Estimating a search and matching model of the aggregate labor market.
Lubik, Thomas A.
The search and matching model has become the workhorse for labor
market issues in macroeconomics. It is a conceptually attractive
framework as it provides a rationale for the existence of equilibrium
unemployment, such that workers who would be willing to work for the
prevailing wage cannot find a job. By focusing on the search and
matching aspect, that is, workers searching for jobs, firms searching
for workers, and both sides being matched with each other, the model
also provides a description of employment flows in an economy. Moreover,
the search and matching model is tractable enough to be integrated into
standard macroeconomic models as an alternative to the perfectly
competitive Walrasian labor market model.
However, the search and matching framework has been criticized,
most notably by Shimer (2005), for being unable to match key labor
market statistics, chiefly the volatility of unemployment and job
vacancies. This observation has generated a large amount of research
intended to remedy this "puzzle." Most of this literature is
largely theoretical and based on calibration. Only recently have there
been efforts to more formally study the quantitative implications of the
entire search and matching framework. This article is among the first
attempts to take a search and matching model to the data in a
full-information setting. (1)
In this article I contribute to these efforts by estimating a small
search and matching model using Bayesian methods. My focus is mainly on
the actual parameter estimates and the implied sources of business cycle
fluctuations. Calibrating the search and matching model tends to be
problematic since some of the model parameters, such as the bargaining
share or the value of staying unemployed, are difficult to pin down.
Hence, much of the arguments about the empirical usefulness of the
search and matching model center around alternative calibrations. This
paper provides some perspective on this issue by adopting a
full-information approach in estimating the model. Parameters are
selected so as to be consistent with the co-movement patterns in the
full data set as seen through the prism of the theoretical model.
My main finding is that the structural parameters of the model are
generally tightly estimated and robust across various empirical
specifications that include different sets of observables and shock
processes. Parameters associated with the matching process tend to be
more stable than those associated with the search process. However, I
also find that the estimates are consistent with an emerging consensus
on the search and matching model (e.g., Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante
2005 and Hagedorn and Manovskii 2008) that emphasizes a low bargaining
power but a high outside option for a worker. On a more cautionary note,
I show that the most important determinant of labor market dynamics are
exogenous movements in the match efficiency, which essentially acts as a
residual in an adjustment equation for unemployment. This finding casts
doubt on the viability of the search and matching framework to provide a
theory for labor market dynamics.
In a larger sense, this article also deals with the issue of
identification in structural general equilibrium models. I use the term
"identification" loosely in that I ask whether the theoretical
model contains enough restrictions to back out parameters from the data.
In that respect, the search and matching framework performs reasonably
well. But identification also has a dimension that may be more relevant
for the theoretical modeler. I show that specific parameters, such as
the worker benefit or search costs, can vary widely across
specifications, and thus are likely not identified in either an
econometric or economic sense. I also argue that they capture the stable
behavior of an underlying structure. They therefore adapt to a change in
the environment and might be better described as reduced-form
coefficients.
The article proceeds as follows. In the next section, I lay out a
simple search and matching model, followed by a discussion in Section 2
of the empirical strategy and the data used. In Section 3, I present the
benchmark estimation results, discuss the estimated dynamics, and
investigate the sources of business cycle fluctuations. Section 4
contains various robustness checks that change the set of observables
and the exogenous shocks. Section 5 concludes.
1. A SIMPLE SEARCH AND MATCHING MODEL
I develop a simple search and matching model in which the labor
market is subject to frictions. Workers and firms cannot meet
instantaneously but must go through a time-consuming search process. The
costs of finding a partner give rise to rents that firms and workers
share between each other. Thus, wages are the outcome of a bargaining
process and are not determined competitively. The labor market set-up is
embedded in a simple general equilibrium framework with optimizing
consumers and firms that serves as a data-generating process for
aggregate time series. The model is otherwise standard and has been
extensively studied in the literature. (2) I first describe the
optimization problems of households and firms, followed by a discussion
of the labor market and wage determination.
The Household
Time is discrete and the time period is one quarter. The economy is
populated by a continuum of households. Each household consists of a
continuum of workers of measure one. Individual households send out
their members to the labor market, where they search for jobs when
unemployed, and supply labor services when employed. During unemployment
the afflicted household member receives government benefits, while all
employed workers earn the wage rate. Total income is shared equally
among all members. I hereby follow the literature and abstract from
heterogeneity in asset holdings and consumption of individual workers
and households (see Merz 1995). (3) In what follows I drop any
household- and worker-specific indices.
The intertemporal utility of a representative household is
[E.sub.t][[infinity].summation over ([j=t])] [[beta].sup.[j-t]]
[[[C.sub.j.sup.[1-[sigma]]] - 1/1 - [sigma]] - [[chi].sub.j][n.sub.j]],
(1)
where C is aggregate consumption and n [member of] [0, 1] is the
fraction of employed household members, which is determined in the
matching market for labor services and is not subject to the
household's control. [beta] [member of] (0, 1) is the discount
factor and [sigma] [greater than or equal to] 0 is the coefficient of
relative risk aversion. [x.sub.t] is an exogenous stochastic process,
which I refer to as a labor shock. Note that in the benchmark version I
assume that households value leisure, which is subject to stochastic shifts. As we will see later on, this affects wage determination and the
interpretation of the parameter estimates.
The representative household's budget constraint is
[C.sub.t] + [T.sub.t] = [w.sub.t][n.sub.t] + (1 - [n.sub.t])b +
[[PI].sub.t].(2)
The household receives unemployment benefits, b, from the
government, which are financed by a lump-sum tax, T. [[PI].sub.t] are
profits that the household receives as the owner of the firms. w is the
wage paid to each employed worker. The sole problem of the household is
to determine the consumption path of its members. There is no explicit
labor supply choice since the employment status of the workers is the
outcome of the matching process. Since the household's program does
not involve any intertemporal decision, the first-order condition is
simply
[C.sub.t.sup.-[sigma]] = [[lambda].sub.t] (3)
where [[lambda].sub.t] is the Lagrange multiplier on the budget
constraint.
The Labor Market
The household supplies labor services to firms in a frictional
labor market. Search frictions are captured by a matching function
m([u.sub.t], [[upsilon].sub.t]) = [u.sub.t][u.sub.t.sup.[xi]]
[[upsilon].sub.t.sub.[1-[xi]]], which describes the outcome of the
search process. Unemployed job seekers, [u.sub.t] and vacancies,
[[upsilon].sub.t], are matched at rate m([u.sub.t], [[upsilon].sub.t]),
where 0 < [xi] < 1 is the match elasticity of the unemployed, and
the stochastic process, [[mu].sub.t], affects the efficiency of the
matching process. The aggregate probability of filling a vacancy (taken
parametrically by the firms) is q ([[theta].sub.t]) =
m([[upsilon].sub.t], [u.sub.t]/[[upsilon].sub.t], where [[theta].sub.t]
= [[upsilon].sub.t]/[u.sub.t] is labor market tightness. I assume that
it takes one period for new matches to become productive and that both
old and new matches are destroyed at a constant rate. The evolution of
employment, defined as [n.sub.t], = 1 - [u.sub.t], is then given by
[n.sub.2] = (1 - [rho]) [[n.sub.[t-1]] +
[[upsilon].sub.[t-1]]q([[theta].sub[t-1]])], (4)
where 0 < [rho] < 1 is the constant separation rate that
measures inflows into unemployment.
The Firms
The firm sector is populated by monopolistically competitive firms
that produce differentiated products. This assumption deviates from the
standard search and matching framework, which lets atomistic firms
operate in a perfectly competitive environment. I introduce this
modification to be able to analyze the effects of mark-up variations on
labor market dynamics, as suggested by Rotemberg (2008). The firms'
output is demanded by households with a preference for variety that
results in downward-sloping demand curves. Thus, a typical firm faces a
demand function:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
where [y.sub.t] is firm production (and its demand), [Y.sub.t] is
aggregate output, [p.sub.t] is the price set by the firm, and [P.sub.t]
is the aggregate price index. The stochastic process, [[epsilon].sub.t],
is the time-varying demand elasticity. I assume that all firms behave
symmetrically and suppress firm-specific indices. The firm's
production function is
[y.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][n.sub.t.sup.[alpha]] (6)
[A.sub.t] is an aggregate technology process and 0 < [alpha]
[less than or equal to] 1 introduces curvature into production. This
implicitly assumes that capital is fixed and firm-specific.
The firm chooses its desired number of workers, [n.sub.t], the
number of vacancies, [[upsilon].sub.t], to be posted, and its optimal
price, [p.sub.t], by maximizing the intertemporal profit function
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
subject to the employment accumulation equation (4) and the demand
function (5). Profits are evaluated at the household's discount
factor in terms of marginal utility, [[lambda].sub.t]. Following
Rotemberg (2008), I assume that vacancy posting is subject to cost,
[k/[psi] [[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[psi]]] where k > 0 and [psi] > 0.
For 0 < [psi] < 1, posting costs exhibit decreasing returns while
costs are increasing for [psi] > 1. The standard case in the
literature with fixed vacancy costs is given by [psi] = 1.
The first-order conditions are
[[tau].sub.t] = [alpha] [y.sub.t]/[n.sub.t] [[epsilon].sub.t]/1 +
[[epsilon].sub.t]] - [w.sub.t] + (1 - [rho]) [E.sub.t][[beta].sub.t + 1]
[[tau].sub.t + 1] and (8)
K[[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[[psi]-1]] = (1 - [rho])q([[theta].sub.t])
[E.sub.t][[beta].sub.[t + 1]] [[tau].sub.[t + 1]], (9)
where [[beta].sub.[t+1]]) =
[[beta][lambda].sub.[t+1]]/[[lambda].sub.t] is a stochastic discount
factor and [[tau].sub.t] is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the
employment constraint. It represents the current-period marginal value of a job. This is given by a worker's marginal productivity, net of
wage payments, and the expected value of the worker in the next period
if the job survives separation.
Since hiring is costly, firms spread employment adjustment over
time. Firms that hire workers today reap benefits in the future since
lower hiring costs can be expended otherwise. This is captured by the
second condition, which links the expected benefit of a vacancy in terms
of the marginal value of a worker to its cost, given by the left-hand
side. Note that this is adjusted by the job creation or hiring rate,
q([[theta].sub.t]) = [m.sub.t] [([v.sub.t]/[u.sub.t]).sup.-[xi]]. Firms
are more willing to post vacancies, the higher the probability is that
they can find a worker. Moreover, vacancy posting also depends
positively on the worker's expected marginal value,
[[tau].sub.[t+1]], (and thus productivity and wages) and on the
elasticity of posting costs.
Combining these two equations results in the job creation condition
typically found in the literature:
k[[[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[[psi]-1]]/q([[theta].sub.t])] = (1-[rho])
[E.sub.t][[beta].sub.[t+1]] [[alpha] [[y.sub.[t+1]]/[n.sub.[t+1]]]
[[[epsilon].sub.[t+1]]/1+[[epsilon].sub.[t+1]]] - [w.sub.[t+1]] +
[k[[upsilon].sub.[t+1].sup.[[psi]-1]]/q([[theta].sub.[t+1]])]] (10)
The left-hand side captures effective marginal hiring costs, which
a firm trades off against the surplus over wage payments it can
appropriate and against the benefit of not having to hire someone next
period.
Wage Determination
Wages are determined as the outcome of a bilateral bargaining
process between workers and firms. Since the workforce is homogeneous
without any differences in skill, each worker is marginal when
bargaining with the firm. Both parties choose wage rates to maximize the
joint surplus generated from their employment relationship: Surpluses
accruing to the matched parties are split to maximize the weighted
average of the individual surpluses. It is common in the literature to
assume a bargaining function, S, of the following type:
[S.sub.t] [equivalent to] [(1/[[lambda].sub.t] [partial
derivative][W.sub.t] ([n.sub.t])/[partial
derivative][n.sub.t]).sup.[eta]] [([partial derivative] [J.sub.t]
([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t]).sup.[1 - [eta]]] (11)
where [eta] [member of] [0, 1] is the workers' weight,
[partial derivative][W.sub.t]] ([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t]
is the marginal value of a worker to the household's welfare, and
[partial derivative][J.sub.t]] ([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t]
is the marginal value of the worker to the firm. (4)
The latter term is given by the firm's first-order condition
with respect to employment, Eq. (8), where we define [[tau].sub.t] =
[partial derivative] [J.sub.t] ([n.sub.t])/[partial
derivative][n.sub.t]. The marginal utility value, [partial
derivative][W.sub.t] ([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t], can be
found by comparing the options available to the worker in terms of a
recursive representation. If the worker is employed, he contributes to
household value by earning a wage, [w.sub.t]. However, he suffers
disutility from working, [[chi].sub.t], (which is simply the exogenous
preference shifter), and forfeits the outside option payments, b. This
is weighted against next period's expected utility. The marginal
value of a worker is thus given by
[partial derivative][W.sub.t]] ([n.sub.t])/[partial
derivative][n.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.t][w.sub.t] - [[lambda].sub.t]b -
[[chi].sub.t] + [beta][E.sub.t][partial
derivative][W.sub.[t+1]]([n.sub.[t+1]])/[partial
derivative][n.sub.[t+1]] [partial derivative][n.sub.[t+1]]/[partial
derivative][n.sub.t] (12)
Using the employment equation (4), I can then substitute for
[partial derivative][n.sub.[t+1]]/[partial derivative][n.sub.t] = (1 -
[rho])[1 - [[theta].sub.t]q ([[theta].sub.t])]. Furthermore, note that
real payments are valued at the marginal utility, [[lambda].sub.t].
Taking derivatives of (11) with respect to the bargaining variable,
[w.sub.t], results in the standard optimality condition for wages:
(1 - [eta]) 1/[[lambda].sub.t] [[[partial
derivative][W.sub.t]([n.sub.t])]/[[partial derivative][n.sub.t]] = [eta]
[[partial derivative][J.sub.t]([n.sub.t])/[[partial
derivative][n.sub.t]]. (13)
Substituting the marginal utility values results, after lengthy
algebra, in an expression for the bargained wage:
[w.sub.t] = [eta] [[[alpha][y.sub.t]/[n.sub.t]] [[epsilon].sub.t]/1
+ [[epsilon].sub.t] + k[[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[[psi]-1]] [[theta].sub.t]]]
+ (1 - [eta]) [b + [[chi].sub.t][c.sub.t.sup.[sigma]]]. (14)
As is typical in models with surplus sharing, the wage is a
weighted average of the payments accruing to workers and firms, with
each party appropriating a fraction of the other's surplus. The
bargained wage also includes mutual compensation for costs incurred,
namely hiring costs and the utility cost of working. The bargaining
weight determines how close the wage is to either the marginal product or to the outside option of the worker, the latter of which has two
components, unemployment benefits and the consumption utility of
leisure.
Closing the Model
I assume that government benefits, b, to the unemployed are
financed by lumpsum taxes, T, and that the government runs a balanced
budget, [T.sub.t] = (1 - [n.sub.t])b. The social resource constraint is,
therefore,
[C.sub.t] + k/[psi] [[upsilon].sub.t.sup.[psi]] = [Y.sub.t]. (15)
In the aggregate, employment evolves according to the law of
motion:
[n.sub.t] = (1 - [rho]) [[n.sub.[t-1]] + [[mu].sub.[t-1]]
[u.sub.[t-1].sup.[xi]][[upsilon].sub.[t-1].sup.[1-[xi]]]. (16)
The model description is completed by specifying the properties of
the shocks, namely the technology shock. [A.sub.t], the labor shock,
[[chi].sub.t], the demand shock, [[epsilon].sub.t], and the matching
shock, [[mu].sub.t]. I assume that the logarithms of these shocks follow
independent AR(1) processes with coefficients [[rho].sub.i], i [member
of] (A, [chi], [epsilon], [mu]) and innovations [[member of].sub.i]
[.sup.~] N (0, [[sigma].sub.i.sup.2]).
2. EMPIRICAL APPROACH
Most papers in the labor market search and matching literature that
take a quantitative perspective rely on calibration methods and
concentrate on the model's ability to replicate a few key
statistics. One issue with such an approach is that information on some
model parameters is difficult to come by. The bargaining parameter,
[eta], and the worker's outside option, b, are prime examples. Much
of the debate on the viability of search and matching as a description
of the labor market centers around the exact values of these parameters
(Shimer 2005; Hagedorn and Manovskii 2008). In this article, I therefore
take an encompassing, but somewhat agnostic, perspective on the
model's empirical implication. I treat the model as a
data-generating process for a large set of aggregate variables. My focus
is on the actual parameter estimates, the implied adjustment dynamics,
and the contribution of various driving forces to labor market
movements.
Methodology
I estimate the model using Bayesian methods. First, I log-linearize
the nonlinear model around a deterministic steady state and write the
linearized equilibrium conditions in a state-space form. The resulting
linear rational expectations model can then easily be solved by methods
such as in Sims (2002). The model thus describes a data-generating
process for a set of aggregate variables. Define a vector of model
variables, [X.sub.t], and a data vector of observable variables,
[Z.sub.t]. The state-space representation of the model can then be
written as
[X.sub.t] = [GAMMA][X.sub.[t-1]] + [psi][[member of].sub.t] and
(17)
[Z.sub.t] = [PHI][X.sub.t], (18)
where [GAMMA] and [PSI] are coefficient matrices, the elements of
which are typically nonlinear functions of the structural parameters,
and [PHI] is a selection matrix that maps the model variables to the
observables. [[member of].sub.t] collects the innovations of the shocks.
In applications, there are typically more variables than
observables. The empirical likelihood function can therefore not be
computed in the standard manner since the algorithm has to account for
the evolution of the model variables not in the data set. This can
easily be done using the Kalman filter, which implicitly constructs time
series for the unobserved variables. A second concern for the modeler is
to ensure that there is enough independent variation in the model to be
able to explain the data. In order to avoid this potential stochastic
singularity, there have to be at least as many sources of uncertainty in
the empirical model as there are observables. This imposes a choice upon
the researcher that can affect the estimation results in a nontrivial manner.
In the benchmark specification, I treat the model as a
data-generating process for four aggregate variables: unemployment,
vacancies, wages, and output. A potential pitfall is that unemployment
and vacancies are highly negatively correlated in the data and may
therefore not contain enough independent variation to be helpful in
identifying parameters. Moreover, the employment equation (4) implies
that these two variables co-move perfectly. With both unemployment and
vacancy data used in the estimation, this relationship would most likely
be violated. Hence, I need to introduce an additional source of
variation to break this link, which I do by making the match efficiency
parameter an exogenous process. I choose not to include consumption
since my focus is on the labor market aspects of the model; nor do I use
data on, for instance, the hiring rate, q([[theta].sub.t]), since the
model implies that it is a log-linear function of [u.sub.t] and
[[upsilon].sub.t]. (5)
The use of four series of observables requires the inclusion of at
least four independent sources of variation. Researchers not only have
to rely on standard shocks such as technology or variations in market
power (i.e., shocks to the demand elasticity, [epsilon]), but they often
have to introduce disturbances that may be considered nonstandard. (6)
This can take the form of converting fixed parameters into exogenous
stochastic processes, such as the shock to the match efficiency, [mu],
used above. Shocks can also capture "wedges" between marginal
rates of substitution (Hall 1997), such as the one between the real wage
and the marginal product of labor, that the model would otherwise not be
able to explain. The labor shock, [chi], is an example of this approach.
In order to implement the Bayesian estimation procedure, I employ
the Kalman filter to evaluate the likelihood function of the observable
variables, which I then combine with the prior distribution of the model
parameters to obtain the posterior distribution. The posterior
distribution is evaluated numerically by employing the random-walk
Metropolis-Hastings algorithm. Further details on the computational
procedure are discussed in Lubik and Schorfheide (2005) and An and
Schorfheide (2007).
Data
For the estimation, I use observations on four data series:
unemployment, vacancies, wages, and output. I extract quarterly data
from the Haver Analytics database. The data set covers a sample from
1964:1-2008:4. The starting date of the sample is determined by the
availability of the earnings series. Unemployment is measured by the
unemployment rate of over-16-year-olds. The series for vacancies is the
index of help-wanted ads in the 50 major metropolitan areas. I capture
real wages by dividing average weekly earnings in private nonfarm
employment by the GDP deflator in chained 2,000$. The output series is
real GDP in chained 2,000$. I convert the output series to per-capita
terms by scaling with the labor force. All series are passed through the
Hodrick-Prescott filter with smoothing parameter 1,600 and are demeaned
prior to estimation.
Prior
I choose priors for the Bayesian estimation based on the typical
values used in calibration studies. I assign share parameters a Beta
distribution with support on the unit interval, and I use Gamma
distributions for real-valued parameters. I roughly distinguish between
two groups of parameters--those associated with production and
preferences, and labor market parameters. I choose tight priors for the
former, but fairly uninformative priors for most of the latter because
the literature lacks independent evidence or disagreement. The priors
are reported in Table 1.
Table 1 Prior Distributions
Definition Parameter Density Mean Std. Dev.
Discount factor [beta] Fixed 0.99 --
Labor elasticity [alpha] Fixed 0.67 --
Demand elasticity [epsilon] Fixed 10.00 --
Relative risk [sigma] Gamma 1.00 0.10
aversion
Match elasticity [xi] Beta 0.70 0.15
Match efficiency [mu] Gamma 0.60 0.15
Separation rate [rho] Beta 0.10 0.02
Bargaining power of [eta] Uniform 0.50 0.25
the worker
Unemployment benefit b Beta 0.40 0.20
Elasticity of vacancy [psi] Gamma 1.00 0.50
creation
Scaling factor on [kappa] Gamma 0.05 0.01
vacancy creation
AR-coefficients of [[rho].sub.i] Beta 0.90 0.05
shocks
Standard deviation of [[sigma].sub.i] Inverse Gamma 0.01 1.00
shocks
I set the discount factor, [beta], at a value of 0.99. The labor
input elasticity, [alpha], is kept fixed at 0.67, the average labor
share in the U.S. economy, while the demand elasticity, [epsilon], is
set to a mean value of 10, which implies a steady-state mark-up of 10
percent, a customary value in the literature. (7) I choose a reasonably
tight prior for the intertemporal substitution elasticity, [sigma],
centered on one. The priors of the matching function parameters are
chosen to be consistent with the observed job-finding rate of 0.7 per
quarter (Shinier 2005). This leads to a prior mean of 0.7 for the match
elasticity, [xi], and of 0.6 for the match efficiency, [mu]. I allow for
a reasonably wide coverage interval as these values are not
uncontroversial in calibration exercises. Similarly, I set the mean
exogenous separation rate at [rho] = 0.1 with a standard deviation of
0.02.
I choose to be agnostic about the bargaining parameter, [eta].
Calibration studies have used a wide range of values, most of which
center around 0.5. Since I am interested in how much information on
[eta] is in the data, which matters for determining the volatility of
wages and labor market tightness, I choose a uniform prior over the unit
interval. Similarly, the value of the outside option of the worker is
crucial to the debate on whether the search and matching model is
consistent with labor market fluctuations (Hagedorn and Manovskii 2008).
Consequently, I set b at a mean of 0.4 with a very wide coverage region.
The prior mean for the vacancy posting elasticity, [psi], is 1 with
a large standard deviation. Linear posting cost is the standard
assumption in the literature, but I allow here for both concave and
convex recruiting costs as in Rotemberg (2008). The scale parameter in
the vacancy cost function is tightly set to K = 0.05. Finally, we
specify the exogenous stochastic processes in the model as AR(1)
processes with a prior mean on the autoregressive parameters of 0.90 and
the innovations as having inverse-gamma distributions with typical
standard deviations. Moreover, I normalize the means of the productivity
process, [A.sub.t], and of the labor shock, [x.sub.t], at 1, while the
means of the other shock processes are structural parameters to be
estimated.
3. BENCHMARK RESULTS
Parameter Estimates
I report posterior means and 90 percent coverage intervals in Table
2. Three parameter estimates stand out. First, the posterior estimate of
[eta] is almost zero with a 90 percent coverage region that is
concentrated and shifted away considerably from the prior. This implies
that firms can lay claim to virtually their entire surplus (and are
therefore quite willing to create vacancies) while workers are just paid
the small outside benefit, b, and compensation for the disutility of
working (see Eq. [14]). Moreover, the disutility of working has an
additional cyclical component via the labor shocks. In order to balance
this so that wages do not become excessively volatile and thus stymie vacancy creation, the estimation algorithm adjusts the contribution of
the marginal product downward, which reduces the bargaining parameter
even further.
Table 2 Posterior Estimates: Benchmark Model
Prior Posterior
Mean Mean 90 Percent Interval
Relative risk [sigma] 1.00 0.72 [0.62. 0.79]
aversion
Match [xi] 0.70 0.74 [0.68, 0.82]
elasticity
Scaling factor m 0.60 0.81 [0.58, 0.99]
matching
function
Separation [rho] 0.10 0.12 [0.09, 0.15]
rate
Bargaining [eta] 0.50 0.03 [0.00, 0.07]
power
Benefit b 0.40 0.18 [0.12, 0.22]
Vacancy cost [psi] 1.00 2.53 [0.92, 3.54]
elasticity
Vacancy K 0.05 0.05 [0.03, 0.06]
creation cost
Second, the posterior estimate of the benefit parameter b = 0.18 is
moved away considerably from the prior without much overlap with the
prior coverage regions. The posterior is also much more concentrated,
which indicates that the data are informative. Thus, this estimate seems
to indicate that the model resolves the Shimer puzzle in favor of smooth
wages to stimulate vacancy posting, and not through a high outside
option of the worker. Recall that Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008) suggest
values of b as high as 0.9, to which the posterior distribution assigns
zero probability. This reasoning is misleading, however, as some
parameters may be specific to the environment they live in. The benefit
parameter, b, is a case in point. In the model it is introduced as
payment a worker receives when unemployed. What matters for wage
determination, however, is the overall outside option of the worker,
which in my model is b + [X.sub.t] [c.sub.t.sup.[sigma]]. That is, it
includes the endogenous disutility of working. This becomes an issue of
how to interpret the large variations in this parameter that are
reported in both the calibration and the estimation literature. For
instance, Trigari (2004) reports a value of b = 0.03 in an estimated
model that includes a utility value of leisure over both an extensive
and intensive labor margin, while Gertler, Sala, and Trigari (2008) find
b = 0.98 in a framework without these elements.
The discussion thus indicates that the generic parameter, b, is not
structural per se, but rather a reduced-form coefficient that captures
part of the outside option of the worker relevant for explaining wage
dynamics. Its value varies with the other components of the outside
option. To get a sense of the magnitude of the latter, I compute b + X
[c.sup.[sigma]] at the posterior mean and find 0.74 with a 90 percent
coverage region of [0.56, 0.88]. In the end, this does give support to
the argument in Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008) that a high outside option
of the worker is needed to match vacancy and unemployment dynamics via
smooth wages. The caveat for calibration studies is that values for b
cannot be taken off the shelf but should be chosen to match, for
instance, wage dynamics.
The third surprising estimate is the vacancy posting elasticity,
[psi], with a posterior mean of 2.53, which is also considerably shifted
away from the prior. This makes vacancy creation more costly to the firm
since marginal postings costs are increasing in the level of vacancies,
and therefore labor market tightness. This estimate is substantially
different from what is typically assumed in the calibration literature.
In most papers, vacancy creation costs are linear, i.e., [psi] = 1.
Rotemberg (2008) even assumes values as low as [psi] = 0.2. A likely
explanation for this high value is that it balances potentially
"excessive" vacancy creation that is driven by a low [eta] and
by the exogenous shocks.
Estimates for the other labor market parameters are much less
dramatic and show substantial overlap with the priors. The posterior
means of the matching function parameters are in line with other values
in the literature, although the match elasticity, [xi], of 0.74 is at
the high end of the range typically considered. However, there is
significant probability mass on the more typical values. The estimate of
the level parameter, [kappa], in the vacancy cost function simply
replicates the prior, and would therefore not be identified in a purely
econometric sense. The estimate of the intertemporal substitution
elasticity, [sigma], as 0.72 is not implausible, and it is reasonably
tight and different from the prior. The autoregressive coefficients of
the shocks (not reported) are largely clustered around 0.8, which
suggests that the model does generate enough of an internal propagation
mechanism to capture the still substantial persistence in the filtered
data.
I also assess the overall fit of the model, and report some
statistics in Table 3. I first compare the structural model to a VAR(2)
estimated on the same four data series. There is typically no
expectation that a small-scale model such as this can match the overall
fit of an unrestricted VAR. This is confirmed by a comparison of the
marginal data densities (MDD). (8) While the fit of the structural model
is clearly worse than the VAR, and would therefore be rejected in a
Bayesian posterior odds as the preferred model, it appears to be at
least in the ballpark. Perhaps a more interesting measure is how well
the estimated model matches unconditional second moments in the data. I
compute various statistics from simulation of the estimated model with
parameters set at their posterior means. The model is reasonably
successful in matching these statistics. The volatility of HP-detrended
output is captured quite well, which is not surprising since the
technology process. [A.sub.t], is identified as the residual in the
production function and therefore adapts to the properties of output.
The relative standard deviations of unemployment and vacancies are also
close to the data, although the volatility of tightness is still
considerably off. Finally, wages are less volatile than in the data,
which contributes to the relative success of capturing vacancy dynamics.
The estimated model is less successful in capturing the high negative
correlation between unemployment and vacancies in the data, the
so-called Beveridge curve. These findings should not be overinterpreted,
however, since the empirical model is designed to capture the data well
simply by virtue of the exogenous shocks. An example of this is the
presence of the matching shock, which can act as a residual in the
employment equation. Consequently, this relative goodness of fit does
not invalidate the argument in Shimer (2005), which is based on a single
second moment, the volatility of tightness, and a single shock to labor
productivity.
Table 3 Measures of Fit: Benchmark Model
Data Model
Overall fit
MDD 736.20 667.50
Second moments
[sigma] (y) 1.61 1.67
[sigma] (u)/[sigma] (y) 7.53 6.49
[sigma]([upsilon])/[sigma] (y) 9.13 7.81
[sigma] ([theta])/[sigma] (y) 14.56 4.36
[sigma] (w)/[sigma] (y) 0.65 0.40
[rho] (u,[upsilon]) -0.89 -0.36
I can draw a few conclusions at this point. First, the structural
labor market model captures the data reasonably well, in particular the
high volatilities of unemployment and vacancies and the relative
smoothness of wages. The parameters for the matching process are tightly
estimated and close to those found in the calibration and nonstructural
estimation literature. There is more discrepancy in the parameters that
affect wage bargaining. The bargaining power of the worker is found to
be almost zero, while the outside option of the worker is fairly high.
The estimates thus confirm the reasoning in Hornstein, Krusell, and
Violante (2005), but they also suggest that specific parameters should
not be interpreted as strictly structural. Furthermore, the posterior
estimates raise questions about the extent to which the performance of
the model is due to the inherent dynamics of the search and matching
model or whether it is largely explained by the exogenous shocks. I
delve further into this issue in the next section.
Variance Decompositions
I now compute variance decompositions in order to investigate the
most important driving forces of the business cycle as seen through the
model. The results are reported in Table 4. The table shows that in the
estimated model unemployment and vacancies are exclusively driven by
demand and matching shocks. In the case of unemployment, the matching
shock essentially takes the role of a residual in the employment
equation (4), which confirms the impression formed above in the
comparison of simulated and data moments. This illustrates the
model's lack of an endogenous propagation mechanism, as emphasized
by Shimer (2005), and the overall fit of the employment equation.
Similarly, the demand shock mainly operates through the job creation
condition (10) as it affects the expected value of a job.
Table 4 Variance Decompositions: Benchmark Model
Technology Labor Demand Matching
U 0.00 0.00 0.08 0.92
[0.00, 0.00] [0.00, 0.00] [0.01, 0.14] [0.76, 0.99]
V 0.00 0.06 0.55 0.38
[0.00, 0.00] [0.00, 0.14] [0.41, 0.67] [0.25, 0.51]
W 0.32 0.10 0.43 0.15
[0.15, 0.45] [0.04, 0.17] [0.24, 0.50] [0.05, 0.26]
Y 0.71 0.04 0.04 0.21
[0.55, 0.87] [0.01, 0.08] [0.01, 0.08] [0.06, 0.32]
Employment and vacancy dynamics thus appear to be largely
independent from the rest of the model. An interesting implication of
this finding is that search and matching models that do not include
either shock offer an incomplete characterization of business cycle
dynamics in the sense that their contribution would be attributed to
other disturbances. An altogether more critical view would be that the
search and matching framework does not present a theory for unemployment
dynamics since they are explained exclusively by the residual in the
definitional equation (4). In other words, unemployment in the data can
be described by a persistent AR(1) process, which is introduced by the
matching shock. The intrinsic persistence component, i.e., lagged
employment and via the endogenous components of the matching function,
on the other hand, does not seem to matter as it likely imposes
restrictions that are violated in the data.
The picture for the other variables is more balanced: 70 percent of
output variations are explained by the technology shock and 21 percent
by the matching shock because of its influence on employment dynamics.
Demand and technology shocks explain most of the wage dynamics, with the
matching shock coming in a distant third. It is perhaps surprising that
the labor shock does not matter more as it directly affects wages
through the outside option of the worker. Moreover, it appears directly
only in the wage equation (14) and thus could be thought of as a
residual, similar to the matching shock. The variance decomposition would, however, support the idea that the wage equation is reasonably
well specified and that the need for a residual shock, designed to
capture the unexplained components of wage dynamics, is small.
4. ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
I now perform three robustness checks to assess the stability of
parameter estimates across specifications and to analyze the dependence
of estimates and variance decompositions on the specific choice of
observables and shocks. The first robustness check uses the same set of
observables as the benchmark, but introduces an AR(1) preference shock
to the discount factor, [[beta].sup.t] [[zeta].sub.t], instead of the
labor shock, [[chi].sub.t]. This changes the model specification in two
places: The discount factor in the job creation condition (10) now has
an additional time-varying component, and the time preference shock
essentially replaces the leisure preference shock in the wage equation
(14). Since this specification and the benchmark use the same set of
observables, I can directly compare the marginal data densities. The
time preference shock specification would be preferred with an MDD of
673.4. However, there are only small differences (not reported) in the
posterior means and the 90 percent coverage regions of the two
specifications overlap considerably. As in the case of the labor shock,
the preference shock plays only a minor role in explaining business
cycle dynamics. It does, however, reduce the importance of the demand
shock, [[epsilon].sub.t], in driving vacancies and wages. Its
contributions are now, respectively, 0.42 and 0.29. This indicates that
it may be difficult to disentangle the effects of a shock to the mark-up
(which I labeled a "demand" shock) from those of movements in
the intertemporal utility function.
In the second robustness check, I remove one series from the set of
observables. By excluding unemployment I can leave out the shock to
match efficiency, [[mu].sub.t]. This allows me to assess to what extent
the model is able to replicate vacancy and unemployment dynamics without
relying on movements in the residual. The prior specification is as
before. Selected results are reported in Table 5. The estimates are, in
many respects, strikingly different. The bargaining parameter, [eta], is
still very close to zero, while the benefit parameter, b, is close to
the prior mean, but also more concentrated. The total value of the
implied outside option is now 0.92 and thus matches the calibrated value
in Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008). The apparent reason is that in the
benchmark model, the matching shock played a crucial role in explaining
unemployment and vacancy dynamics. Without it, the estimation algorithm
has to compensate, and it does so in the direction suggested by these
authors: a low value of [eta] and a high value of b. This impression is
also supported by the decline in the vacancy cost elasticity. The table
also reports selected variance decompositions for unemployment,
vacancies, and the wage. The term in brackets below the entry denotes
the largest contributor to the variation in the respective variable. The
contribution of the matching shock to vacancy dynamics in the baseline
version now gets captured by technology, which explains 39 percent, but
the demand shock still explains 51 percent. Movements in wages are now
largely captured by the technology shock, while the demand shock remains
important with a contribution of 32 percent.
Table 5 Posterior Estimates: Robustness Checks
Specification Estimates
[eta] b [psi]
Benchmark 0.03 0.18 2.53
[0.00, 0.07] [0.12, 0.22] [1.92, 3.54]
Data: [V.sub.t], 0.02 0.39 1.67
[W.sub.t], [Y.sub.t]
[0.00, 0.04] [0.32, 0.46] [1.49, 1.88]
Data: [U.sub.t], 0.07 0.23 1.22
[V.sub.t], [W.sub.t]
[0.01, 0.18] [0.10, 0.34] [0.99, 1.65]
Data: [U.sub.t], 0.10 0.21 1.45
[V.sub.t]
[0.01, 0.25] [0.08, 0.40] [0.99, 2.01]
Specification Variance Decompositions
U V W
Benchmark 0.92 0.55 0.43
(Match.) (Demand) (Demand)
Data: [V.sub.t], -- 0.51 0.48
[W.sub.t], [Y.sub.t]
-- (Demand) (Tech.)
Data: [U.sub.t], 0.94 0.61 0.71
[V.sub.t], [W.sub.t]
(Match.) (Tech.) (Tech.)
Data: [U.sub.t], 0.95 0.89 --
[V.sub.t]
(Match.) (Tech.) --
I also experiment with removing the output series from the set of
observables. I then estimate the model for technology, matching, and
labor shocks. The removal of the demand shock has the most pronounced
effect on the variance decomposition as the previous contribution of
movements in the mark-up gets transferred to the technology process. It
now explains, respectively, 61 percent and 71 percent of the variations
in vacancies and wages. The removal of the output series has no marked
effect on the parameter estimates compared to the benchmark. Obviously,
including output helps pin down the technology process but is otherwise
not crucial for pinning down the structural parameters.
The third robustness check only uses data on unemployment and
vacancies, the exogenous shocks being technology and matching. The
predictions from the estimated model are fairly clear-cut. Unemployment
dynamics are driven by the matching shock, while vacancy dynamics are
driven by the technology shock. The parameter estimates are consistent
with the results from the previous specifications. However, the coverage
regions are noticeably wider and closer to the prior distributions,
which reflect the reduction in information when fewer data series are
used.
I can now summarize the findings from the robustness exercise as
follows. The parameter estimates of the search and matching model are
fairly consistent across specifications. In particular, the parameters
associated with the matching process, i.e., the match elasticity, [xi],
the match efficiency, [mu], and the separation rate, [rho], do not show
much variation and are close to the values reported in other empirical
studies. The other parameters exhibit more variation, in particular the
benefit parameter, b. Its estimated value is heavily influenced by both
the empirical specification of the model as well as the theoretical
structure, and should therefore be properly considered a reduced-form
coefficient rather than a structural parameter. Furthermore, the
different estimates of the vacancy cost elasticity, [psi], suggest that
a model with linear creation cost is misspecified.
Overall, the model matches the data and the second moments
reasonably well. Much of this success is, however, due to the incidence
of specific shocks. Unemployment dynamics, for instance, are captured
almost exclusively by movements in the match efficiency, which acts as a
residual in the equation defining how unemployment evolves. This calls
into question whether the restrictions imposed by the theoretical search
and matching model hold in the data and whether the model provides a
reasonable theory of labor market dynamics. The estimates also show that
shocks that are not typically considered in the calibration literature,
such as the matching or the demand shock, are important in capturing
model dynamics, while others, such as preference shocks, play only a
subordinate role.
5. CONCLUSION
I estimate a typical search and matching model of the labor market
on aggregate data using Bayesian methods. The structural estimation of
the full model allows me to assess the viability of the model as a
plausible description of labor market dynamics, taking into account all
moments of the data and not just selected covariates. The findings in
this article are broadly consistent with the literature and would
support continued use of the search and matching framework to analyze
aggregate labor market issues. However, the article also shows that the
relative success of this exercise relies on atypical shock processes
that may not have economic justification, such as variations in the
match efficiency. An alternative interpretation would be that the shock
proxies for a missing component in the employment. A prime candidate
would be endogenous variations in the separation rate. The article has
also attempted to make inroads into the issue of identification in
structural general equilibrium models, mainly by means of extensive
robustness checks with respect to alternative data and shocks. Research
into this issue is still in its infancy since simple measures of
identification in nonlinear models of this kind are not easy to come by.
REFERENCES
An, Sungbae, and Frank Schorfheide. 2007. "Bayesian Analysis of DSGE Models." Econometric Reviews 26: 113-72.
Christoffel, Kai Philipp, Keith Kuster, and Tobias Linzert. 2006.
"Identifying the Role of Labor Markets for Monetary Policy in an
Estimated DSGE Model." Discussion Paper Series 1: Economic Studies
2006, 17, Deutsche Bundesbank, Research Centre.
Gertler, Mark, Luca Sala, and Antonella Trigari. 2008. "An
Estimated Monetary DSGE Model with Unemployment and Staggered Nominal
Wage Bargaining." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 40
(December): 1,713-64.
Hagedorn, Marcus, and Iourii Manovskii. 2008. "The Cyclical
Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies Revisited."
American Economic Review 98 (September): 1,692-706.
Hall, Robert E. 1997. "Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the
Allocation of Time." Journal of Labor Economics 15 (January):
S223-50.
Hornstein, Andreas, Per Krusell, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2005.
"Unemployment and Vacancy Fluctuations in the Matching Model:
Inspecting the Mechanism." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 91 (Summer): 19-51.
Krause, Michael U., and Thomas A. Lubik. 2007. "The
(Ir)relevance of Real Wage Rigidity in the New Keynesian Model with
Search Frictions." Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (April):
706-27.
Krause, Michael U., David Lopez-Salido, and Thomas A. Lubik. 2008.
"Inflation Dynamics with Search Frictions: A Structural Econometric
Analysis." Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (July): 892-916.
Lubik, Thomas A., and Frank Schorfheide. 2005. "A Bayesian
Look at New Open Economy Macroeconomics." NBER Macroeconomics
Annual, 313-66.
Merz, Monika. 1995. "Search in the Labor Market and the Real
Business Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics 36 (November):
269-300.
Pissarides, Christopher. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Rotemberg, Julio J. 2008. "Cyclical Wages in a
Search-and-Bargaining Model with Large Firms." In NBER
International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2006. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 65-114.
Shimer, Robert. 2005. "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium
Unemployment and Vacancies." American Economic Review 95 (March):
25-49.
Sims, Christopher A. 2002. "Solving Linear Rational
Expectations Models." Computational Economics 20 (October): 1-20.
Trigari, Antonella. 2004. "Equilibrium Unemployment, Job
Flows, and Inflation Dynamics." European Central Bank Working Paper
304.
Trigari, Antonella. 2006. "The Role of Search Frictions and
Bargaining for Inflation Dynamics." Manuscript.
The author thanks Andreas Hornstein, Marianna Kudlyak, Devin
Reilly, Pierre Sarte, and Michael Krause for many helpful comments and
discussions. The views expressed in this article do not necessarily
represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal
Reserve System. E-mail: thomas.lubik@rich.frb.org.
(1) Other recent contributions are Trigari (2004); Christoffel,
Kuster, and Linzert (2006); Gertler, Sala, and Trigari (2008); and
Krause, Lopez-Salido, and Lubik (2008).
(2) Pissarides (2000) gives an excellent overview of the search and
matching framework.
(3) Trigari (2006) gives a concise description of the assumptions
required for this construct.
(4) Detailed derivations of the bargaining solutions and the
utility values can be found in Trigari (2006) and Krause and Lubik
(2007).
(5) I analyze the implications of changing the set of observables
in a series of robustness exercises, where I also address the tight link
between unemployment and vacancies.
(6) An alternative is to use shocks to the measurement equation in
the state-space representation of the model. While this is certainly a
valid procedure, these measurement errors lack clear economic
interpretation In particular, structural shocks are part of the
primitive of the theoretical model and agents respond to them.
Measurement errors, however, are only relevant for the econometrician and do not factor into the agents' decision problem.
(7) Estimating the model by allowing for variation in the fixed
parameters shows virtually no differences in the estimates. Using
marginal data densities as measures of goodness of fit, I find that the
preferred specification is for an unrestricted [alpha]. The differences
in posterior odds are tiny, however, and it is well known that they are
sensitive to minor specification changes.
(8) The MDD is the value of the posterior distribution with the
estimated parameters integrated out. It is akin to the value of the
maximized likelihood function in a frequentist framework.