Instability and indeterminacy in a simple search and matching model.
Krause, Michael U. ; Lubik, Thomas A.
The search and matching model of Mortensen and Pissarides (1994)
has become a popular and successful framework for analyzing labor market
dynamics in dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. (1) In
this article, we point out a potentially problematic feature of this
framework. We show that the solution to the dynamic model can be
nonexistent or indeterminate. In particular, uniqueness problems arise
when endogenous matching in response to labor market pressures is not
elastic enough. In such a scenario, extraneous uncertainty,
"sunspots," can lead to business cycle fluctuations even in
the absence of any other disturbances. However, a solution does not
exist when matching is too elastic. While these determinacy problems are
plausible outcomes, we argue that they are not likely, as they are
associated with regions of the parameter space that are at the extremes
of typical calibrations.
Indeterminacy in search and matching models has previously been
addressed by Giammarioli (2003). Her article differs from ours in that
it introduces increasing returns in the matching function, which is a
well-known mechanism to generate multiplicity in DSGE models (see Farmer
and Guo [1994]). We show that indeterminacy in the search and matching
model can arise even under constant returns. Our paper is similar to
Burda and Weder (2002) in this respect. Their indeterminacy results are
driven, however, by the existence of labor market distortions, such as
taxes, and the associated fiscal policy functions, and not by the
features of the matching process per se. More recently, Hashimzade and
Ortigueira (2005) analyzed the determinacy properties of a real search
and matching model with capital. They show numerically how, for a given
parameterization, the model admits sunspot equilibria. Zanetti (2006)
incorporates the standard search and matching model into a New Keynesian
DSGE model, where monetary policy is governed by an interest rate
feedback rule. He shows that this expands the region of the parameter
space where the Taylor principle, and thus equilibrium uniqueness, is
violated. However, his paper focuses on the monetary policy rule as a
source of indeterminacy. Labor market search and matching only provides
a transmission mechanism, but is not analyzed as an independent factor
of determinacy problems.
This article proceeds as follows. We present a canonical DSGE model
with search and matching frictions in the next section. This is a
bare-bones version of the model that does not rely on any increasing
returns to scale in the functional forms. Our model specification has
the advantage that the determinacy regions can be characterized largely
analytically. Section 2 discusses issues related to the calibration of
this model, while Section 3 derives its determinacy properties, both
analytically and numerically. The final section briefly summarizes and
concludes.
1. A CANONICAL DSGE MODEL OF LABOR MARKET SEARCH AND MATCHING
We develop a simple version of a discrete-time DSGE model with
search and matching frictions in the labor market. (2) Key to the search
and matching model is that new employment relationships are the result
of time-consuming searches, both by firms and potential workers. In
order to hire workers, firms first have to advertise open positions;
they have to post vacancies, which is assumed to be costly. Existing
matches between workers and firms are subject to job destruction, which
leads to a flow of workers into the unemployment pool. The behavior of
the aggregate economy is governed by the choices of a representative
household, which engages in consumption smoothing. The household engages
in perfect risk-sharing between its employed and unemployed members. The
latter enjoy unemployment benefits while searching for a job. We employ
some simplifying assumptions later on that lead to steady-state and
dynamic equations that can be solved analytically. The properties of the
full model are then analyzed numerically.
Time is discrete. One period in the model is assumed to be a
quarter. There is a continuum of identical firms that employ workers,
who each inelastically supply one unit of labor. (3) Output, y, of a
typical firm is linear in employment, n:
[y.sub.t] = [n.sub.t]. (1)
The matching process is represented by a constant-returns matching
function, m([u.sub.t], [[upsilon].sub.t]) = [mu.sub.t.sup.[xi]]
[[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[1-[xi]]], of unemployment, u, and vacancies,
[upsilon], with parameters m > 0 and 0 < [xi] < 1. It captures
the number of newly formed employment relationships that arise out of
the contacts of unemployed workers and firms seeking to fill open
positions. Unemployment is defined as
[u.sub.t] = 1 - [n.sub.t], (2)
which is the measure of all potential workers in the economy who
are not employed at the beginning of the period and are thus available
for job search activities.
Inflows to unemployment arise from exogenous job destruction at
rate 0 < [rho] < 1. Employment therefore evolves according to
[n.sub.t] = (1 - [rho])[[n.sub.[t-1]] + m([u.sub.[t-1]],
[[upsilon].sub.[t-1]])]. (3)
Note that newly matching workers who are separated from their job
within the period reenter the matching pool immediately. We can define
q([[theta].sub.t]) as the probability of filling a vacancy, or the
firm-matching rate, where [[theta].sub.t] =
[[[upsilon].sub.t]/[u.sub.t]]. We refer to [theta] as the degree of
labor market tightness. In terms of the matching function, we can write
this as q([[theta].sub.t]) = m([u.sub.t],
[[upsilon].sub.t])/[[upsilon].sub.t] = m[[theta].sub.t.sup.-[xi]].
Similarly, the probability of finding a job, the worker-matching rate,
is p([[theta].sub.t]) = m ([u.sub.t], [[upsilon].sub.t])/[u.sub.t] =
m[[theta].sub.t.sup.[1-[xi]]]. An individual firm is atomistic in the
sense that it takes the aggregate matching rate, q([[theta].sub.t]), as
given. The employment constraint on the firm's decision problem is
therefore
[n.sub.t] = (1 - [rho])[[n.sub.[t-1]] +
[[upsilon].sub.[t-1]]q([[theta].sub.[t-1]])], (4)
that is, it is linear in vacancy postings.
Firms maximize profits using the discount factor [[beta].sup.t]
[[[lambda].sub.t]/[[lambda].sub.0]] (to be determined below):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
Wages paid to the workers are w, while [kappa] > 0 is a
firm's cost of opening a vacancy. [mu] is the Lagrange multiplier
on the firm's employment constraint. It can be interpreted as the
marginal value of a filled position. Firms decide how many vacancies to
post (which can be turned into employment relationships) and how many
workers to hire. The first-order conditions are
[n.sub.t]: [[mu].sub.t] = 1 - [w.sub.t] + [beta](1 -
[rho])[[[lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t]][[mu].sub.[t+1]], (6)
[[upsilon].sub.t]: [kappa] = [beta](1 -
[rho])[[[lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t]][[mu].sub.[t+1]]q([[theta].sub.t]), (7)
which imply a job-creation condition
[[kappa]/q([[theta].sub.t])] = (1 -
[rho])[beta]([[[lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t]])[1 - [w.sub.[t+1]]
+ [[kappa]/q([[theta].sub.[t+1]])]]. (8)
This optimality condition trades off the expected hiring cost
(which depends on the success probability q([[theta].sub.t])) against
the benefits of a productive match (which consists of the output
accruing to the firms net of wage payments and the future savings on
hiring costs when the current match is successful).
We assume that the economy is populated by a representative
household. The household is composed of workers who are either
unemployed or employed. If they are unemployed they are compelled to
search for a job, but they can draw unemployment benefits, b. Employed
members of the household receive pay, w, but share this with the
unemployed. They do not suffer disutility from working and supply a
fixed number of hours. (4) The household's only choice variable is
consumption, so that its optimization problem is trivial:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
subject to
[C.sub.t] = [Y.sub.t], (10)
where C is consumption and Y is income earned from labor and
residual profits from the firms; 0 < [beta] < 1 is the discount
factor, and [[sigma].sup.-1] is the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution. From the household's (trivial) first-order condition
we find that [[lambda].sub.t] = [C.sub.t.sup.-[sigma]], where [lambda]
is the multiplier on the household's budget constraint. In
equilibrium, total income accruing to the household equals net output in
the economy, which is composed of production less real resources lost in
the search process:
[Y.sub.t] = [y.sub.t] - [kappa][[upsilon].sub.t]. (11)
Finally, we need to derive how wages are determined. We assume that
wages are set according to the Nash bargaining solution. (5) Firms and
workers maximize the bargaining function
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
with respect to the variable over which the two parties bargain,
namely the wage, [w.sub.t]. This results in the sharing rule:
[eta][J.sub.t] = (1 - [eta])[W.sub.t]. (13)
[W.sub.t] denotes the match surplus accruing to the worker, while
[J.sub.t] is the firm's surplus, that is, the value of a filled
job. The latter can be found from the firm's optimization problem.
It is equal to the Lagrange multiplier on the employment constraint,
[[mu].sub.t], and is the shadow value of a filled position; to wit,
[J.sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t]. From the first-order condition with respect to
employment we find that
[J.sub.t] = 1 - [w.sub.t] + [beta](1 -
[rho])[[[lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t]][J.sub.[t+1]]. (14)
The expression states that the value of a filled job is its
marginal product, 1, net of wage payments, [w.sub.t]; but it also has a
continuation value [J.sub.[t+1]], which is discounted at the time
preference rate, [beta], and assuming that the filled job is still there
next period. The latter is captured by the survival rate (1 - [rho]).
We can derive the worker's surplus as follows. The worker
receives payment in the form of the wage, [w.sub.t]. But while he is
working, he loses the value of being unemployed, b. The latter can be
interpreted as the money value of enjoying leisure, engaging in
household production, or simply unemployment benefits. Therefore, the
current period net return is [w.sub.t] - b. In the next period, the
worker receives the continuation value [W.sub.[t+1]], which is
discounted at rate [beta]. The worker has to take into account that he
might not be employed next period, which is captured by the survival
rate (1 - [rho]), adjusted for the fact that a separated worker might
not find a job again with probability [1 - p([[theta].sub.t])]. Putting
it all together, we have
[W.sub.t] = [w.sub.t] - b + [beta](1 - [rho])[1 -
p([[theta].sub.t])][[[lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t]][W.sub.[t+1]].
(15)
The two marginal values can now be substituted into the sharing
rule and, after some algebra using the firm's first-order
conditions, we can find the Nash-bargained wage:
[w.sub.t] = [eta](1 + [kappa][[theta].sub.t]) + (1 - [eta])b. (16)
We can now use this wage equation to derive the job-creation
condition:
[[kappa]/q([[theta].sub.t])] = (1 -
[rho])[beta][[Y.sub.t.sup.[sigma]]/[Y.sub.[t+1].sup.[sigma]]][(1 -
[eta]) (1 - b) - [eta][kappa][[theta].sub.[t+1]] +
[[kappa]/q([[theta].sub.[t+1]])]]], (17)
where we have used the first-order conditions of the household to
eliminate the Lagrange multiplier, [lambda], from the discount factor.
The dynamics of the model are given by the five equations in five
unknowns: (2), (3), (11), (17), and the definition of labor market
tightness, [[theta].sub.t].
2. STEADY STATE AND CALIBRATION
We first compute the deterministic steady state of the model. We
then linearize the dynamic system around the steady state and analyze
the local determinacy properties of the economy. The equations
describing the steady state are
u = 1 - n, (18)
[theta] = [[upsilon]/u], (19)
n = [1 - [rho]/[rho]]m[[upsilon].sup.[1-[xi]]][u.sup.[xi]], (20)
Y = n - [kappa][upsilon], (21)
(1 - [eta]) (1 - b) = [[1 - [beta](1 - [rho])]/[[beta](1 -
[rho])]][[kappa]/m][[theta].sup.[xi]] + c[eta][theta]. (22)
(20) is the employment accumulation equation. It stipulates that
inflows and outflows of the unemployment pool have to be equal. In a
steady-state equilibrium, the number of separated workers, [rho]n, has
to equal newly hired workers. Equation (22) is the job-creation
condition, while the other equations are definitions.
There are five endogenous variables (u, n, [upsilon], [theta], y)
and seven structural parameters ([rho], m, [chi], [kappa], [beta],
[eta], b). Because of the nonlinearity in the last equation, there is no
analytical solution to this system. Given values for the parameters,
however, we can compute a numerical solution. Using a nonlinear equation
solver we determine [theta] from equation (22). (6) From equation (20)
we can find u = [(1 + [1 - [rho]/[rho]]m[[theta].sup.[1-[xi]]]).sup.-1],
and the solution for the other variables follows immediately.
We find it more convenient, however, to calibrate the model by
fixing the steady-state unemployment rate, u = [bar.u]. This implies
that one parameter has to be determined endogenously. Additionally, we
can fix the endogenous matching rate, [bar.q] = m[[theta].sup.-[xi]], by
using evidence on the rates at which firms fill vacancies. Hence,
another parameter has to be determined endogenously. Using n = 1 -
[bar.u] in (20), we find that the match efficiency parameter is m =
[([rho]/1-[rho] 1-[bar.u]/u).sup.[xi]] [[bar.q].sup.[1-[xi]]] and labor
market tightness is [theta] = [(m/[bar.q]).sup.[1/[xi]]]. From (22) we
can then also compute 1 - b/[kappa] = [eta]/1-[eta] [theta] + 1/1 -
[eta] [1 - [beta](1 - [rho])/[beta](1 - [rho])] [[theta].sup.[xi]]/m.
Note, however, that this condition does not pin down b and [kappa]
independently, nor does any other restriction in the model. Equation
(21) helps only insofar as it restricts [kappa] such that y remains
positive. We chose to fix the vacancy cost parameter, [kappa], and let
the benefit parameter, b, be determined endogenously.
For our calibration exercise we set the discount factor as [beta] =
0.99. We chose a separation rate of [rho] = 0.1. This is consistent with
the evidence reported in Shimer (2005) and Lubik (2010), who use various
econometric methods to estimate this parameter from U.S. labor market
data. We agnostically set the bargaining parameter as [eta] = 0.5 and
follow most of the literature in this respect. Similarly, the match
elasticity is [xi] = 0.5, which is on the low end of estimates in the
literature. Note that this benchmark calibration implements the Hosios
condition, under which the market allocation in the model is socially
efficient. The value for the match elasticity is at the low end of the
plausible range as reported in the empirical study by Petrongolo and
Pissarides (2001). We set the intertemporal substitution elasticity as
[sigma] = 1.
Finally, the two steady-state values are chosen as follows. We fix
the unemployment rate, [bar.u], at 12 percent. Our idea is to capture
both measured unemployment in terms of recipients of unemployment
benefits and potential job searchers that are only marginally attached
to the labor force, but are open to job search. Since we do not model
labor force participation decisions, this is a shortcut to capturing
effective labor market search. This approach has been taken by Cooley
and Quadrini (1999) and Trigari (2009). In choosing the steady-state
job-matching rate, we follow den Haan, Ramey, and Watson (2000) who set
[bar.q] = 0.7. In the numerical determinacy analysis below we conduct
robustness checks for selected parameters and the calibrated
steady-state values by varying them over their admissible range.
3. INDETERMINACY AND NONEXISTENCE
We now proceed by linearizing the dynamic equilibrium conditions
around the steady state. It is a well-known feature of linear rational
expectations models that they can have multiple equilibria, or that the
solution may not even exist. We show that both scenarios are possible
outcomes in the standard search and matching model, but they are
associated with regions at the fringes of the parameter space. The
linearized system is as follows (where [[^.x].sub.t] = log [x.sub.t] -
log x denotes the percentage deviation of the variable [x.sub.t] from
its steady state x):
u[[^.u].sub.t] = -n[[^.n].sub.t], (23)
[[^.[theta]].sub.t] = [[^.[upsilon]].sub.t] - [[^.u].sub.t], (24)
[[^.n].sub.[t+1]] = (1 - [rho])[[^.n].sub.t] + [rho](1 -
[xi])[[^.[upsilon]].sub.t] + [rho][xi][[^.u].sub.t], (25)
[[^.Y].sub.t] = [n/y][[^.n].sub.t] -
[[kappa][upsilon]/y][[^.[upsilon]].sub.t], (26)
[xi][[^.[theta]].sub.t] - [sigma][[^.Y].sub.t] =
([[kappa][xi]/m][[theta].sup.[xi]] - [eta][kappa][theta])
[X.sup.-1][[^.[theta]].sub.[t+1]] - [sigma][[^.Y].sub.[t+1]], (27)
where X = 1/[beta](1 - [rho]) [kappa]/m [[theta].sup.[xi]].
It is straightforward to substitute out [[^.u].sub.t],
[[^.[upsilon]].sub.t], and [[^.Y].sub.t], so that we are left with
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (28)
where [[alpha].sub.1] = [beta](1 - [rho])([xi] -
[eta]m[[theta].sup.[1-[xi]]]) + [sigma] [kappa][upsilon]/y and
[[alpha].sub.2] = [sigma] n/y (1 + [kappa][theta]). This reduced form is
expressed in terms of the state (or predetermined) variable,
[[^.n].sub.t], and the jump variable, [[^.[theta]].sub.t], which is a
function of vacancy postings, [[^.[upsilon]].sub.t]. The stability
properties of the solution depend on the eigenvalues of the coefficient
matrix. A unique solution requires that one root be inside the unit
circle and the other root outside. Indeterminacy arises when both roots
are inside the unit circle, while nonexistence occurs with both roots
being explosive. In the former case, both equations are dynamically
stable and an infinite number of paths (starting from arbitrary initial
conditions) toward the unique steady state exist. In the latter case,
both equations are explosive, which implies that, from any arbitrary
initial condition, employment and vacancies would grow without bounds.
This violates transversality or boundary conditions and can therefore
not be an equilibrium.
The coefficient matrix is sufficiently complicated to prevent
simple analytical derivations of the equilibrium regions. For
illustrative purposes and for gaining intuition, we therefore make the
simplifying assumption that the representative household is risk
neutral, [sigma] = 0. Later on, we discuss the general case using
simulation results. Under risk neutrality, the coefficient matrix
reduces to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (29)
Since the coefficient matrix is triangular, the eigenvalues can be
read off the principal diagonal. Recall that the worker matching rate is
p = m[[theta].sup.[1-[xi]]], which is equal to [rho]/1 - [rho] 1 - u/u.
Since we are treating the unemployment rate as a parameter to be
calibrated, the determinacy conditions therefore only depend on
structural parameters.
We establish the determinacy properties in the following
proposition.
Proposition 1
1. The model solution is indeterminate if and only if
(a) 0 < [rho] < 2u,
(b) 0 < [xi] < [[[beta](1 - [rho])]/[1 + [beta](1 -
[rho])]][eta]p.
2. The model solution is nonexistent if and only if
(a) [rho] > 2u > 0,
(b) [[[beta](1 - [rho])]/[1 + [beta](1 - [rho])]][eta]p < [xi]
< 1.
3. The model solution is unique if and only if either
(a) 0 < [rho] < 2u,
(b) [[[beta](1 - [rho])]/[1 + [beta](1 - [rho])]][eta]p < [xi]
< 1,
or
(c) [rho] > 2u > 0,
(d) 0 < [xi] < [[[beta](1 - [rho])]/[1 + [beta](1 -
[rho])]][eta]p.
Proof. Indeterminacy requires both roots inside the unit circle.
Call [[lambda].sub.2] = [u - [rho]/u]. It is straightforward to verify
that [absolute value of [[lambda].sub.2]] < 1 over the permissible
range iff 0 < [rho] < 2u. Call the other root [[lambda].sub.1] =
[[xi]/[beta](1 - [rho])([xi] - [eta]p)]. We have to distinguish two
cases: if [xi] > [eta]p, no parameter combination can be found such
that [absolute value of [[lambda].sub.1] < 1. If [xi] < [eta]p, we
can write -[beta](1 - [rho])([xi] - [eta]p) > [xi] > [beta](1 -
[rho])([xi] - [eta]p). Simple algebra in combination with [xi] > 0
then yields 1(b). Nonexistence requires that both roots be outside the
unit circle. This is just the opposite scenario discussed before. Part 2
of the proposition follows immediately. Uniqueness requires one stable
and one unstable eigenvalue. The parameter regions are consequently
implied by those not considered in part 1 and 2.
The proposition shows that indeterminacy is a potential outcome in
this model. It arises when the job destruction rate is less than twice
the (calibrated) unemployment rate. For instance, at a separation rate
of 10 percent, the unemployment rate would have to be less than 5
percent to definitely rule out indeterminacy on account of condition
1(a). This value is not implausible, given historical data for the
United States where the average post-war unemployment rate is 4.8
percent. However, it has been argued (e.g., Trigari [2009]) that the
proper corresponding concept for model unemployment includes not only
the registered unemployed but also all workers potentially available for
employment, such as discouraged workers or workers loosely attached to
the labor force. Consequently, [bar.u] should be assigned a much higher
value (for instance, 26 percent as in Trigari [2009]), which raises the
possibility of equilibrium indeterminacy. (7)
Condition 1(b) imposes an upper bound on the match elasticity,
[xi]. In the benchmark calibration, this upper bound is 0.147. Since
[xi] is typically calibrated to be above 0.5, this would rule out
indeterminacy. However, this observation comes with the caveat that
values for the match elasticity below 0.5 have some support in the
literature. For instance, Cooley and Quadrini (1999) argue that a low
elasticity in the range of [xi] = 0.1 is necessary to match labor market
cyclically. Using likelihood-based econometric methods, Lubik (2010)
finds that there is, in fact, substantial probability mass on low values
of [xi]. We also note that the upper bound is increasing in the Nash
bargaining parameter. But even if [eta] [right arrow] 1, indeterminacy
would not occur for the typical parameter choices in the literature.
Suppose, however, that the unemployment rate were set to [bar.u] = 0.06.
In this case, the upper bound increases to 0.816, which would imply
indeterminacy for typical search elasticity choices. Clearly, the
interpretation of the pool of searchers in the matching model matters
for determinacy questions.
Intuitively, we can think about a sunspot equilibrium in the
following way. Firms are willing to incur vacancy posting costs if they
expect to recoup them through the proceeds from production net of wages
and the savings on future hiring, as captured by the job-creation
condition (17). The equilibrating mechanism is the behavior of the
matching rate, q([theta]). An increase in vacancy posting raises labor
market tightness and lowers the probability that an individual firm is
successful in finding an employee. This, in turn, raises effective
hiring costs, [[kappa]/q([theta])], which would have to be offset by
higher expected returns. It is this externality, namely the fact that
firms do not internalize the effect of their posting decisions on
aggregate match probabilities, that is at the heart of the determinacy
issue. (8)
Now suppose that a firm believes that future profits will be higher
than is warranted by the fundamentals, such as the level of
productivity. Beliefs of this kind can be triggered by sunspot shocks,
as in the interpretation by Lubik and Schorfheide (2003). This belief
would compel the firm to post more vacancies. If other firms were to do
the same, aggregate tightness would increase and match probability would
fall, raising effective hiring cost. What tends to rule out a sunspot
equilibrium is that expected future benefits are not consistent with the
higher posting costs. Consequently, rational firms do not act on sunspot
beliefs. This argument breaks down in an environment where future
benefits rise to accommodate higher current costs. The proposition
stipulates that indeterminacy arises when both the separation, [rho],
and the match elasticity, [xi], are too small. When the former applies,
the unemployment pool is small, while the latter makes new matches, and
thereby future employment, highly elastic to vacancy postings.
Consequently, the savings on future hiring costs react more than current
effective costs, which helps validate sunspot beliefs.
A similar argument applies for the case of nonexistence of
equilibrium. In general, nonexistence problems would arise for
unemployment rates that are too low for given separation rates, in
combination with excessively high match elasticities. In more technical
terms, this combination makes the employment equation explosive. Any
disturbance to a steady-state equilibrium would result in excessive job
destruction (due to high separation rates) and matching that is
inconsistent with the job-creation condition.
We now turn to the full model solution with risk-averse households
([sigma] > 0). We compute the determinacy regions numerically for
combinations of the match elasticity, [xi], and various other structural
parameters. The results are presented in Figure 1, where we have plotted
determinacy regions for different subsets of the parameter space. The
parameters are calibrated at the benchmark values discussed above. In
each panel we vary two parameters over their admissible range while
keeping the other parameters at their benchmark values.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As a general conclusion, determinacy problems tend to arise when
the match elasticity, [xi], is either too small or too big. For small
[xi], the equilibrium is indeterminate when the job destruction rate,
[rho], or the unemployment rate, u, is too small. This is related to the
analytical condition found in Proposition 1. Furthermore, firm-matching
rates, q, above 0.2 and a Nash parameter that puts more weight on
workers also lead to multiplicity. No equilibrium exists for large [xi]
and either a small unemployment rate or [rho] above 0.2. We also analyze
the sensitivity of the regions with respect to [sigma] (not reported).
As [sigma] [right arrow] 0, the indeterminacy regions expand. In
particular, any q implies multiple equilibria when [xi] < 0.2. In the
limit the boundaries between regions are given in the proposition. As
the household becomes more risk averse, however, regions of
indeterminacy disappear entirely.
An interesting special case to consider is a calibration with the
Hosios condition, where [eta] = [xi]. This can be represented by a
45-degree line in the lower-right panel of Figure 1. In the absence of
outside information on the value of the bargaining parameter, [eta], the
Hosios calibration is often chosen in the literature. In this case,
indeterminacy and nonexistence are ruled out and become highly unlikely
for other parameter combinations. For instance, equilibrium nonexistence
requires a separation rate of [rho] = 0.81. Moreover, if [eta] = [xi],
we can rule out indeterminacy in the case of [sigma] = 0 because
condition 1(b) of the proposition never holds. The equilibrium could
still be nonexistent, but this would require very high separation rates.
In principle, these could obtain when the model period is much longer
than a quarter since eventually all workers turn over within a long
enough time horizon. (9)
Interpreting these results in light of standard calibrations used
in the literature, we would argue that indeterminacy and nonexistence do
not present serious problems for the search and matching framework.
Hence, it is unlikely that sunspot equilibria would be helpful in
explaining labor market dynamics (as claimed in Hashimzade and
Ortigueira [2005]). This is not to say that labor search and matching
frameworks cannot support indeterminate equilibria. Mildly increasing
returns to scale in the matching function (Giammarioli 2003) lead to
widely expanded indeterminacy regions, while a New Keynesian model with
search and matching frictions in the labor market has broader
indeterminacy properties than the standard New Keynesian model (Zanetti
2006).
4. CONCLUSION
We show in this article that for most plausible parameterizations
the simple search and matching model does not suffer from determinacy
problems. Specifically, we argue that it is unlikely that the model has
multiple equilibria so that extraneous uncertainty, i.e., animal
spirits, can cause business cycles. Parameterizations that lead to
indeterminacy can be found, but they lie at the boundaries of the region
that the empirical literature would consider plausible. We identify the
match elasticity and the separate rate as crucial parameters in that
respect.
These properties are obviously model specific, but our conclusions
are likely robust to modifications such as endogenous job destruction.
While the boundaries of the determinacy regions are likely to shift, the
dynamic mechanism stays unaffected. The main caveat to our study is that
our analysis applies to a local equilibrium in the neighborhood of the
steady state. However, the underlying model is nonlinear and local
results may therefore not adequately describe the global equilibrium
properties. Naturally, this is a topic for further investigation.
Moreover, researchers may actually be interested in the business cycle
implications of indeterminacy that do not depend on policy rules or
externalities. It appears plausible that actual labor market decisions
are characterized to some extent by animal spirits. Further research
should shed some light on this issue.
REFERENCES
Andolfatto, David. 1996. "Business Cycles and Labor Market
Search." American Economic Review 86 (March): 112-32.
Burda, Michael C, and Mark Weder. 2002. "Complementarity of
Labor Market Institutions, Equilibrium Unemployment and the Propagation
of Business Cycles." German Economic Review 3 (February): 1-24.
Cooley, Thomas F., and Vincenzo Quadrini. 1999. "A
Neoclassical Model of the Phillips Curve Relation." Journal of
Monetary Economics 44 (October): 165-93.
den Haan, Wouter, Garey Ramey, and Joel Watson. 2000. "Job
Destruction and the Propagation of Shocks." American Economic
Review 90 (June): 482-98.
Farmer, Roger E. A., and Jang-Ting Guo. 1994. "Real Business
Cycles and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis." Journal of Economic
Theory 63 (June): 42-72.
Giammarioli, Nicola. 2003. "Indeterminacy and Search
Theory." European Central Bank Working Paper 271 (September).
Hashimzade, Nigar, and Salvador Ortigueira. 2005. "Endogenous
Business Cycles with Frictional Labor Markets." The Economic
Journal 115 (March): 161-75.
Krause, Michael U., and Thomas A. Lubik. 2007. "The
(Ir)relevance of Real Wage Rigidity in the New Keynesian Model with
Search Frictions." Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (April):
706-27.
Lubik, Thomas A. 2009. "Estimating a Search and Matching Model
of the Aggregate Labor Market." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 95 (Spring): 101-20.
Lubik, Thomas A. 2010. "Identifying the Search and Matching
Model of the Labor Market." Manuscript.
Lubik, Thomas A., and Frank Schorfheide. 2003. "Computing
Sunspot Equilibria in Linear Rational Expectations Models." Journal
of Economic Dynamics and Control 28 (November): 273-85.
Merz, Monika. 1995. "Search in the Labor Market and the Real
Business Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics 36 (November):
269-300.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1994. "Job
Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment." Review
of Economic Studies 61 (July): 397-415.
Petrongolo, Barbara, and Christopher Pissarides. 2001.
"Looking Into the Black Box: A Survey of the Matching
Function." Journal of Economic Literature 39 (June): 390-431.
Shimer, Robert. 2005. "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium
Unemployment and Vacancies." American Economic Review 95 (March):
25-49.
Trigari, Antonella. 2009. "Equilibrium Unemployment, Job
Flows, and Inflation Dynamics." Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 41 (February): 1-33.
Zanetti, Francesco. 2006. "Labor Market Frictions,
Indeterminacy, and Interest Rate Rules." Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking 38 (October): 1,959-70.
(1) A nonexhaustive list of references includes Merz (1995);
Andolfatto (1996); Cooley and Quadrini (1999); den Haan, Ramey, and
Watson (2000); Krause and Lubik (2007); and Trigari (2009).
(2) The model is similar to Lubik (2009), to which we refer the
reader for additional discussion and references.
(3) For expositional convenience, we present the problem of a
representative firm only, and abstract from indexing the individual form
and aggregation issues.
(4) We thus assume income pooling between employed and unemployed
households and abstract from potential incentive problems concerning
labor market search. This allows us to treat the labor market separate
from the consumption choice. See Merz (1995) and Andolfatto (1996) for
discussion of these issues.
(5) This is a standard assumption in the literature. Shimer (2005)
provides further discussion.
(6) Since the function in [theta] is monotonically increasing for
nonnegative [theta], there is a unique solution to this equation as long
as 0 [less than or equal to] b < 1. This reflects the fact that the
outside option of the worker, namely staying unemployed, cannot be
larger than the worker's marginal product, i.e., the maximum rent
that the worker can extract from the firm.
(7) Calibrating [bar.u] to a different value implies that benefits,
b, and match efficiency, m, would have to change, too, since they are
computed endogenously from the steady-state conditions. Higher
steady-state unemployment corresponds to a higher value of b and lower
m. This can be interpreted as an implication of different labor market
institutions.
(8) This has similar characteristics to the notion of an
upward-sloping labor demand schedule in Farmer and Guo (1994). In their
model, production exhibits constant returns to scale at the individual
firm level, but increasing returns in the aggregate. An individual firm
hiring more workers raises the marginal product of workers in the
aggregate, thereby stimulating more labor demand. The job-creation
condition can be thought of as a vacancy-demand curve.
(9) Incidentally, the continuous-lime version of this simple search
and matching model always has a unique solution (see Shimer [2005]), as
the separation-relevant time horizon is infinitesimally small. We are
grateful to Andreas Hornstein for pointing this out.
We are grateful to Andreas Hornstein, Anne Davlin, Marianna
Kudlyak, and Alex Wolman for useful comments. The views expressed in
this paper are those of the authors and should not necessarily be
interpreted as those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the
Federal Reserve System. Krause is with the Economic Research Centre of
the Deutsche Bundesbank in Frankfurt, Germany. Lubik is a senior
economist with the Richmond Fed. E-mails:
michael.u.krause@bundesbank.de; thomas.lubik@rich.frb.org.