A Quantitative study of the role of wealth inequality on asset prices.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos
There is an extensive body of work devoted to understanding the
determinants of asset prices. The cornerstone formula behind most of
these studies can be summarized in equation (1). The asset pricing
equation states in recursive formulation that the current price of an
asset equals the present discounted value of future payments delivered
by the asset. Namely,
p([S.sub.t]) = E[m([S.sub.t],[S.sub.[t + 1])(x([S.sub.[t +
1]])+p([S.sub.[t + 1]])) | [S.sub.t], (1)
where [RHO] (s) denotes the current price of an asset in state s; x
(s) denotes the payments delivered by the asset in state s; and m (s,
s') denotes the stochastic discount factor from state s today to
state s' tomorrow, that is, the function that is, the function that
determines the equivalence between current period dollars in state s and
next period dollars in state s'. It is apparent from equation (1)
that the stochastic discount factor m plays a key role in explaining
asset prices.
One strand of the literature estimates m using time series of asset
prices, as well as other financial and macroeconomic variables. The
estimation procedure is based on some arbitrary functional form linking
the discount factor to the explanatory variables. Even though this
strategy allows for a high degree of flexibility in order to find the
stochastic discount factor that best fits the data, it does not provide
a deep understanding of the forces that drive asset prices. In
particular, this approach cannot explain what determines the shape of
the estimated discount factor. This limitation becomes important once we
want to understand how structural changes, like a modification in the
tax code, may affect asset prices. The answer to this type of question
requires that the stochastic discount factor is derived from the
primitives of a model.
This is the strategy undertaken in the second strand of the
literature.(1) The extra discipline imposed by this line of research has
the additional benefit that it allows one to integrate the analysis of
asset prices into the framework used for modern macroeconomic
analysis.(2) On the other hand, the extra discipline imposes a cost: it
limits the empirical performance of the model. The most notable
discrepancy between the asset pricing model and the data was pointed out
by Mehra and Prescott (1985). They calibrate a stylized version of the
consumption-based asset pricing model to the U.S. economy and find that
it is incapable of replicating the differential returns of stocks and
bonds. The average yearly return on the Standard & Poor's 500
Index was 6.98 percent between 1889 and 1978, while the average return
on 90-day government Treasury bills was 0.80 percent. Mehra and
Prescott(1985) could explain an equity premium of, at most, 0.35
percent. The discrepancy, known as the equity premium puzzle, has
motivated an extensive literature trying to understand why agents demand
such a high premium for holding stocks.(3) The answer to this question
has important implications in other areas. For example, most
macroeconomic models conclude that the costs of business cycles are
relatively low (see Lucas 2003), which suggests that agents do not care
much about the risk of recessions. On the other hand, a high equity
premium implies the opposite, which suggests that a macro model that
delivers asset pricing behavior more aligned with the data may offer a
different answer about the costs of business cycles.
The present article is placed in the second strand of the
literature mentioned above. The objective here is to explore how robust
the implications of the standard consumption-based asset pricing model
are once we allow for preferences that do not aggregate individual
behavior into a representative agent setup.
Mehra and Prescott (1985) consider an environment with complete
markets and preferences that display a linear coefficient of absolute
risk tolerance (ART) or hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA).(4)
This justifies the use of a representative-agent model. Several authors
have explored how the presence of heterogenous agents could enrich the
asset pricing implications of the standard model and, therefore, help
explain the anomalies observed in the data. Constantinides and Duffle
(1996), Heaton and Lucas (1996), and Krusell and Smith (1997) are
prominent examples of this literature. These articles maintain the HARA
assumption, but abandon the complete markets setup. The lack of complete
markets introduces a role for the wealth distribution in the
determination of asset prices.
An alternative departure from the basic model that also introduces
a role for the wealth distribution is to abandon the assumption of a
linear ART. This is the avenue taken in Gollier (2001). He studies
explicitly the role that the curvature of the ART plays in a model with
wealth inequality. He shows in a two-period setup that when the ART is
concave, the equity premium in an unequal economy is larger than the
equity premium obtained in an egalitarian economy. The aim of the
present article is to quantify the analytical results provided in
Gollier's article. Preferences with habit formation constitute
another example of preferences with a nonlinear ART. Constantinides
(1990) and Campbell and Cochrane (1999) are prominent examples of asset
pricing models with habit formation. As in Gollier (2001), these
preferences also introduce a role for the wealth distribution, but this
channel is shut down in these articles by assuming homogeneous agents.
The present article considers a canonical Lucas tree model with
complete markets. There is a single risky asset in the economy, namely a
tree. This asset pays either high or low dividends. The probability
distribution governing the dividend process is commonly known. Agents
also trade a risk-free bond. Each agent receives in every period an
exogenous endowment of goods, which can be interpreted as labor income.
The endowment varies across agents. For simplicity, it is assumed that a
fraction of the population receives a higher endowment in every period,
that is, there is income inequality. Agents are also initially endowed with claims to the tree, which are unevenly distributed across agents.
The last two features imply that wealth is unequally distributed. Agents
share a utility function with a piecewise linear ART.
The exercise conducted in this article compares the equilibrium
asset prices in an economy that features an unequal distribution of
wealth with an egalitarian economy, that is, an economy that displays
the same aggregate resources as the unequal economy, but in which there
is no wealth heterogeneity. For a concave specification of the ART, this
article finds evidence suggesting that the role played by the
distribution of wealth on asset prices may be non-negligible. The
unequal economy displays an equity premium between 24 and 47 basis
points larger than the egalitarian economy. This is still far below the
premium of 489 basis points observed in the data.(5) The risk-free rate in the unequal economy is between 11 and 20 basis points lower than in
the egalitarian economy.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 1
discusses the assumption of a concave ART. Section 2 introduces the
model. Section 3 outlines how the model is calibrated. Section 4
presents the results, defining the equilibrium concept and describing
how the model is solved. Finally, Section 5 presents the conclusions.
1. PREFERENCES
It is assumed that agents' preferences with respect to random
payoffs satisfy the continuity and independence axioms and, therefore,
can be represented by a von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility
formulation. The utility function is denoted by u (c). The utility
function is increasing and concave in c. The concavity of u (c) implies
that agents dislike risk, that is, agents are willing to pay a premium
to eliminate consumption volatility. The two most common measures of the
degree of risk aversion are the coefficient of absolute risk aversion
and the coefficient of relative risk aversion. The coefficient of
absolute risk aversion measures the magnitude of the premium (up to a
constant of proportionality) that agents are willing to pay at a given
consumption level c, in order to avoid a "small" gamble with
zero mean and payoff levels unrelated to c. The coefficient of absolute
risk aversion (ARA) is computed as follows:
ARA (c) = - [u"(c)/u'(c)].
The coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA) also measures the
magnitude of the premium (up to a constant of proportionality) that
agents are willing to pay at a given consumption level c to avoid a
"small" gamble with zero mean, but with payoff levels that are
proportional to c. The coefficient of relative risk aversion is computed
as follows:
RRA(c) = - [cu"(c)/u'(c)].
The coefficient of ART is the inverse of the coefficient of ARA.
The utility function used in this article is reverse engineered to
display a piecewise linear ART, namely,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Where [[a.sub.1] - [a.sub.0]] = ([[b.sub.0]-[b.sub.1]]) [caret.c].
This equality implies that the ART is continuous. It is assumed that
both slope coefficients, [b.sub.0] and [b.sub.1], are strictly positive.
When [[b.sub.1] gt; [b.sub.0]] the ART is concave, and when [[b.sub.1]
< [b.sub.0]], the ART is convex. The standard constant RRA utility
function corresponds to the case where [[b.sub.1] = [b.sub.0]], and
[a.sub.1] = [a.sub.0] = 0].
The previous formulation implies that individual preferences can be
represented by the following utility function. (6)
Where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The present parameterization of the utility function has several
advantages. First, it nests the concave and convex ART cases in a simple
way. Second, it enables us to introduce a high degree of curvature of
the ART. Finally, it helps provide a transparent explanation of the
results.
On the Concavity of the Coefficient of Absolute Risk Tolerance
The results in Gollier (2001) suggest that wealth inequality may
help in reconciling the model with the equity premium observed in the
data as long as agents display a concave ART. This section discusses to
what extent this is a palatable assumption.
One possible way to verify the validity of a concave ART is to
contrast the testable implications of a concave (or convex) ART in terms
of individual savings and portfolio behavior with the data. This is the
avenue taken in Gollier (2001). He argues that the evidence is far from
conclusive. He documents that even though saving and investment patterns
do not seem to favor a concave ART, several studies are able to explain
this behavior without relying on a convex ART. More precisely, an
increasing and concave ART would imply that the fraction invested in
risky assets is increasing with wealth, but at a decreasing rate. This
is not observed in the data. However, once the complete information
setup is abandoned, one alternative explanation emerges: information
does not appear to be evenly distributed across market participants.
This is supported by Ivkovich, Sialm, and Weisbenner (forthcoming), who
find evidence suggesting that wealthier investors are more likely to
enjoy an informational advantage and earn higher returns on their
investments, which may feed into their appetite for stocks.
In a model without uncertainty, a concave ART would imply an
increasing marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. The data
contradict this result. But there are various alternative explanations
for the increasing propensity to save that do not rely on a convex ART.
The presence of liquidity constraints is one of them. The fact that the
investment set is not uniform across agents is another one. (7)
Another alternative to test the validity of a concave ART is to use
the results from experimental economics. However, Rabin and Thaler (2001) argue that not only is the coefficient of risk aversion an
elusive parameter to estimate, but also the entire expected utility
framework seems to be at odds with individual behavior. In part, this
has motivated the burst of behavioral biases models in the finance
literature.(8) The landscape is different in the macro literature. The
expected utility framework is still perceived as a useful tool for
understanding aggregate behavior.
The previous arguments suggest that the data do not provide strong
evidence in favor of or against a concave ART, which does not invalidate a concave specification of the ART as a possible representation of
individual preferences. The rest of the article focuses on this case in
order to measure the role of wealth inequality on asset pricing.
2. THE MODEL
This article analyzes a canonical Lucas tree model. The only
difference with Lucas (1978) is that our model features heterogeneous
agents. We consider a pure exchange economy with complete information.
There is a single risky asset in the economy: a tree. There is a unit
measure of shares of the tree. The tree pays either high dividends
([d.sub.h]) or low dividends ([d.sub.1]). The probability that the tree
pays high dividends tomorrow given that it has paid high dividends today
is denoted by [[pi].sub.h]]. (9) The probability that the tree pays high
dividends tomorrow given that it has paid low dividends today is denoted
by [[pi].sub.1]]. There is a measure one of agents in the economy.
Agents are initially endowed with shares of the tree and receive
exogenous income y in every period. A fraction [empty set] of the
population is endowed in every period with high income [y.sup.r].The
remaining agents receive low income [y.sup.p]. (10) The exogenous income
is not subject to uncertainty. This can be viewed as an extreme
representation of the fact that labor income is less volatile than
capital income. Agents trade in stocks and one-period risk-free bonds.
These two assets are enough to support a complete markets allocation.
The economy is inhabited by a measure 1 of infinitely lived agents.
Agents have preferences defined over a stream of consumption goods.
Preferences can be represented by a time-separable expected utility
formulation, namely,
[U.sub.0] = E[[[infinity].summation over (t =
0)][[beta].sup.t]u([c.sub.t])] = [[infinity].summation over (t =
0)][summation over ([z.sup.t][euro][Z.sup.t])][[beta].sup.t]Pr
([z.sup.t]|[z.sub.0])u([c.sub.t]([z.sup.t])),
where [Z.sup.t] denotes the set of possible dividend realizations
from period 0 up to period t, [Z.sup.t] denotes an element of such a
set, [c.sub.t] (.) denotes a consumption rule that determines the
consumption level in period t for a given stream of dividend
realizations, and Pr([z.sup.t | [z.sub.0])]] denotes the conditional
probability of observing stream of dividend realizations [Z.sup.t],
given that the initial realization is [z.sub.0]. Trivially,
[z.sub.0].[member of] {[d.sub.l][d.sub.h]}.
The consumer's objective is to maximize the present value of
future utility flows. Let us assume for the moment that the price of a
stock is given by the function p (s), and the price of a risk-free bond
is given by the function q (s), where S denotes the aggregate state. In
the present framework, the aggregate state is fully specified by the
dividend realization and the distribution of wealth. Given that the
price functions are time-invariant, the consumer's optimization
problem can be expressed using a recursive formulation.
The timing within each period is as follows: at the beginning of
the period the aggregate tree pays off and agents receive dividend
income. After that, they cash in the bonds and stocks purchased in the
previous period and receive the exogenous endowment (labor income). The
sum of these three components define the cash-on-hand wealth available
for investment and consumption. Agents trade in two markets: the market
of risk-free bonds and the market of claims to the tree. At the end of
the period, they consume the resources that were not invested in stocks
or bonds.
The following Bellman equation captures the individual optimization
problem of agent i:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to
p(s)a' + q(s)b' + c=[omega], [omega]'(s') =
a'[d(s') + p(s')] + b'+[y.sup.i], and c[greater than
or equal to]0
The agent's type, i, depends on the exogenous endowment the
agent receives. This means that i [member of] {r,p}. There are two
relevant state variables for any given individual: the cash-on-hand
wealth available at the beginning of the period (denoted by [omega]) and
the aggregate state of the economy. The aggregate state determines the
current prices and the probability distribution over future prices. The
state of the economy, S, is represented by the vector ([[omega].sup.r],
[[omega].sup.p], d]). The first two components characterize the
distribution of wealth, while the last component captures the current
dividend realization. The amount of stocks purchased in the current
period is denoted by a'. The amount of bonds purchased in the
current period is denoted by b'. The next-period state realization
is denoted by S'. The set of possible aggregate state realizations
in the following period is denoted by S'. The aggregate state
realization in the next period may depend on the current aggregate
state, S. The function d (S) represents the mapping from aggregate
states into dividend payoffs.
The first-order conditions of agent i are represented by equations
(3) and (4).
p(s) = [summation over (s')] (s' | s)[m.sub.i](s,
s')[d(s') + p(s')].(3)
q(s) = [summation over (s')] (s' | s)[m.sub.i](s,
s').(4)
These two equations illustrate how the asset pricing equation (1)
presented at the beginning of this article can be derived from a
consumer's optimization problem. The stochastic discount factor of
agent i is now a well-defined function of observables (wealth and
income), namely
[m.sub.i](s, s')=[[[beta]u'([c.sub.i](s'))]/[u'([c.sub.i](s))]]
where [c.sub.i] (S) denotes the optimal consumption of agent i in
state S. In equilibrium, equations (3) and (4) must be satisfied for all
agents, which means that any individual stochastic discount factor can
be used to characterize the equilibrium prices of stocks and bonds.
A recursive competitive equilibrium consists of a set of policy
functions [[g.sub.r.sup.a] ([omega], s), [g.sub.p.sup.b] ([omega], s),
price functions p(s), q(s), and an aggregate law of motion S' (S),
such that:
1. The policy functions [g.sub.i.sup.a] ([omega], s),
[g.sub.i.sup.b] ([omega], s) solve the consumer's problem (2) for i
= r, p.
2. Markets clear,
[phi][g.sub.r.sup.a]([[omega].sup.r],s) + (1 - [phi])
[g.sub.p.sup.a]([[omega].sup.p],s) = 1, and
[phi][g.sub.r.sup.b]([[omega].sup.r],s) + (1 -
[phi])[g.sub.p.sup.b]([[omega].sup.p],s) = 0
for all possible values of [[omega].sub.r] [[omega.sub.p] and s.
3. The aggregate law of motion is consistent with individual
behavior, that is, [for all]S' = ([[omega].sup.r'] (d'),
[[omega].sup.p'] (d'), d') [member of] S' (s) it is
the case that
[[omega].sup.r'](d')=[g.sub.r.sup.a]([[omega].sup.h],s)[p([[omega.sup.r'](d'),[[omega].sup.p'](d'),d')+d']+[g.sub.r.sup.b([[omega].sup.r],s)+[y.sup.r],
[[omega].sup.p'](d')=[g.sub.p.sup.a]([[omega].sup.p],s)[p([[omega.sup.r'](d'),[[omega].sup.p'](d'),d')+d']+[g.sub.p.sup.b([[omega].sup.p],s)+[y.sup.p],
The above implies that Pr (s' | s) = Pr (d (s') | s) [for
all] s' [member of] S' (s).
Notice that given that markets are complete, marginal rates of
substitution are equalized across agents, states, and periods. Given the
time separability of preferences, the equalization of marginal rates of
substitution implies that the sequence of consumption levels of rich
(poor) agents only depends on the aggregate dividend realization and not
on the time period. This means that the individual wealth of rich (poor)
agents only depends on the aggregate dividend realization and not on the
time period. This simplifies the dynamics of the model: the economy
fluctuates over time across two aggregate states characterized by
different dividend realizations and wealth distributions. The Appendix
provides a detailed description of how the model is solved.
Table 1 Parameter Values
[d.sub.h] [d.sub.l] [[pi].sub.h] [[pi].sub.l] [y.sup.r] [y.sup.p]
1.18 0.82 0.87 0.18 4.0 1.0
[d.sub.h] [PHI] [a.sub.initial period.sup.r]
1.18 0.33 1.5
[d.sub.h] [b.sub.0] [b.sub.1] [caret.c]
1.18 0.5 0.2 2.5
3. CALIBRATION
The baseline parameterization used in this article is described in
Table 1. The volatility of dividends is parameterized using the index of
real dividends paid by stocks listed in the Standard & Poor's
500 Index. (11) First, a linear trend is applied to the logarithm of the
series of dividends in order to remove the long-run trend of the series.
(12) Second, the exponential function is applied to the filtered series.
Figure 1 shows the logarithm of the index of real dividends and its
trend. Figure 2 shows the distribution of percentage deviations between
the index of real dividends and its trend value. The average deviation
over the sample period is 17.6 percent. However, this represents the
volatility of a highly diversified portfolio. Several studies document
that agents do not diversify as much as standard portfolio theories
predict. Thus, the dividend volatility of the stocks actually held by
individuals may very well be larger than this measure. The benchmark
values of [d.sub.h] and [d.sub.l] were chosen to deliver a coefficient
of variation of 17.3 percent but we also report results for higher
dividend volatility.
In order to estimate the transition probabilities [[pi].sub.l] and
[[pi].sub.h] the periods with dividends above the trend are denoted as
periods of high dividends, and the periods with dividends below the
trend are denoted as periods of low dividends. The values of
[[pi].sub.h] and [[pi].sub.l]--the probabilities of observing a period
with high dividends following a period with high (low) dividends--were
chosen to maximize the likelihood of the stream of high and low
dividends observed between 1871 and 2004. A value of [[pi].sub.l] = 0.18
and a value of [[pi].sub.h] = 0.87 are obtained.
Reproducing the degree of inequality is a more difficult job.
First, there have been sizable changes in the wealth distribution over
the last decades. Second, for the purpose of this article, the relevant
measure is the wealth inequality among stockholders, which is not
readily available. As an approximation, the present calibration focuses
only on households that had an income higher than $50,000 in 1989. Even
though this group does not represent the entire population, it
represents a large fraction of stockholders. (13) According to the
Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), 8.6 percent of American families
received an annual income higher than $100,000 in 1989, while the
fraction of families receiving an annual income between $50,000 and
$100,000 in the same year was 22.7 percent.
The first group represents the "rich" agents in the
model. The second group represents the "poor" agents in the
model. Thus, rich families represent 27 percent of all families with
income higher than $50,000 in 1989. A fraction [empty.set] equal to 33
percent is used in the article. The exogenous endowment (labor income)
received in each period by rich individuals is set equal to 4, while the
exogenous endowment of poor individuals is set equal to 1. The initial
endowment of stocks of rich individuals is set equal to 1.5, which
leaves the poor with an initial endowment of stocks of 0.75. Thus, on
average, rich agents receive three times as much income as poor
individuals. According to the SCF, the ratio of mean total income
between rich and poor was 3.4 in 1989. In addition, the previous
parameterization implies a ratio of aggregate "labor income"
to capital income (dividends) equal to 2. It is worth stressing that the
"poor" in this calibration are not strictly poor. They are
intended to represent the set of stockholders who are less affluent.
Thus, the previous parameterization yields a distribution of wealth that
is less unequal than the overall distribution of wealth.
Finally, the preference parameter [b.sub.0] is set equal to 0.5,
[a.sub.0] is set equal to 0, and [b.sub.1] is set equal to 0.2. This
implies that a representative agent would display an average coefficient
of relative risk aversion of 2.2, which is within the range of values
assumed in the literature. "The threshold value c is set equal to
2.5. This guarantees that the consumption of poor agents always lives in
the region with steep ART, and the consumption of rich agents always
lives in the region of relatively flat ART.
It should be stressed that the pricing kernel used in the present
article is not based on aggregate consumption data. In fact, the
consumption process of the two groups considered in the article displays
a higher volatility and higher correlation with stock returns than
aggregate consumption. The reason for this is twofold. First, there is
evidence against perfect risksharing among households. (14) This
suggests that using a pricing kernel based on aggregate consumption data
can be potentially misleading. Second, as was pointed out by Mankiw and
Zeldes (1991), stockholding is not evenly distributed across agents.
Guvenen (2006) and Vissing-Jorgensen (2002) provide further evidence
that the consumption processes of stockholders and non-stockholders are
different. Thus, the pricing kernel of stockholders appear as a more
appropriate choice to study asset prices than the pricing kernel implied
by the aggregate consumption.
4. RESULTS
The expected return of a tree in state i is denoted by
[R.sub.i.sup.e], where
[R.sub.i.sup.e] = [[pi].sub.i][([p.sub.h] + [d.sub.h])/[p.sub.i]] +
(1 - [[pi].sub.i])[([p.sub.l] + [d.sub.l])]/[p.sub.i]].
The return on a risk-free bond in state i is denoted by
[R.sub.i.sup.f], where
[R.sub.i.sup.f] = [1/[q.sub.i]].
The asset pricing moments are computed using the stationary
distribution. In the long run, the probability that the economy is in a
state with high dividends is denoted by [pi], where
[pi] = [[pi].sub.l]/[1 + [[pi].sub.l] - [[pi].sub.h]].
The average long-run return on a stock is denoted by [R.sup.e]. The
average long-run return on a bond is denoted by [R.sup.f]. They are
computed as follows:
[R.sup.e] = [pi][R.sub.h.sup.e] + (1 - [pi])[R.sub.l.sup.e], and
[R.sup.f] = [pi][R.sub.h.sup.f] + (1 - [pi])[R.sub.l.sup.f].
Table 2 Average Returns and Volatility
Variable Egalitarian Unequal
Economy Economy Data (15)
Mean Returns on Equity 4.77 4.91 7.86
Mean Risk-Free Rate 3.78 3.67 2.83
Equity Premium 0.96 1.20 4.89
Std. Dev. of Equity Returns 11.43 12.75 14.3
Std. Dev. of Risk-Free Rate 4.23 4.76 5.8
Table 2 compares the first two moments of the equilibrium long-run
riskfree rate and stock returns in two hypothetical economies. The
unequal economy refers to the economy described in Section 2. In the
egalitarian economy, however, every agent is initially endowed with the
same amount of stocks and receives the same exogenous endowment in every
period. The aggregate resources are the same as in the unequal economy.
Table 2 reports that the role of wealth inequality on asset prices
is small but non-negligible. (16) The risk-free interest rate in the
unequal economy is 11 basis points lower than the risk-free rate in the
egalitarian economy. The premium for holding stocks is 24 basis points
larger in the unequal economy. As the distribution of wealth becomes
more unequal, the gap in the equity premium increases. For example, when
each rich agent is initially endowed with 2 stocks, instead of 1.5, the
premium for holding stocks is 34 basis points higher in the unequal
economy compared to the egalitarian ecomomy. (17)
The present model generates a higher equity premium than Mehra and
Prescott (1985) for two reasons. First, agents bear more risk by holding
stocks. The present article features a risky asset that is riskier than
the risky asset in Mehra and Prescott (1985). In their model, agents
only receive a risky endowment that is calibrated to mimic the behavior
of real per capita consumption between 1889 and 1978. In the present
setup, the risky endowment mimics the behavior of the dividend process
of the stocks contained in the S&P 500 Index, which is more volatile
than aggregate consumption. The second reason why the present article
delivers a higher equity premium is because stocks provide poor
diversification services and, therefore, agents demand a higher premium
per unit of risk. This is reflected in a higher Sharpe ratio. The Sharpe
ratio--described in equation (5)--measures the excess returns per unit
of risk that agents demand for holding stocks. Equation (5) can be
obtained from equation (1) after using the property that
[R.sub.i.sup.f] = [1/[E(m | [d.sub.i])]]
Sharpespaceratio = [E([R.sup.e] \ [d.sub.i]) -
[R.sub.i.sup.f]]/[[sigma]([R.sup.e]\[d.sub.i])]] = - Corr(m,
[R.sup.e]/[d.sub.i])[[[sigma](m\[d.sub.i])]/[E(m\[d.sub.i])]]. (5)
Table 3 Sharpe Ratio and Moments of the Stochastic Discount Factor
in the Egalitarian Economy
Aggregate State Sharpe Ratio Corr(m, [R.sup.e] \ d[sub.i])
[d.sub.h] 0.0990 -1
[d.sub.l] 0.0940 -1
Aggregate State E (m \ [d.sub.i]) [SIGMA](m \ [d.sub.i])
[d.sub.h] 0.099 0.998
[d.sub.l] 0.087 0.919
Table 3 illustrates the magnitudes of the moments present in
equation (5) for the case of the egalitarian economy. The model
generates a Sharpe ratio slightly lower than 0.10. This value can be
explained by the high negative correlation between the stochastic
discount factor and the returns on stocks, and by the relatively high
standard deviation of the stochastic discount factor. The perfect
negative correlation between the stochastic discount factor and the
returns on stocks is due to the assumption of a binary process for
dividends. (18)
As far as the standard deviation of the stochastic discount factor
is concerned, it can be approximated by
[sigma](m) [approximately equal to] [gamma][sigma] ([DELTA]Inc),
Table 4 Average Returns and Volatility for the Baseline
Parameterization and for a Parameterization with Higher
Dispersion of Dividends
[d.sub.h] = 1.18 and [d.sub.i] = 0.82
Egalitarian Unequal
Mean Returns on Equity 4.77 4.91
Mean Risk-Free Rate 3.78 3.67
Equity Premium 0.96 1.20
Std. Dev. of Equity Returns 11.43 12.75
Std. Dev. of Risk-Free Rate 4.23 4.76
[d.sub.h] = 1.25 and [d.sub.i] = 0.75
Egalitarian Unequal
Mean Returns on Equity 5.34 5.62
Mean Risk-Free Rate 3.41 3.21
Equity Premium 1.87 2.34
Std. Dev. of Equity Returns 16.20 18.16
Std. Dev. of Risk-Free Rate 5.87 6.62
where [gamma] stands for the coefficient of relative risk aversion
and [sigma] ([delta]Inc) represents the standard deviation of the growth
rate in consumption (see footnote 18). In the model, the coefficient of
relative risk aversion of the representative agent is above 2.2, while
the volatility of the growth rate in consumption is slightly below 0.05.
This value is higher than the standard deviation of the growth rate of
aggregate consumption (below 2 percent in the postwar years), but it
does not differ significantly from the estimates of the standard
deviation of consumption growth of stockholders. Mankiw and Zeldes
(1991) estimate a standard deviation of consumption growth of U.S.
stockholders slightly above 3 percent over the period 1970-1984. (19)
Table 4 shows that as the dispersion of dividends increases to 24
percent, the equity premia in the unequal economy is 47 basis points
larger in the unequal economy compared to the egalitarian case. A
dispersion of dividends of 24 percent is not such a large figure once we
internalize the fact that investors do not diversify as much as standard
portfolio theories predict. (20)
Interpretation of the Results
Gollier (2001) shows that in an economy with wealth inequality, the
ART of the hypothetical representative agent consists of the mean ART of
the market participants. Thus, when the ART is concave, Jensen's
inequality implies that the ART of a hypothetical representative agent
in an economy with wealth inequality is below the ART of the
representative agent in an economy with an egalitarian distribution of
wealth. In turn, Gollier shows that this implies that the equity premium
in an economy with an unequal distribution of wealth is higher than the
equity premium in an economy with an egalitarian distribution of wealth.
This result holds regardless of whether the ART is increasing or
decreasing with consumption. The baseline parameterization used in this
article considers the first case, which appears to be in line with the
data. It implies that in equilibrium, wealthier agents bear more
aggregate risk.
Even though Gollier (2001) relies on a two-period model, the
results in this section suggest that his results also hold in an
infinite-horizon setup. An intuitive explanation is provided in Figure
3. The graph describes how the consumption of rich and poor agents is
affected by the nonlinearity of the ART. The solid line describes the
ART. If the ART was linear and represented by the dashed line AB, the
economy would behave as if there was a representative agent. In this
case, the consumption levels of rich and poor agents in state i would
correspond to points like [c.sub.i.sup.r] and [c.sub.i.sup.p],
respectively. [C.sub.i] denotes the average per capita consumption in
state i. In equilibrium, the marginal rates of substitution are
equalized across agents:
[[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r])]/[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r])]] =
[[u'([C.sub.l])]/[u'([C.sub.h])]] =
[[u'([c.sub.l.sup.p])]/[u'([c.sub.h.sup.p])]].
Poor agents are more risk-averse when the ART is represented by the
solid curve OB, instead of AB. This means that at the prices prevailing
when the economy behaves as if there was a representative agent, poor
individuals are willing to consume less than [c.sub.h.sup.p] in the high
divident state and more than [C.sub.p.sup.l] in the low divident state.
Thus, the "new" equilibrium consumption levels of rich and
poor agents must move in the direction of the arrows. Notice that the
marginal rate of substitution for rich agents ([u.sup.t]
([C.sub.r.sup.l]) / [u.sub.t] ([C.sub.r.sup.h])) is higher in the
economy with concave ART, compared to the economy with linear ART (curve
OB versus curve AB).
From the perspective of a rich individual, the mean price of stocks
must therefore decrease. The reason is that the tree is paying low
returns in states that have now become more valuable (low consumption)
and high returns in states that have become less valuable (high
consumption). Since markets are complete and the marginal rate of
substitution are equalized across agents, poor agents agree with their
rich counterparts. As a consequence, the average equity premium asked to
hold stocks is larger than in the economy with a representative agent.
(21)
The Role of the Concavity of the Coefficient of Risk Tolerance
In order to illustrate the role played by the curvature of the ART,
this section illustrates how the equity premium changes with alternative
parameterizations of the ART. The comparative statics exercise is
reduced to alternative parameterizations of [b.sub.0]. In order to make
the results comparable with the ones presented before, this section
considers alternative values of [b.sub.0] but restricts the remaining
parameters in the utility function change in such a way that, on
average, the ART remains constant in the economy with wealth inequality.
This is best illustrated in Figure 4. The graph displays two
parameterizations of the ART: the solid line OB represents the baseline
case with a concave ART. The dashed line AD represents a case with a
convex ART. The line AD features a lower slope (lower [b.sub.0]) on the
first segment of the piecewise linear formulation. The remaining
coefficients of the line AD are chosen to satisfy the following
conditions: average ART is the same for poor and rich agents, and the
change in the slope of the ART occurs at [^.c]. (22)
Figure 5 shows that when the ART is convex, the equity premium is
larger in an economy with an egalitarian distribution of wealth compared
to the economy with wealth inequality. Conversely, when the ART is
concave, the equity premium is lower in the economy with an egalitarian
distribution of wealth. These findings are in line with the results of
Gollier (2001).
An alternative interpretation of Figure 5 is that if the data are
actually generated by the economy with wealth inequality, using a
representative agent model would generate biased predictions. A
representative agent model--that implicitly assumes that every agent is
endowed with the same wealth level--would overestimate the equity
premium in the case with convex ART and underestimate the equity premium
in the case with concave ART.
5. CONCLUSIONS
The objective of this article is to quantify how robust the asset
pricing implications of the standard model are once alternative
preference specifications are considered. The exercise is motivated on
the grounds that there is no strong evidence in favor of the constant
ARA or constant RRA utility representations usually used in the finance
and macroeconomic literature. Following Gollier (2001), the article
focuses on a case with a concave ART. In the economy analyzed in this
article, the heterogeneity of individual behavior is not washed out in
the aggregate. This introduces a role for the wealth distribution in the
determination of asset prices. The model is parameterized based on the
historic performance of U.S. stocks and approaches the salient features
of the wealth and income inequality among stockholders. For the baseline
parameterization, the equity premium is 0.24 percent larger in the
unequal economy compared to the economy in which the wealth inequality
is eliminated. The premium increases if we allow for the fact that
agents typically hold portfolios that are more concentrated than the
market portfolio. For example, if the stocks display standard deviation
of dividends of 25 percent, the increase in the equity premium in the
unequal economy increases to slightly less than half a percentage point.
This suggests that the role played by the distribution of wealth on
asset prices may be non-negligible.
APPENDIX A: DERIVATION OF THE UTILITY FUNCTION
Start from a linear formulation of the ART,
- [[u'(c)]/[u"(c)]] = a + bc (A.1)
The above inequality implies that the primitive functions of any
transformation of both sides of equation (A. 1) must be equalized. In
particular,
[integral] [[u"(c)]/[u'(c)]]dc = [integral] - [1/[a +
bc]]dc (A.2)
Thus,
ln[u'(c)] = - [1/b]lnSpace(a + bc) + [C.sub.0] (A.3)
where [C.sub.0] is a real scalar.
Equation (A.4) is obtained after applying the exponential function
to both sides of equation (A.3),
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A.4)
Finally, equation (A.5) is obtained after integrating both sides of
equation (A.4),
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A.5)
where [~.C.sub.1] is another real scalar. Equation (A.5) implies
that the piecewise linear formulation of the ART considered in this
article generates four constants that need to be determined: two
constants [~.C.sub.0] and [~.C.sub.1] for each of the two combinations
of coefficients ([a.sub.i], [b.sub.i]). In order to pin down the values
of these constants, four restrictions are imposed. In the first section
of values of the ART--characterized by the parameters [a.sub.0] and
[b.sub.0]--the constants [~.C.sub.0] and [~.C.sub.1] are chosen so that
u (c) and u' (c) are continuous. In the second section of values of
the ART--characterized by the parameters [a.sub.1] and [b.sub.1]--the
constants [~.C.sub.0] and [~.C.sub.1] are normalized to take values of 1
and 0, respectively.This normalization does not affect any of the
results, given that an expected utility function is unique only up to an
affine transformation (see proposition 6.B.2 in MasColell, Whinston, and
Green [1995]).
APPENDIX B: SOLVING FOR THE EQUILIBRIUM
The present model features complete markets. A well-known result in
this setup is that, in equilibrium, marginal rates of substitution
across states and periods are equalized across agents. This implies that
[[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r])]/[u'([c.sub.h.sup.p])]] =
[[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r])]/[u'([c.sub.l.sup.p])]] = [[1 -
[lambda]]/[lambda]],with[lambda][euro](0,1),(B.1)
where [c.sub.i.sup.j]denotes the consumption of agent j in a state
where the tree pays dividends [d.sub.i]. The value of [lamda] is
determined in equilibrium.
The two equalities in equation (B.1), jointly with the aggregate
resource constraints
[phi]([c.sub.r.sup.h]) + (1 - [phi])[c.sub.p.sup.h] = [d.sub.h] +
[phi][y.sup.r] + (1 - [phi])[y.sup.p],and
[phi][c.sub.r.sup.l] + (1 - [phi])[c.sub.p.sup.l] = [d.sub.i] +
[phi][y.sup.r] + (1 - [phi])[y.sup.p],
fully determine the allocation of consumption as a function of
consumption as a function of [lamda]. In turn, the consumption levels
[c.sub.i.sup.j] ([lamda]) can be used to retrieve the market prices
implied by [lamda]. Market prices must satisfy equations (B.2)-(B.5),
which are derived from the first-order conditions of a rich individual.
(23)
[p.sub.h]([lambda]) = [beta][[[pi].sub.h]([d.sub.h] +
[p.sub.h]([lambda])) + (1 -
[[pi].sub.h])[[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r]([lambda]))]/[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r]([lambda]))]]([p.sub.l]([lambda]) + [d.sub.l])], (B.2)
[p.sub.l]([lambda]) =
[beta][[[pi].sub.l][[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r]([lambda]))]/[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r]([lambda]))]]([d.sub.h] + [p.sub.h]([lambda])) + (1 -
[[pi].sub.l])([p.sub.l]([lambda]) + [d.sub.l])],(B.3)
[q.sub.h]([lambda]) = [beta][[[pi].sub.h] + (1 -
[[pi].sub.h])[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r]([lambda]))]/[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r]([lambda]))]], and (B.4)
[q.sub.l]([lambda]) =
[beta][[[pi].sub.l][[u'([c.sub.h.sup.r]([lambda]))]/[u'([c.sub.l.sup.r]([lambda]))]] + 1 - [[pi].sub.l]], (B.5)
where [[rho].sub.i] ([lamda]) denotes the price of a share of the
tree in a period when the tree has paid dividends [d.sub.i], and
[q.sub.i] ([lamda]) denotes the price of the risk-free bond in a period
when the tree has paid dividends [d.sub.i].
Notice that only the aggregate resource constraint has been used
until this point. In order to pin down values of [lamda] consistent with
the equilibrium allocation, an additional market-clearing condition must
be considered. We use the market-clearing condition for stocks. An
initial condition is also required. For this reason, it is assumed that
the tree pays high dividends in the first period. The results are not
sensitive to this. Equations (B.6) and (B.7) define the two initial
conditions that the demand for bonds and stocks of agent
j([a'.sub.h.sup.j]([lamda]) and [b'.sub.h.sup.j] ([lamda]))
must meet,
[[omega].sub.h.sup.j] -
[p.sub.h]([lambda])[a'.sub.h.sup.j]([lambda]) -
[q.sub.h]([lambda])[b'.sub.h.sup.j]([lambda]) =
[c.sub.h.sup.j]([lambda]),and (B.6)
[y.sup.j] + [a'.sub.h.sup.j]([lambda])([p.sub.h]([lambda]) +
[d.sub.h]) + b['.sub.h.sup.j]([lambda]) = [[omega].sub.h.sup.j],
(B.7)
for j = r, p, and initial wealth leverls [[omega].sub.h.sup.r], and
[[omega].sub.h.sup.p]. Equation (B.6) states that the investment
decisions of an agent of type j must leave [c.sub.h.sup.j] ([lamda])
available for consumption in the first period. The second equation
states that the cash-on-hand wealth available at the beginning of the
second period in a state in which the tree pays high dividends must
equal the initial wealth (recall that the tree pays high dividends in
the first period). The logic behind the second condition is the
following. Given the stationarity of the consumption and price
processes, the discounted value of future consumption flows in the first
period is identical to the discounted value of future consumption flows
in any period in which the tree pays high dividends. This means that the
discounted value of claims to future income must also be equalized
across periods with high dividend realizations, which implies that
equation (B.7) must hold.
Thus, the value of [lamda] consistent with the equilibrium
allocation must satisfy
[phi][a'.sub.h.sup.r]([lambda]) + (1 -
[phi])[a'.sub.h.sup.p]([lambda]) = 1.
Finally, the following equation must also hold:
[y.sup.j] + [a'.sub.l.sup.j]([lambda])[[p.sub.h]([lambda]) +
[d.sub.h]] + [b'.sub.l.sup.j]([lambda]) = [[omega].sub.h.sup.j],
(B.8)
for j = r, p. The above equality states that if the tree has paid
low dividends in the current period, the cash-on-hand wealth available
at the beginning of the following period in a state where the tree pays
high dividends must be equal to the initial wealth of the agent.
Equations (B.7) and (B.8) imply that, in equilibrium, the individual
portfolio decisions are independent of the current dividend realization,
that is,
[a'.sub.h.sup.j] = [a'.sub.l.sup.j] and
[b'.sub.h.sup.j] = [b'.sub.l.sup.j] = r, p.
REFERENCES
Attanasio, Orazio, and Stephen J. Davis. 1996. "Relative Wage
Movements and the Distribution of Consumption." Journal of
Political Economy 104 (6): 1,227-62.
Attanasio, Orazio P., James Banks, and Sarah Tanner. 2002.
"Asset Holding and Consumption Volatility." Journal of
Political Economy 110 (4): 771-92.
Barberis, Nicholas C, and Richard Thaler. 2003. "A Survey of
Behavioral Finance." In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, ed.
G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R.M. Stulz, chap. 18. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane. 1999. "By Force of
Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market
Behavior." Journal of Political Economy 107 (2): 205-51.
Cochrane, John H. 1991. "A Simple Test of Consumption
Insurance." Journal of Political Economy 99 (5): 957-76.
Constantinides, George M. 1990. "Habit Formation: A Resolution
of the Equity Premium Puzzle." Journal of Political Economy 98 (3):
519-43.
Constantinides, George M., and Darrell Duffie. 1996. "Asset
Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers." Journal of Political Economy
104 (2): 219-40.
Gollier, Christian. 2001. "Wealth Inequality and Asset
Pricing." Review of Economic Studies 68 (1): 181-203.
Guvenen, Faith. 2006. "Reconciling Conflicting Evidence on the
Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution: A Macroeconomic
Perspective." Journal of Monetary Economics 53(7): 1,451-72.
Guvenen, Faith. 2007. "Do Stockholders Share Risk More Effectively
than Non-Stockholders?" Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (2):
275-88.
Hayashi, Fumio, Joseph Altonji, and Laurence Kotlikoff. 1996.
"Risk-Sharing Between and Within Families." Econometrica 64
(2): 261-94.
Heaton, John, and Deborah J. Lucas. 1996. "Evaluating the
Effects of Incomplete Markets on Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing."
Journal of Political Economy 104 (3): 443-87.
Ivkovich, Zoran, Clemens Sialm, and Scott Weisbenner. Forthcoming.
"Porfolio Cencentration and the Performance of Individual
Investors." Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.
Jermann, Urban J. 1998. "Asset Pricing in Production
Economies." Journal of Monetary Economics 41 (2): 257-75.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 1997. "Income and
Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice, and Equilibrium Asset
Returns." Macroeconomic Dynamics 1 (2): 387-422.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1978. "Asset Prices in an Exchange
Economy." Econometrica 46 (6): 1,429-46.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 2003. "Macroeconomic Priorities."
American Economic Review 93 (1): 1-14.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Stephen P. Zeldes. 1991. "The
Consumption of Stockholders and Nonstockholders." Journal of
Financial Economics 29 (1): 97-112.
Mas-Colell, Andreu, Michael D. Whinston, and Jerry R. Green. 1995.
Microeconomic Theory. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
McGrattan, Ellen R., and Edward C. Prescott. 2003. "Average
Debt and Equity Returns: Puzzling?" American Economic Review 93
(2): 392-97.
Mehra, Rajnish, and Edward C. Prescott. 1985. "The Equity
Premium: A Puzzle." Journal of Monetary Economics 15(2): 145-61.
Quadrini, Vincenzo. 2000. "Entrepreneurship, Saving and Social
Mobility." Review of Economic Dynamics 3 (1): 1-40.
Rabin, Matthew, and Richard H. Thaler. 2001. "Anomalies: Risk
Aversion." Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (1): 219-32.
Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette. 2002. "Limited Asset Market
Participation and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution."
Journal of Political Economy 110 (4): 825-53.
(1) Lucas (1978) represents the basic reference of the
consumption-based asset pricing model. He studies an endowment economy
with homogeneous agents and shows how the prices of assets are linked to
agents' consumption.
(2) See Jermann (1998) for an example of a study of asset prices in
a real business cycle model.
(3) McGrattan and Prescott (2003) argue that the actual equity
premium is lower than 6 percent after allowing for diversification
costs, taxes, and the liquidity premium of the short-term government
bonds.
(4) The coefficient of absolute risk tolerance is defined as
-[u.sup.'] (c)/[u.sup."] (c)
(5) This number is 129 basis points smaller than the premium
documented in Mehra and Prescott (1985). There are two reasons for this.
First, the sample period used in the present article is 1871 to 2004,
while Mehra and Prescott (1985) use data from 1889 to 1978. Second, the
present article uses one-year Treasury bills as a proxy for the
risk-free rate, while Mehra and Prescott (1985) use 90-day Treasury
bills.
(6) See Appendix A for a description of how the utility function is
recovered from the ART.
(7) See Quadrini (2000).
(8) See Barberis and Thaler (2003).
(9) It is assumed that the tree pays high dividends in the first
period.
(10) In order to assist the reader, the subscript r stands for
"rich," while the subscript p stands for "poor."
(11) The dividend index can be found in http://www.econ.yale.edu/
shiller/data/ie_data.htm. All nominal variables are deflated using the
overall Consumer Price Index.
(12) This procedure delivers a smoother trend than what could be
found using a Hodrick-Prescott filter with a value of [lamda] equal to
100, which is the value commonly used to detrend annual variables.
However, in the present case, a smoothing parameter of 100 implies that
a high fraction of the volatility of the detrended series of dividends
would be absorbed by movements in the trend, which may underestimate the
actual risk perceived by individual investors.
(13) The fact that the characteristics of stockholders may differ
from the characteristics of the rest of the population was first pointed
out in Mankiw and Zeldes (1991).
(14) See Cochrane (1991); Attanasio and Davis (1996); Hayashi,
Altonji, and Kotlikoff (1996); and Guvenen (2007).
(15) The equity returns correspond to the real returns of the
stocks listed in the Standard & Poor's 500 Index. The risk-free
interest rate corresponds to one-year Treasury bills. The sample period
is 1871-2004.
(16) The actual data reported in Table 2 differ from Mehra and
Prescott (1985). See footnote 5
(17) In this case, the ratio of financial wealth between rich and
poor agents is equal to 4. The ratio equals 2 in our benchmark
parameterization.
(18) One way to contrast this correlation with the data is to look
at the correlation between consumption growth and stock returns. The
motivation for this is that when agents display a utility function with
a constant coefficient of relative risk aversion, the discount factor
has the following form:
m(s, s') = [beta] [([(c(s')]/[c(s)]).sup.[-gamma]]
where [gamma] denotes the coefficient of relative risk aversion.
Thus, the stochastic discount factor is inversely proportional to
consumption growth. In the present article, the utility function does
not display a constant coefficient of relative risk aversion, but there
is still a close relationship between consumption growth and the
discount factor. In fact, in the present model, the counterpart of a
perfect negative correlation between the discount factor and stock
returns is a perfect correlation between consumption growth and stock
returns or excess returns ([R.sup.e] - [R.sup.f]). Mankiw and Zeldes
(1991) find that the correlation between consumption growth and excess
returns ranges from 0.26 to 0.4 using aggregate data, and it can be as
high as 0.49 when the data refer to the consumption of shareholders.
(19) Attanasio, Banks, and Tanner (2002) find a standard deviation
of consumption growth of stockholders ranging from 3.7 to 6.5 percent in
the case of the UK.
(20) See Ivkovich, Sialm, and Weisbenner (forthcoming).
(21) Note that the ranking of consumption in Figure 3 respects the
ranking of consumption given by the baseline parameterization. In
particular, the average consumption level is always above the threshold
value [^.c].
(22) Note that the equilibrium allocation of consumption of poor
and rich agents in good and bad states does not depend on the shape of
the utility function. This is because of the complete markets
assumption.
(23) Given that marginal rates of substitution are equalized across
agents, the same prices are obtained using the first-order condition of
poor individuals.
I would like to thank Ilya Faibushevich, Borys Grochulski, Andreas
Homstein, Leonardo Martinez, and Roy Webb for helpful comments. The
views expressed in this article do not necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
JuanCarlos.Halchondo@rich.frb.org.