Risk sharing, investment, and incentives in the neoclassical growth model.
Espino, Emilio ; Sanchez, Juan M.
The amount of risk sharing among households, regions, or countries
is crucial in determining aggregate welfare. For example, pooling
resources at the national level can help regions better deal with
natural disasters like floods. Similarly, pooling resources with an
insurance company can help individuals deal with shocks like a house
fire or a car accident.
Capital accumulation and economic growth also are crucial in
determining aggregate welfare. In particular, they determine the stock
of wealth available for consumption and investment. Importantly,
wealthier households, regions, or countries possess a buffer stock of
precautionary assets, a form of self-insurance.
These two important factors in determining welfare have interesting
interactions with one another. An important one is how insurance and
savings substitute for each other. For example, individuals may want to
save more when they do not have access to insurance than when they do
because the extra savings can protect against the consequences of an
uninsured shock. Therefore, capital accumulation and growth would be
faster in an economy without perfect insurance than in one with perfect
insurance.
This article explores the tradeoffs between insurance and growth in
the neoclassical growth model with two agents and preference shocks.
Most of the analysis reviews the full information version of the model,
where there are no limits on insurance between the two agents, though
there is still aggregate uncertainty that affects aggregate savings
behavior. Private information is then added to the model to limit the
ability to insure the two agents. This is a much harder problem, as has
been observed in the literature, and only a partial characterization is
provided.
Literature Review
Our article relates to the voluminous consumption/savings/capital
accumulation literature on two levels. On one hand, there has been a
growing literature focusing on the accumulation effects of demand side
shocks in dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, following the
pioneering work of Baxter and King (1991) and Hall (1997). In general
equilibrium models, demand side shocks (such as preference shocks to
consumption demand) have a strong tendency to crowd out investment. (1)
On the other hand, there is literature on the impact of inequality on
capital accumulation. If preferences aggregate in the Gorman sense, the
distribution of wealth does not affect the evolution of aggregate
variables--see Chatterjee (1994) and Caselli and Ventura (2000). In our
setting, preferences do not aggregate in that strong sense. Thus,
distribution matters for aggregate savings and the corresponding
dynamics of the aggregate stock of capital. (2)
The literature analyzing economic growth and private information is
not as large, and the valuable contributions have relied on different
simplifying assumptions to make the analysis tractable. This article is
related to those articles because we are interested in understanding
when information is (more) important to implement the full information
allocation. However, we solve the full information model to obtain the
full information allocation and characterize only the incentives to
misreport the shocks under that allocation.
Pioneering contributions in the literature on constrained efficient
allocations with private information abstracted from capital
accumulation, as the main goal was to study wealth distribution. In a
pure exchange economy setting, Green (1987) and Atkeson and Lucas (1992)
show that (constrained) efficient allocations, independent of the
feasibility technologies, display extreme levels of
"immiserization": The expected utility level of (almost) every
agent in the economy converges to the lower bound with probability one.
This result is also present in Thomas and Worrall (1990). Then, in an
early contribution that includes capital accumulation, Marcet and
Marimon (1992) examine a two-agent model where a risk-neutral investor
with unlimited resources invests in the technology of a risk-averse
producer whose output is subject to privately observed productivity
shocks. They show that the full information investment policy can be
implemented in the private information environment. That is, in their
setting, a risk-neutral investor can make the risk-averse entrepreneur
follow the full information investment policy and allocate his
consumption conditional on output realizations. Thus, they find that
growth levels are as high as with perfect information. The key
simplification in this article is that the second agent in the economy
is risk-neutral with unlimited resources.
Khan and Ravikumar (2001) extend Marcet and Marimon (1992) to
impose a period-by-period feasibility constraint and endogenous growth.
In particular, they examine the impact of incomplete risk sharing on
growth and welfare in the context of the AK model. The source of market
incompleteness is private information since household technologies are
subject to idiosyncratic productivity shocks not observable by others.
Risk sharing between households occurs through contracts with
intermediaries. This sort of incomplete risk sharing tends to reduce the
rate of growth relative to the complete risk-sharing benchmark. However,
"numerical examples indicate that, on average, the growth and
welfare effects on incomplete risk sharing are likely to be small."
One key simplification in this case is that the allocation solved is not
necessarily the best incentive-compatible allocation.
Recently, Greenwood, Sanchez, and Wang (2010a) embedded the costly
state verification framework into the standard growth model. (3) The
relationship between the firm and lender is modeled as a static
contract. In the economy in which information is too costly, undeserving
firms are overfinanced and deserving ones are underfunded. A reduction
in the cost of information leads to more capital accumulation and a
redirection of funds away from unproductive firms toward productive
ones. Greenwood, Sanchez, and Wang (2010b) show that this mechanism has
quantitative significance to explain cross-country differences in
capital-to-income ratios and total factor productivity.
Other studies use similar models for other purposes. Espino (2005)
studies a neoclassical growth model that includes a discrete number of
agents, like the one presented in this article. However, he uses the
economy with private information about the preference shock to analyze
the validity of Ramsey's conjecture about the long-run allocation
of an economy in which agents are heterogeneous in their discount
factor. Clementi, Cooley, and Giannatale (2010) study a repeated
bilateral exchange model with hidden action, along the lines of Spear
and Srivastava (1987) and Wang (1997), that includes capital
accumulation. The two agents in the economy are a risk-neutral investor
and a risk-averse entrepreneur. They show that the incentive scheme
chosen by the investor provides a rationale for firm decline.
This article is organized as follows: Section 1 presents the
physical environment and the planner's problem, and derives the
optimal allocation. Section 2 describes the calibration and the
numerical solution of the full information allocation. Section 3 studies
in which cases the full information allocation would be incentive
compatible in an economy with private information. Section 4 offers
concluding remarks.
1. MODEL
Environment
There is a constant returns to scale aggregate technology to
produce the unique consumption good that is represented by a standard
neoclassical production function, F(K, L), where K is the current stock
of capital and L denotes units of labor. There are two agents in the
economy, h = 1, 2. Agent h is endowed with one unit of time each period
and does not value leisure, i.e., the time endowment is supplied
inelastically in the labor market. The initial stock of capital at date
0 is denoted by [K.sub.0] Greater than 0. Capital depreciates at the
rate [delta] [member of] (0, 1).
At the beginning of date t, agent 1 faces an idiosyncratic
preference shock [s.sub.t] [member of] [S.sub.t] = {[S.sub.L],
[S.sub.H]}, where [s.sub.H] Greater than [s.sub.L]. This shock is
assumed to be i.i.d. across time, where [[pi].sub.i] Greater than 0 is
the probability of [s.sub.i], i = L, H. Notice that [s.sub.t] is also
the aggregate preference shock at date t. The aggregate history of
shocks from date 0 to date t, denoted [s.sup.t] = ([s.sub.0] ...,
[s.sub.t]), has probability at date 0 given by [pi]([s.sup.t]) =
[pi]([s.sub.0]) ... [pi]([s.sub.t]).
Given a consumption plan [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] such that [[c.sub.1,t]]: [S.sup.t] [right arrow] [caps
R.sub.+], agent 1's state-dependent preferences are represented by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[u.sub.1]: [caps R.sub.+] [right arrow] [caps R]]is strictly
increasing, strictly concave, and twice differentiable, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], and [beta] [member of] (0, 1).
Similarly, given [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
agent 2's preferences are represented by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Planner's Problem
Consider the problem of a fictitious planner choosing the best
feasible allocation. Let [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] be an investment plan that every period allocates next
period's capital for all t. Similarly, let [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] be a consumption plan where [C.sub.t] =
([c.sub.1t], [c.sub.2t]). Given [K.sub.0], a sequential allocation (C,
K') is feasible if, for all [s.sup.t],
[[K.sub.t] ([s.sup.t]) + [c.sub.1t] ([s.sup.t]) [less than or equal
to] F([K.sub.t]([s.sup.t-1]), 1) + (1-[delta]) [K.sub.t]([s.sup.t-1])].
We will assume throughout the article that the production function
F is Cobb-Douglas with exponent [gamma].
The Pareto-optimal allocation in this economy is a feasible
allocation such that there is no other feasible allocation that provides
all the agents the same or more lifetime utility. One reason to be
interested in these allocations is that, under certain conditions, they
are equivalent to competitive equilibrium allocations. Under our
assumptions, Pareto-optimal allocations can be obtained by solving the
following problem:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to
[K ([s.sup.t]) + [c.sub.1]([s.sup.t]) + [c.sub.2]([s.sup.t]) [less
than or equal to] F (K ([s.sup.t-1]), 1) + (1 + [delta]) K
([s.sup.t-1]), [for all][s.sub.t]],
where [K.sub.0] is given and [alpha] [member of] [0, 1] is the
weight that the planner assigned to agent 1--referred to hereafter as
Pareto weight. Notice that different values of a characterize different
points in the Pareto frontier. Later, we will consider a different
allocation varying the value of [alpha].
To characterize the problem further, it is simpler to consider the
methods developed by Lucas and Stokey (1984) to solve for Pareto-optimal
allocations in growing economies populated with many consumers. It is
actually simple to adapt their method to analyze this economy. The idea
is to make next period welfare weights conditional on the current shock.
(4)
The planner's recursive problem is a fixed point, V, of the
function equation
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
subject to
[f (k) + (1 - [delta])k [greater than or equal to] [k'.sub.L]
+ [c.sub.1L] + [c.sub.2L]], (2)
[f (k) + (1 - [delta])k [greater than or equal to] [K'.sub.H]
+ [c.sub.1H] + [c.sub.2H]], (3)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
where [bar] alpha and w are the from-tomorrow-on utilities. The
idea in (1)-(5) is to represent the problem of choosing an optimal
allocation for a given stock of capital k and a vector of Pareto weights
([alpha], 1 - [alpha]) as one of choosing a feasible current period
allocation of consumption [c = {[c.sub.1L], [c.sub.1H], [c.sub.2L],
[c.sub.2H]}] and capital goods [k' = {[k'.sub.L],
[k'.sub.H]}], and a vector of from-tomorrow-on utilities [w =
{[w.sub.1L], [w.sub.1H], [w.sub.2L], w.sub.2H]}, subject to the
constraint that these utilities be attainable given the capital
accumulation decision, as guaranteed by constraints (4)-(5). As in Lucas
and Stokey (1984), the weights {[[bar]'[[alpha].sub.L],
[[bar]'[[alpha].sub.H]} that attain the minimum in (4) and (5) will
be the new weights used in selecting tomorrow's allocation, and so
on, ad infinitum.
Characterization
Assume preferences are represented by
[[u.sub.1] (s, c) = [s[c.sup.1 - [delta]]/[1 - [delta]] and
[[u.sub.2](c) = [c.sup.1-[delta]]/1 - [delta]].
The first-order conditions (FOC) for consumption are
[[alpha][[pi].sub.L][s.sub.L] ([c.sub.1L])sup.-[delta] =
[[lambda].sub.L]],
[[alpha][[pi].sub.H][s.sub.H] ([c.sub.1H])sup.-[delta] =
[[lambda].sub.H]],
[(1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.L] ([c.sub.2L]).sup. -[delta] =
[[lambda].sub.L]],
[(1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.H] ([c.sub.2H]).sup. -[delta] =
[[lambda].sub.H]],
where [[lambda].sub.i] is the Lagrange multiplier in the resource
constraints in state i = L, H. From these equations it is simple to
obtain that the consumption of each agent will be a share of the
aggregate consumption, [C.sub.i],
[[c.sub.1L] = ([[alpha][s.sub.L])sup.1/[delta]/([[alpha][s.sub.L])sup.1/[delta] + (1 - [alpha])sup.1/[delta] [C.sub.L]]
[[c.sub.1H] = ([[alpha][s.sub.H])sup.1/[delta]/([[alpha][s.sub.H])sup.1/[delta] + (1 - [alpha])sup.1/[delta] [C.sub.H]]
[[c.sub.2L] = [(1 -
[alpha]).sup.1/[delta]]/([[alpha][s.sub.L])sup.1/[delta]] + [(1 -
[alpha])sup.1/[delta]] [C.sub.L],
[[c.sub.2H] = [(1 -
[alpha]).sup.1/[delta]]/([[alpha][s.sub.H])sup.1/[delta]] + [(1 -
[alpha])sup.1/[delta]] [C.sub.H].
The FOC with respect to [omaga] are
[[alpha][[pi].sub.L]][beta] = [[mu].sub.L][[alpha]'.sub.L],
[[alpha][[pi].sub.H]][beta] = [[mu].sub.H][[alpha]'.sub.H],
[(1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.L][beta] = [[mu].sub.L](1 -
[[alpha]'sub.L])],
[(1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.H][beta] = [[mu].sub.H](1 -
[[alpha]'sub.H])].
These imply that
[[alpha][[pi].sub.L][beta] + (1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.[beta]] =
[[mu].sub.L][[alpha]'.sub.L] + [[mu].sub.L] (1 -
[[alpha]'.sub.L])],
and therefore [[pi].sub.L][beta]] + [[mu].sub.L]] and
[[pi].sub.H][beta]] + [[mu].sub.H]]. Using the FOC with respect to w
again, these two conditions imply [[alpha] = [[alpha]'sub.L] =
[[alpha]'sub.H]]. Thus, the Pareto weights will be constant in this
problem.
Using the fact that individual consumption is a share of aggregate
consumption and that Pareto weights are constant, this problem can be
rewritten as one solving for the consumption (or capital accumulation)
of a representative consumer with aggregate preference shocks. In that
case, the state-dependent utility of the representative consumer,
[u.sub.R], would be
[[u.sub.R(s, C) = ((s[alpha]1/[delta] + [(1 -
[alpha]).sup.1/[delta])sup.[delta]][[C.sup.1-[delta]]/[1 - [delta]].
Notice here that the level of the shock depends not just on the
size of s, but also on [alpha]. This representation is useful to
understand that the optimal investment decision is affected by the
realization of the preference shock and the distributional parameter
[alpha]. When s is larger, the representative agent prefers to increase
consumption today and decrease investment. Given the same shock, the
size of the drop in investment depends on the Pareto weight of the agent
that received the shock.
The FOC with respect to capital accumulation are
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
An application of the envelope conditions makes these conditions
imply the standard Euler equations determining capital accumulation,
[1 = (F'[k'.sub.L] + (1 -
[delta]))[beta]([[pi].sub.L][s.sub.L][([c'.sub.1L]).sup.-[delta]] +
[[pi].sub.H][s.sub.H] [([c'.sub.1H]).sup.-[delta]]/[s.sub.L]
[([c.sub.1L].sup.-[delta]]
[1 = (F'[k'.sub.H] + (1 -
[delta]))[beta]([[pi].sub.L][s.sub.L][([c'.sub.1L]).sup.-[delta]] +
[[pi].sub.H][s.sub.H] [([c'.sub.1H]).sup.-[delta]]/[s.sub.H]
[([c.sub.1H].sup.-[delta]]
2. NUMERICAL SOLUTION
This model can be solved in the computer once the values of the
parameters are determined. Most of the parameters are standard in the
neoclassical growth model and take standard values. Others, such as the
size of the preference shock and the probability of occurrence, were
chosen only to illustrate the behavior of the model. In particular, a
high preference shock happens on average every 6.7 years, but it is
large enough to demand a significant amount of resources. Think, for
example, that a country in an economic union requires help or assistance
on average every 6.7 years. Table 1 presents the values for all the
parameters of the model.
The right-hand side of (1)-(5) defines a contraction. The
computation is based on value function iteration as follows. Guess a
function V. Then solve for [max.sub.c,w' k'] using V, the FOC
described above, and numerical maximization.
Table 1 Parameter Values
Parameter Value
[gamma] Exponent of 0.30
capital in
production
function
[delta] Depreciation 0.07
rate of
capital
[beta] Discount 0.97
factor
[partial Relative risk 0.50
derivative] aversion
sL Low value of 0.95
the
preference
shock
sH High value of 1.05
the and
preference 2.00
shock
[pi]L Probability 0.85
of low value
of the
preference
shock
[pi]H Probability 0.15
of high value
of the
preference
shock
With this solution, construct a new function V' and restart
the maximization unless V is sufficiently close to V. Now we discuss the
results using the parameters in Table 1 with [s.sub.H] = 2 and Pareto
weights {0.75, 0.25}. Figure 1 presents time series for aggregate
consumption and capital accumulation in the steady state of this
economy. On the top panel that aggregate consumption jumps after a
preference shock and then returns slowly to a relatively constant value
until a new shock hits. As a consequence, capital accumulation drops
after a high preference shock to accommodate larger aggregate
consumption, as shown on the top panel. The effect of this change on the
incentives to misreport a shock--if it would be unobservable--is
discussed in the next section. The distribution of consumption among
agents is determined by equations (6), i.e., agent 1's share of
aggregate consumption increases with the value of the shock. More on
this later.
Figure 2 depicts the stationary distribution of the main variables
for the same example analyzed in Figure 1. The top left panel shows that
15 percent of the time there is a large preference shock equal to 2 and
most of the time (85 percent) a low shock equal to 0.95. The top right
panel presents the stationary distribution of capital. It is somehow
surprising that very different values (e.g., 3 and 6) are reached with
positive probability. Most of its mass is accumulated on the higher
values, however. Those correspond to periods with low preference shocks.
The lowest values of capital correspond to periods of several
consecutive high preference shocks. Something similar happens with
[c.sub.2], on the bottom right panel. A priori, these properties could
have been expected since k' and [c.sub.2] are the two sources to
finance transfers to agent 1 after a high preference shock. The
distribution of [c.sub.1], presented on the bottom left panel, has most
of the mass around lower values and some mass at higher values. The
highest values correspond to a high preference shock hitting the economy
after a long period of low shocks.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
3. THE ROLE OF INFORMATION
This section investigates the incentives to misreport preference
shocks by agent 1 whenever the full information allocation described
above is the target to be implemented. To do so, consider the value of
the following (implicit) incentive compatibility constraints:
[[[icc.sub.HL] = [s.sub.H]u ([c.sub.1H]) + [[betta][[omega].sub.1H]
- [[s.sub.H]u ([c.sub.1L]) + [[beta][omega].sub.1L]], (7)
[[[icc.sub.LH] = [s.sub.L]u ([c.sub.1L]) + [[betta][[omega].sub.1L]
- [[s.sub.L]u ([c.sub.1H]) + [[beta][omega].sub.1H]], (8)
The interpretation of these variables is very important for the
analysis hereafter. If the variable [icc.sub.HL] is positive, it means
that when the state H realizes, agent 1 would prefer truthfully
reporting a high preference shock and obtaining {[c.sub.1H], [w.sub.1H]}
instead of misreporting it and receiving {[c.sub.1L], [w.sub.1L]}.
Similarly, a negative value of [icc.sub.LH] means that agent 1 would
prefer misreporting a high preference shock and obtaining {[c.sub.1H],
[w.sub.1H]} to truthfully reporting a low shock and receiving
{[c.sub.1L], [w.sub.1L]}.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Since [c.sub.1H] Greater than [c.sub.1L], one may expect that there
is no incentive to report the low shock when the high shock was actually
realized, i.e., a positive value of [icc.sub.HL]. This is actually what
happens in the stationary distribution, as shown on the top panel of
Figure 3. In contrast, agent 1 may be tempted to misreport a high
preference shock to obtain higher consumption. Remember that this would
imply that [icc.sub.LH] < 0. This does not need to always be the
case, however. Since k' is lower after a high preference shock,
agent 1's prospects worsen after a high preference shock. Thus, it
will be a race between more consumption today, [c.sub.1H] >
[c.sub.1L], and less future consumption, [w.sub.1L] > [w.sub.1H]. The
results for the example described above are presented in the bottom
panel of Figure 3. There, [icc.sub.LH] is negative more than 80 percent
of the time but positive in some instances. This means that in all such
instances, the drop in from-tomorrow-on utilities caused by reporting a
high preference shock is enough to compensate for the negative or
positive will be studied next by analyzing different examples.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The next two examples capture the role of the size of
redistribution versus disinvestment. The first example is presented in
Figure 4. This is the same example in all the previous figures, but the
difference is that the Pareto weight of agent 1 is only 0.33 (instead of
0.75) and the weight of agent 2 is 0.67. This implies that agent
2's consumption is larger, as shown in the top left panel. The top
right panel presents the behavior of capital accumulation. Notice that
the time series in the graphs correspond to the transition toward a
higher level of capital. From these two figures it is clear that a
nontrivial part of the rise in agent 1's consumption after a high
preference shock comes from redistribution of consumption across agents.
As a consequence, the promised utilities from next period on are not
that different after a report of high or low preference shock, as shown
in the bottom left panel. In turn, this implies that [icc.sub.LH] is
always negative, as presented in the right bottom panel. Thus, this is
an example in which the full information allocation would not be
implementable under private information: After a low preference shock,
agent 1 would prefer to falsely report a high preference shock.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Now consider the example presented in Figure 5. Here, the behavior
of the same series is presented for an economy in which the Pareto
weight of agent 1 is 0.85 and the steady-state distribution of capital
is reached. This implies that agent l's consumption is much larger
than that of agent 2, as shown in the top left panel. As a consequence,
capital accumulation must vary significantly to provide more consumption
to agent 1 after the realization of a high preference shock. This is
shown in the top right panel. Therefore, as presented in the bottom left
panel, the difference in from-tomorrow-on utilities associated with low
and high preference shocks is large. Thus, both incentive compatibility
constraints are positive in the stationary distribution of this economy
(see bottom right panel), and the full information allocation would be
implementable under private information.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The previous two examples are useful to understand that the
relative importance of the agent who privately observes the shock
matters for the role of private information. When this agent is more
important, her share of aggregate consumption is larger, and the rise of
that agent's consumption after a shock comes mainly from
disinvestment. This makes misreporting a high preference shock too
costly in terms of her own future consumption, and hence the full
information allocation is implementable under private information. Thus,
the size of disinvestment, determined by the importance of the agent
with the preference shock, matters for the provision of incentives under
private information. This suggests that in a fully specified model with
private information, the planner would like to increase the Pareto
weight of the agent with private information to reduce the incidence of
this friction.
The next example illustrates the role of the outlook for economic
growth at the time of disinvestment in preventing misrepresentation of
preference shocks. First, consider the example in Figure 6. It displays
the transition to the steady state from a larger stock of capital. The
weights of agents 1 and 2 are 0.75 and 0.25, respectively. Initially,
consumption, capital, and from-tomorrow-on utilities decrease. During
this initial phase, while capital is large and decreasing, [icc.sub.LH]
is negative and increasing. This means that when there is extra capital
in the economy, as compared to the stationary distribution, the optimal
drop in capital that a high preference shock would require (and its
corresponding drop in promised utility) is not large enough to provide
incentives to make the report of that shock incentive compatible.
Eventually, a high preference shock hits the economy, the consumption of
agent 1 jumps, and capital drops significantly. Now, the economy is
expected to grow in the coming years, which implies that another high
preference shock would hurt both agents more. Therefore, reporting a
high preference shock becomes incentive compatible for a few years,
until the stock of capital reaches a higher level. The same story occurs
again in a few years, when a high preference shock hits the economy
again. Thus, this example illustrates the interaction of growth and
information. Misrepresentation of preference shocks is more costly if
the economy is expected to grow. This finding suggests that a planner
solving for the best incentive-compatible allocation would delay growth
to facilitate the provision of incentives.
The last example confirms the importance of the size of
disinvestment and the outlook for economic growth. Consider the time
series artificial data presented in Figure 7. The Pareto weight for
agent 1 is larger than in previous examples, 0.85, but the value of the
high preference shock is smaller, sH = 1.05. First, notice that this
example confirms the result in the previous figure: It is easier to
provide incentives ([icc.sub.LH] is larger) when the economy is expected
to grow. However, in this case, [icc.sub.LH] is never greater than zero.
Notice that this happens despite agent l's weight being larger than
in all other examples. The key difference is that the shock is not that
large. Thus, the size of the drop in capital accumulation is not very
relevant, and therefore the difference between w\l and u)2l is small.
4. CONCLUSIONS
This article studies the interaction between growth and risk
sharing. First, it answers how investment is affected by insurance
needs. A stochastic growth model with two agents and preference shocks
is used to answer this question. Only one of the agents (or groups,
regions, countries) is affected by this shock, which basically increases
the need of consumption for this agent. When both agents are
risk-averse, the socially optimal response to this shock requires both
decreasing the consumption of other agents and decreasing capital
accumulation. Thus, the occurrence of this shock slows down the
convergence toward the stationary distribution of capital.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Then, we analyze if the best path of capital accumulation and
consumption allocation is implementable if needs are privately observed
by the agents. That is, if the shocks are privately observed by
individuals, do they have incentive to misrepresent? The value of the
incentive compatibility constraints implied by the full information
allocation is used to answer this question. Because investment drops
when an agent reports a high preference shock, the prospects of all
agents deteriorate after such a report. This may be enough to prevent
misreporting. The size of disinvestment after the report of a high
preference shock and the outlook for economic growth at the time of
disinvestment are important to induce individuals to report a low
realization of the preference shock truthfully. This analysis suggests
that in a fully specified model with private information, the best
incentive compatible allocation would tend to hurt growth, by decreasing
investment, and increase inequality, by augmenting the share of
consumption of the agent with private information. Of course, this is
only a conjecture. Solving for the constrained-efficient allocation in
this environment is necessary to verify the validity of this conjecture.
This is left for future research.
REFERENCES
Atkeson, Andrew, and Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1992. "On Efficient
Distribution with Private Information." Review of Economics Studies
59 (July): 427-53.
Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King. 1991. "Productive
Externalities and Business Cycles." Institute for Empirical
Macroeconomics at Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Discussion Paper
53.
Beker, Pablo F., and Emilio Espino. 2011. "The Dynamics of
Efficient Asset Trading with Heterogeneous Beliefs." Journal of
Economic Theory 146 (January): 189-229.
Caselli, Francesco, and Jaume Ventura. 2000. "A Representative
Consumer Theory of Distribution." American Economic Review 90
(September): 906-26.
Chakraborty, Shankha, and Amartya Lahiri. 2007. "Costly
Intermediation and the Poverty of Nations." International Economic
Review 48 (1): 155-83.
Chatterjee, Satyajit. 1994. "Transitional Dynamics and the
Distribution of Wealth in a Neoclassical Growth Model." Journal of
Public Economics 54 (May): 97-119.
Clementi, Gian Luca, Thomas Cooley, and Soni Di Giannatale. 2010.
"A Theory of Firm Decline." Review of Economic Dynamics 13
(October): 861-85.
Espino, Emilio. 2005. "On Ramsey's Conjecture: Efficient
Allocations in the Neoclassical Growth Model with Private
Information." Journal of Economic Theory 121 (April): 192-213.
Green, Edward J. 1987. "Lending and the Smoothing of
Uninsurable Income." In Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal
Trade, edited by Edward C. Prescott and Neil Wallace. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press, 3-25.
Greenwood, Jeremy, Juan M. Sanchez, and Cheng Wang. 2010a.
"Financing Development: The Role of Information Costs."
American Economic Review 100 (September): 1,875-91.
Greenwood, Jeremy, Juan M. Sanchez, and Cheng Wang. 2010b.
"Quantifying the Impact of Financial Development on Economic
Development." Economie d'Avant Garde Research Report 17.
Hall, Robert E. 1997. "Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the
Allocation of Time." Journal of Labor Economics 15 (January):
S223-50.
Khan, Aubhik. 2001. "Financial Development and Economic
Growth." Macroeconomic Dynamics 5 (June): 413-33.
Khan, Aubhik, and B. Ravikumar. 2001. "Growth and Risk-Sharing
with Private Information." Journal of Monetary Economics 47 (June):
499-521.
Lucas, Robert Jr., and Nancy L. Stokey. 1984. "Optimal Growth
with Many Consumers." Journal of Economic Theory 32 (February):
139-71.
Marcet, Albert, and Ramon Marimon. 1992. "Communication,
Commitment, and Growth." Journal of Economic Theory 58 (December):
219-49.
Sorger, Gerhard. 2002. "On the Long-Run Distribution of
Capital in the Ramsey Model." Journal of Economic Theory 105
(July): 226-43.
Spear, Stephen E., and Sanjay Srivastava. 1987. "On Repeated
Moral Hazard with Discounting." Review of Economic Studies 54
(October): 599-617.
Thomas, Jonathan, and Tim Worrall. 1990. "Income Fluctuation
and Asymmetric Information: An Example of a Repeated Principal-Agent
Problem." Journal of Economic Theory 51 (August): 367-90.
Wang, Cheng. 1997. "Incentives, CEO Compensation, and
Shareholder Wealth in a Dynamic Agency Model." Journal of Economic
Theory 76 (September): 72-105.
Wen, Yi. 2006. "Demand Shocks and Economic Fluctuations."
Economics Letters 90 (March): 378-83.
(1) See Wen (2006) for an overview and references therein.
(2) See Lucas and Stokey (1984) for a general early discussion and.
more recently, Sorger (2002).
(3) See also Khan (2001) and Chakraborty and Lahiri (2007).
(4) See Beker and Espino (2011) for a discussion about the
implementation and the corresponding technical details.
* Espino is an economist and professor at Universidad Torcuato Di
Telia. Sanchez is an economist affiliated with both the Richmond and St.
Louis Federal Reserve Banks. The authors gratefully acknowledge helpful
comments by Arantxa Jarque, Borys Grochulski, Ned Prescott, Nadezhda
Malysheva, and Constanza Liborio. The views expressed here do not
necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, or the Federal Reserve System.
E-mails: eespino@utdt.edu; juan.m.sanchez@stls.frb.org.