under-collateralization.
Understanding how this arrangement could arise optimally is not an easy
task. Lacker (2001) provides a framework to think about collateralized
debt that could be used to address these kinds of issues (see, also,
Dang, Gorton, and Holmstrom [2010]). More work is clearly needed in this
area.
In the United States, paying interest on demand deposits was not
allowed until very recently. This restriction was especially binding for
businesses. However, the financial system has developed some
alternatives that constitute close substitutes of interest-bearing
demand deposits. The tri-party repo arrangement could be considered one
such alternative. The newly enacted Dodd-Frank financial reform
legislation includes a provision that repeals the prohibition of paying
interest on demand deposits and, starting on July 21, 2011, banks are
now allowed to pay interest on these accounts. It is an open question
how this will impact the tri-party repo market in the long run. It seems
plausible that some cash investors looking for a way to earn interest on
their cash holdings overnight may now turn to demand deposits at banks
for this purpose. But, of course, there is a demand as well as a supply
side in the tri-party repo market. On the demand side, securities
dealers will still need to fund their portfolios of securities. Some
form of repo contract is likely to play a role in satisfying that
demand.
As we have explained, the source of funding for tri-party repos is
twofold: during the night, cash investors provide the funding and,
during the day, daylight overdrafts granted by the clearing banks
provide (most of) the funding. Some (if not most) of the cash owned by
cash investors does not leave the books of the clearing bank during the
day. Those funds are effectively demand deposits held by cash investors
in their accounts at the clearing bank. These deposits, then, can be
used by the clearing bank to fund the daylight credit provided to the
dealers as part of the tri-party repo contract. But, to the extent that
some of the cash owned by investors is used during the day to make
payments and other transfers, the clearing bank needs to obtain daylight
funding for the overdraft granted to the dealers. Of course, one readily
available source of daylight funding for clearing banks is their
daylight overdraft capabilities with the Federal Reserve. If we think
that the rate charged by the Fed for daylight credit is intentionally
kept low ("to ensure the smooth functioning of payment and
settlement systems"), then we could conclude that, to a certain
extent, the tri-party repo arrangement is an indirect way for dealers to
access subsidized funding during the day. (20)
With its simplified treatment of the events associated with a
dealer's default, our formal analysis could not be used to address
some significant issues being discussed in policy circles (see, for
example, Copeland et al. [2011]). For example, the possibility that the
liquidation of a dealer's portfolio could result in fire sale
prices and externalities to other dealers (and to market participants in
general) was left unexplored. (21) Another important issue that was not
examined here is the possibility of "a loss of confidence" in
the solvency of a clearing bank. This was a major concern for
policymakers during the crisis and has been a salient point in the
discussions about possible reforms to the infrastructure in the
tri-party repo market (Bernanke 2008). Each clearing bank in the United
States provides services to multiple dealers and to a large number of
investors. To some extent, dealers need the clearing bank for their
daily operation. It seems plausible, then, that problems at a clearing
bank could spread to its client dealers if, for example, those dealers
were relying on daylight credit to stay in business. Furthermore, cash
investors usually have large unsecured exposures to their clearing bank
during the day that could also destabilize them if that cash were no
longer readily available. These are important issues that deserve
careful consideration and are certainly related to the subject of this
article. Here, however, we chose to keep the model simple on these
dimensions to be able to sharpen our understanding of the strategic
interaction between the clearing bank and investors, which may play a
crucial role in the functioning of this complex market during a crisis.
In May 2010, the Tri-Party Repo Infrastructure Reform Task Force
issued a set of recommendations to increase the stability of this market
(PRC Task Force 2010). Their main proposal was to reform the system in
order to reduce as much as possible the reliance of market participants
on large amounts of intraday credit provided by clearing banks. In
short, the proposal calls for an elimination of the indiscriminate daily
unwind of all tri-party repo trades. Evidently, reducing the credit
exposure of the clearing banks will limit the power of some of the
strategic interactions highlighted in this article. However, if the
morning unwind creates some valuable operational advantages that make
the tri-party repo contract especially attractive to dealers and
investors, then an obvious tradeoff arises between stability and
effectiveness. (22) In such a case, fragility is not to be combated at
all costs. As in many other situations where a risk-return frontier
results in a tradeoff, the optimal arrangement could very well involve
actually tolerating some positive risk.
There are also other alternatives that have been considered to
limit this source of fragility in the tri-party repo market. For
example, a system of capital requirements and risk charges that
penalizes the intraday exposure of the clearing banks may give the
appropriate incentives to participants, inducing them to move away from
their over-reliance on intraday credit from the clearing banks (Tuckman
2010). Similarly, changes in the treatment of repos under bankruptcy
law, such as removing them from the exception to the automatic stay (Roe
2009), could make these contracts less attractive and, hence, reduce the
size of this potentially destabilizing market.
As the process of evaluating possible reforms continues, it is
important to keep in mind that many of the features of the tri-party
repo contract that we observe in the data are contingent on a set of
rules (and common practices) that existed when the data was collected.
If some of those rules are changed (by fiat or by newly built consensus
among major participants), then some prevalent characteristics of the
existing contract may also change. A case in point is the distribution
of maturity terms in the market. Currently, term trades represent 10
percent to 40 percent of the market (PRC Task Force 2010). To the extent
that participants stop perceiving the morning unwind as an automatic
event for repos of longer maturities, it seems plausible that an even
higher proportion of the outstanding repos will become overnight
contracts. This may seem a fairly obvious point, yet it clearly
highlights the limitations of evaluating the effects of possible changes
in policies using only historical data. To complement our data analysis,
we need to develop better models of the tri-party repo market that can
allow us to conduct policy evaluations in a more meaningful way. The
alternative is a costly process of trial and error purely based on
experience in the actual market. Considering the current importance of
this market, pushing forward a model-based agenda for studying this
market seems worthwhile. The model introduced in this article is an
attempt to take a preliminary step in this direction.
3. CONCLUSION
In this article, we study a simple model of the strategic
interaction between investors and the clearing bank in the tri-party
repo market. In order to be able to apply simple game theory techniques
to the problem, we abstract from many important features of this complex
market. We mention several of them along the way in the presentation.
Clearly, a lot more work is needed to extend the formal analysis in ways
that would allow us to evaluate the role, and the relative importance,
of those various features left unexplored here.
Perhaps the aspect most clearly highlighted by the model in this
article is the role in the inception of a crisis played by
participants' anticipation of each others' perceptions and
actions. In particular, the model eloquently illustrates how changes in
expectations about future events and actions can make a crisis happen
abruptly before the fundamental factors behind it visibly manifest
themselves. We conclude, then, that swings in perceptions (about
fundamentals or about market confidence) can, in principle, trigger
sudden crises in the tri-party repo market.
REFERENCES
Acharya, Viral V., and S. Viswanathan. 2011. "Leverage, Moral
Hazard, and Liquidity." Journal of Finance 66 (February): 99-138.
Adrian, Tobias, Christopher R. Burke, and James J. McAndrews. 2009.
"The Federal Reserve's Primary Dealer Credit Facility."
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance
15 (August).
Armantier, Olivier, Eric Ghysels, Asani Sarkar, and Jeffrey
Shrader. 2011. "Stigma in Financial Markets: Evidence from
Liquidity Auctions and Discount Window Borrowing during the
Crisis." Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 483
(January).
Bernanke, Ben S. 2008. "Financial Regulation and Financial
Stability." Speech at the FDIC Forum on Mortgage Lending for Low
and Moderate Income Households. Arlington, Va., July 8.
Copeland, Adam, Antoine Martin, and Michael Walker. 2010. "The
Tri-Party Repo Market before the 2010 Reforms." Federal Reserve
Bank of New York Staff Report 477 (November).
Copeland, Adam, Darrell Duffie, Antoine Martin, and Susan
McLaughlin. 2011. "Policy Issues in the Design of Tri-Party Repo
Markets." Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Dang, Tri Vi, Gary Gorton, and Bengt Holmstrom. 2010.
"Financial Crises and the Optimality of Debt for Liquidity
Provision." Unpublished manuscript, Yale University.
Dudley, William C. 2009. "More Lessons from the Crisis."
Remarks at the Center for Economic Policy Studies (CEPS) Symposium.
Princeton, N. J., November 13.
Duffie, Darrell. 2010. "The Failure Mechanics of Dealer
Banks." Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (Winter): 51-72.
Ennis, Huberto M., and John A. Weinberg. 2010.
"Over-the-Counter Loans, Adverse Selection, and Stigma in the
Interbank Market." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper
10-07 (April).
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2010. "Tri-Party Repo
Infrastructure Reform." Federal Reserve Bank of New York White
Paper (May 17).
Gorton, Gary, and Andrew Metrick. 2010. "Haircuts."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92 (November/December): 507-19.
Gorton, Gary B., and Andrew Metrick. Forthcoming. "Securitized
Banking and the Run on Repo." Journal of Financial Economics.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. 2001. "Collateralized Debt as the Optimal
Contract." Review of Economic Dynamics 4 (October): 842-59.
Lubben, Stephen J. 2010. "The Bankruptcy Code Without Safe
Harbors." American Bankruptcy Law Journal 84 (Spring): 123.
Martin, Antoine, David Skeie, and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden. 2010.
"Repo Runs." Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report
444. (April).
Osborne, Martin J., and Ariel Rubinstein. 1994. A Course in Game
Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press.
PRC Task Force. 2010. Report of the Payments Risk Committee Task
Force on Tri-party Repo Infrastructure. (May 17)
Roe, Mark. 2009. "End Bankruptcy Priority for Derivatives,
Repos and Swaps." Financial Times, December 16.
Tuckman, Bruce. 2010. "Systemic Risk and the Tri-Party Repo
Clearing Banks." CFS Policy Paper (February 2).
(1.) Implementation of the reforms have proven to be more difficult
than previously expected. On February 15, 2012, the New York Fed issue a
statement indicating that the vulnerabilities in this market still
persist.
(2.) In what follows, for the purpose of concreteness, we will
always call the lender in the tri-party repo the (cash) investor, and we
will call the borrower the (securities) dealer. The tri-party agent will
be called the clearing bank, or sometimes just the bank, for short.
(3.) Up-to-date information on the composition of collateral in the
tri-party repo market can be found at www.newyorkfed.org/tripartyrepo/.
(4.) The repo exemption from the stay is likely to extend to the
case of the failure of a broker dealer, as explained by Copeland,
Martin, and Walker (2010, Appendix C). There is an ongoing debate about
the appropriateness of granting safe-harbor exemptions from the
automatic stay to a broad range of derivative transactions, including
repos. See, for example, Roe (2009) and Lubben (2010).
(5.) The clearing bank has a lien on the dealer's collateral
structured as a repo with broad flexibility for collateral substitution.
When the dealer sells (delivery versus payment) a security during the
day, the cash received as payment cancels out the part of the overdraft
that is no longer collateralized because of the sale of the security.
When a dealer delivers a security free of payment, the clearing bank is
protected by its "right of offset" on all the securities that
the dealer has at the clearing bank, including those that were not used
in tri-party repo transactions.
(6.) The ongoing reorganization of the market intends to reduce the
predominance of the automatic "morning unwind" practice. See
PRC Task Force (2010) for details. However, in the statement issued on
February 15, 2012, the New York Fed said: "the amount of intraday
credit provided by clearing banks has not yet been meaningfully reduced,
and therefore, the systemic risk associated with this market remains
unchanged."
(7.) For recent work on the possibility of stigma at the discount
window see Ennis and Weinberg (2010) and Armantier et al. (2011).
(8.) See Duffle (2010) for a detailed description of the various
activities generally undertaken by broker dealers and the role that the
repo market plays in funding those activities.
(9.) In the United States, most tri-party repos are arranged in the
morning and settle in the books of the clearing bank late in the
afternoon, after the close of Fedwire securities. For the formal
representation of the problem, the only relevant aspect is that, each
day, new repo funding is arranged only after the morning unwind.
(10.) See Martin, Skeie, and von Thadden (2010) for a more fleshed
out formal treatment of the role of investors' decisions in
determining the fate of the dealer.
(11.) See Duffie (2010) for a thorough description of the various
factors that can contribute to the failure of a dealer bank.
(12.) The bank, at the time of unwinding the repos, grants an
overdraft to the dealer of size 1 + r. After the dealer fails, the
securities pay 1 - L and the bank gets the proceeds. Hence, the net loss
for the bank is equal to L + r.
(13.) Recall that in game theory, an equilibrium is a property of a
profile of strategies. A strategy is a complete contingent plan of play
for all possible circumstances in the game, not just the ones that occur
in equilibrium. For example, when [xi] < [bar.[[xi].sub.a]] the
equilibrium strategy of the bank is {NO, NU if the investor plays R} and
the equilibrium strategy of the investor is (NR if the bank plays O}. In
this article, we sometimes loosely describe equilibrium play by the
actions taken in equilibrium, just to keep the presentation simple.
(14.) Copeland, Martin, and Walker (2010) call this strategic
interaction "the hand-off of risk between investors and clearing
banks."
(15.) Osborne and Rubinstein (1994, 101) call games with this
structure extensive games with perfect information and chance moves.
(16.) Osborne and Rubinstein (1994, 102) call games with this
structure extensive games with perfect information and simultaneous
moves.
(17.) This role of the PDCF is highlighted by Adrian, Burke, and
McAndrews (2009) when they say: "The PDCF has the potential to
benefit trading in the repo market beyond the direct injection of
funding. The very existence of the facility is a source of reassurance
to the primary dealers and their customers." Dudley (2009) also
says that "the PDCF essentially placed the Fed in the role of the
tri-party repo investor of last resort thereby significantly reducing
the risk to the clearing banks that they might be stuck with the
collateral. As a consequence, the PDCF reassured end investors that they
could safely keep investing. This, in turn, significantly reduced the
risk that a dealer would not be able to obtain short-term funding
through the tri-party repo system."
(18.) There is also a mixed-strategy SPN equilibrium of Game 3 in
which investors randomize over actions R and NR, playing R with
probability [z.sub.1] /([x.sub.1]/ [z.sub.1]). In such an equilibrium,
the bank also faces uncertainty about the ability of the dealer to get
funding at the end of period 1. However, we find the interpretation of
this equilibrium less appealing and, for this reason, we do not discuss
it here.
(19.) Copeland, Martin, and Walker (2010) consider a coordination
game similar to the one studied here but where there are three investors
in the game. See also Martin, Skeie, and von Thadden (2010).
(20.) Currently, the Fed provides daylight credit to depository
institutions using a two-tiered fee schedule. Those institutions that
pledge enough acceptable collateral with their Reserve Bank receive
daylight credit (up to a cap) at no charge. Uncollateralized daylight
credit is charged a fee that is calculated per minute using an annual
rate of 50 basis points. This system was only recently introduced.
During the crisis, the Fed charged a uniform rate of 36 basis points for
intraday credit and this credit was all uncollateralized. For more
information on the current system see
www.federalreserve.gov/paymentsystems/psr_policy.htm.
(21.) For a model that is useful to address some of these issues,
see Acharya and Viswanathan (2011).
(22.) For example, changing to a system in which repos get unwound
only later in the day (or, not unwound at all, in the case of term
repos) will make those contracts less comparable with a demand deposit
from the perspective of cash investors. While it is true that during the
day investors are unlikely to need all the cash used in tri-party repos,
the option to have that cash available presumably has some value for
investors.
I would like to thank Jeff Lacker for many stimulating
conversations that motivated me to write this article, Jim Peck for
answering my game theory questions patiently, and Borys Grochulski, Bob
Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein, Tim Hursey, Todd Keister, Antoine Martin, Ned
Prescott, Alex Wolman, and John Walter for comments on an earlier draft.
All errors and imprecisions are of course my exclusive responsibility.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author and do not
necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail: huberto.ennis@rich.frb.org.