On the evolution of income inequality in the United States.
Bryan, Kevin A. ; Martinez, Leonardo
The recent rise in income inequality in the United States has
received considerable attention in policy debates. (1) This article
discusses individual income inequality trends. In doing so, we summarize results presented in existing work. As in previous studies, the article
shows that income inequality has increased since the 1960s--see, for
example, Diaz-Gimenez et al. (2002), Eckstein and Nagypal (2004),
Weinberg and Steelman (2005), and Katz, Autor, and Kearney (2007).
Furthermore, our article documents periods characterized by a decline in
real income for lower income groups.
Figure 1 shows that between 1975 and 2002, only labor income in the
top 10 percent of the income distribution (Current Population Survey
March Supplement) increased more than the per-worker (total nonfarm
employment, Bureau of Economic Analysis) wage and salary income
(National Income and Product Account). (2) In particular, while during
this period per-worker labor income increased 32 percent, labor income
in the 10th percentile of the income distribution increased only 5
percent. In addition, Figure 1 shows that between 1975 and 1997, labor
income in the 10th percentile decreased 7 percent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
We begin by discussing inequality trends for the whole population,
and then we document how these trends vary across different subsets of
the population. In doing so, we present findings that are consistent
with those in previous studies and are robust to different data sets and
inequality measures.
First, we show that the evolution of income inequality displays
different patterns for the top and the bottom halves of the income
distributions. In the bottom half of the distribution, income inequality
rose in the 1980s but was stable after that. Income inequality in the
top half of the distribution has risen continuously in recent decades.
Second, we show that trends in male and female income inequality
are similar over the past few decades. However, the level of inequality
is lower among females than among males. We also show that at the same
time inequality among both males and females has been increasing,
inequality between the two groups has been decreasing. This decrease in
the gender gap implies that overall inequality has been lowered because
female incomes caught up with male incomes.
Third, we show that income differentials have increased both
between and within levels of education. We also show that the increase
in between education-group inequality has been greater for males than
for females.
Our analysis focuses on labor income inequality trends, but brief
discussions of wage inequality, welfare inequality, and wealth
inequality are also presented. In particular, we discuss why the recent
increase in income inequality may not be reflected in an increase in
welfare inequality.
Finally, we discuss the pre-1960s period. Although data from before
1960 is fairly limited, studies of wage tables, state censuses, tax
returns, and industrial surveys are available. We summarize the findings
of these studies, which conclude that U.S. income inequality displayed
an inverted U-curve pattern. In the 19th century, income inequality
rose, but during the interwar period and especially during World War II,
there was a marked decrease in inequality, with narrowing overall income
differences, as well as shrinking income gaps between males and females,
among different races, among blue-and white collar workers, and among
workers with different levels of education (see, for example, Goldin and
Katz 1999a).
The rest of this article is organized as follows. Section I
describes the data sources we use. Section 2 discusses measures of
inequality. Section 3 shows that in recent decades income inequality
increased and that this increase in inequality is explained mainly by an
increase in inequality among individuals with higher incomes. Section 4
discusses income inequality trends and gender. Section 5 focuses on
inequality trends and education. Section 6 comments on wage inequality,
welfare inequality, and wealth inequality. Section 7 discusses
inequality trends before the 1960s. Section 8 concludes.
1. DATA SOURCES
We use four data sources: the Current Population Survey (CPS) March
Supplement, the CPS Outgoing Rotation Group (ORG) supplement, Piketty
and Saez's (2003) Internal Revenue Service (IRS) top-income data
set, and Kopczuk, Saez, and Song's (2007) Social Security data. The
Personal Consumption Expenditures price index is used to deflate income
figures--deflating with the CPI-U price index does not materially change
our results.
The CPS is a monthly survey of households conducted by the Bureau
of the Census. Survey questions are always related to employment, but
some months also feature supplemental questions. In particular, the CPS
March Supplement (available since 1962, recording income from 1961) asks
detailed questions about annual labor income, while the CPS ORG
(available since 1979, recording 1978 data) asks about hourly wage and
hours worked. Though the CPS collects information on interest payments,
social security receipts, and other nonwage income, this data is
generally considered less reliable than wage data and as such is often
not analyzed in studies of income inequality (see Luxembourg Income
Study 2007). The two CPS supplements are commonly used because of their
large sample size (between 60,000 and 190,000 observations) and the
length of the sample period.
As is standard when inequality measures are constructed using CPS
data, we examine only income from the 10th percentile to the 90th
percentile. This is because income data tends to be unreliable at the
very bottom of the income distribution, and because CPS data sets are
topcoded. That is, incomes above a certain level are capped for privacy
reasons. For instance, if an individual earns $200,000 in a year where
the cap is $99,999, the CPS would list that individual's income as
$99,999. This implies that the CPS offers little guidance for examining
the top of the income distribution. This may be a significant problem
when analyzing income inequality trends because, as we will show later,
over the past decades income inequality has risen very rapidly among the
top percentiles of the income distribution and, therefore, using
topcoded data biases the measured growth in inequality downward.
For CPS March Supplement data, we use a merged 1962-2003 file
compiled by Zvi Eckstein and Eva Nagypal. (3) Our analysis of the CPS
ORG data is based on the 2007 National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER) Labor Extracts CD-ROM. Our CPS ORG annual labor income figures
are computed by multiplying the NBER ORG Labor Extracts weekly earnings
figures by 52. In both CPS files, we keep only full-time, full-year
workers, where full-year work is defined as 40+ weeks per year.
Volunteers, the self-employed, workers younger than 22 years of age, and
workers older than 65 years of age are removed from the sample. As in
earlier literature, we multiply topcoded incomes by 1.4. This has little
effect since we do not examine top incomes using these data sets, though
the topcode is binding for 90th percentile incomes for male college
graduates in the mid-1980s. Following Katz, Autor, and Kearney (2007),
we drop workers with a stated annualized real wage of less than $1/hr.
We drop entries with allocated earnings--meaning that missing data has
been imputed--from the CPS ORG. Education dummies are constructed so
that 0-11 years of school is "High School Dropout," 12 years
is "High School Graduate," 13-15 years is "Some
College," 16-17 years is "College Graduate," and 18 +
years is "Postgraduate."
Kopczuk, Saez, and Song's (2007) Social Security Earnings Data
allows us to study the top percentiles of the income distribution. The
authors examine data from individual Social Security returns from 1937
to 2005. Since the data is based on Social Security returns, the income
reported only includes pre-tax, pre-transfer wages. In this article, we
only analyze publicly available statistics--income shares--of the Social
Security data (which, in general, is not publicly available). (4)
Another data set for high-earner incomes is the one studied by
Piketty and Saez (2003) in their examination of income tax returns since
1913. The large number of entries at the top of the distribution in this
data set allows us, for instance, to compare the evolution of income of
the 99.9th percentile and the 99th percentile of the income
distribution. In this article, we analyze summary statistics for labor
income made available by Emmanuel Saez. (5) As with the Social Security
data, the underlying data set is not publicly available. Labor income
data is available from 1927 to 2004 and is missing some years during
this period. It should be emphasized that tax data is reported at the
level of the tax unit, not the individual. Tax units are sometimes
individuals, sometimes couples, and sometimes extended families,
depending on how a household chooses to file its taxes and whom it
chooses to count as dependents. The increasing correlation between
spousal income and compositional changes in tax units makes trends in
this data not fully comparable with individual income trends. Because
income tax returns are only completed for workers above an exemption
limit, it is not possible to examine trends in the bottom of the income
distribution with this data set.
2. MEASURES OF INEQUALITY
We measure the degree of income inequality using range ratios and
income shares. There are many other commonly used measures of
inequality, such as Theil's T, variance of log income, Gini
coefficients, the coefficient of variation, and the Atkinson Index.
Cowell (1995) provides an overview of benefits and failures of each of
these measures.
Range ratios, such as the ratio between the 90th percentile income
and the 10th percentile income, are often used because they are easy to
understand and unambiguous to compute. Furthermore, they allow us to
conduct a quick decomposition of changes in inequality. For instance, we
will decompose a change in inequality summarized by a variation in the
"90-10 ratio" into changes in the bottom half of the income
distribution summarized by a variation in the "50-10 ratio"
and changes in the top half summarized by a variation in the "90-50
ratio."
As is standard in studies of income inequality, we focus on logged
ratios, because the log of a ratio of two values is equal to the
difference of the logs of these values, which is approximately equal to
the percentage change between these values. For instance, an increase in
the log 90-10 ratio from 0.10 to 0.15 implies that the worker in the
90th percentile went from making approximately 10 percent more than the
worker in the 10th percentile to making approximately 15 percent more.
Income shares are simply the share of income held by a given group,
such as the top 10 percent of the income distribution. This measure is
particularly useful for data sets that do not cover the entire income
distribution. For instance, income tax data before World War II covers
only the top few percents. Nonetheless, national accounts include total
income, and trends in top income shares can therefore be calculated.
3. INEQUALITY TRENDS FOR ALL WORKERS
In this section we focus on pre-tax individual labor income.
Focusing on individual income instead of household income allows us to
present inequality trends that are not directly affected by changes in
household composition. Piketty and Saez (2006) argue that changes in the
progressivity of taxes and transfers have been small and, therefore,
that pre-tax inequality trends are very similar to after-tax inequality
trends.
We study the evolution of inequality since the 1960s. Data
availability is significantly better for this period than for earlier
periods. Comprehensive micro-level data was only available sporadically before 1940, and decennially from 1940 to 1960. Regular surveys
beginning in the early 1960s, such as the CPS March Supplement, offer
annual income data along with matched information on education levels,
occupations, and other variables. This improved data availability allows
us to present a detailed examination of inequality trends.
We look at the evolution of the 90-10, 90-50, and 50-10 income
ratios. To compute these ratios, we use only the CPS data sets. We do
not have exact data for 10th percentile and 50th percentile incomes in
the IRS and Social Security data sets used in this article.
Figure 2 presents the evolution of log income ratios. It shows that
from 1961 to 2002, the CPS March log 90-10 ratio increased from 1,23 to
1.61. The ratios computed using the CPS ORG data set behave similarly.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 2 also shows that the vast majority of the increase in the
log 90-10 ratio is due to an increase in the 90-50 ratio. Since 1961,
the log 90-50 ratio grew 0.29, accounting for around 75 percent of the
overall increase in 90-10 inequality during this period. The increase in
90-50 inequality also accounts for nearly all of the increase in 90-10
inequality since 1990. This squares with results presented in earlier
studies (see, for example, Cutler and Katz 1991 and Katz, Autor, and
Kearney 2007). The log 50-10 ratio increased 0.09 during the 1980s but
was otherwise constant over the period studied.
The reason for the rise in the 50-10 income ratio during the 1980s
has received considerable attention in the income inequality literature.
Card and DiNardo (2002) conclude that the decrease in the real minimum
wage is responsible for up to 90 percent of the increase in bottom-half
income inequality in the 1980s. (6) Similarly, Lee (1999) uses
state-level data on wages and unemployment, and finds that nearly all of
the increase in bottom-tail income inequality in the 1980s is a result
of changes in the real minimum wage. In contrast, between 1998 and 2006
the real minimum wage fell nearly 20 percent and no significant increase
in bottom-half inequality was observed.
Figure 3 illustrates further that the increase in income inequality
during the period under study is concentrated at the top of the income
distribution. This figure presents the ratio between the real income in
2002 and the real income in 1978 for each decile of the income
distribution. It shows that during this period, differences in income
growth rates across percentiles are larger for the higher percentiles.
(7) In particular, as in Figure 2, Figure 3 shows that 50-10 inequality
increased less than 90-50 inequality during this period.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Since the increase in 90-10 inequality observed in recent decades
was concentrated at the top of the 90-10 income distribution, it may
also be important to analyze the top 10 percent of the income
distribution in order to have a better understanding of the overall
trend in inequality. Unfortunately, the CPS data sets are topcoded and
therefore do not allow us to conduct such analysis. One way of studying
the evolution of income inequality for top incomes is to use Social
Security data.
Figure 4 presents the shares of total pre-tax wage earnings of the
top 10 percent, the top 1 percent, and the top 0.1 percent of the
distribution computed using Social Security data by Kopczuk, Saez, and
Song (2007). It shows that between 1961 and 2003, the labor income share
of the top 10 percent rose from 27 to 37 percent, and that more than 60
percent of this rise is explained by an increase of the share of the top
1 percent of the income distribution. Kopczuk's data also includes
the income share of the top 0.1 percent since 1977. More than 60 percent
of the increase of the share of the top percentile between 1977 and 2003
is explained by a rise in the share of the top 0.1 percent. The top 0.1
percent of individuals earn between 2 and 5 percent of the national
labor income in our sample.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Though there is much less robust data on working conditions other
than labor income, evidence in previous studies suggests that including
nonwage income and compensation would increase the growth in inequality
observed in recent decades. Pierce (2001) compiles data on fringe
compensation from census microdata and finds that including benefits
such as leave and health insurance increases the growth of inequality.
Mishel, Bernstein, and Allegretto (2006) provide evidence of declining
medical insurance and pensions for low-wage workers. Hamermesh (1999)
finds that workplace injury rates and the number of nighttime or weekend
shifts have fallen more rapidly for high-wage workers than for low-wage
workers. These findings suggest that inequality measures based on labor
income alone should be taken as a lower bound of the increase in
inequality.
4. INEQUALITY TRENDS AND GENDER
In this section we present inequality trends for males and females
separately. We will show that trends in male and female income
inequality over the past few decades are similar. While in 1961 females
represented 34 percent of the labor force, in 2007 they represented 46
percent (Bureau of Labor Statistics).
Figure 5 presents the evolution of income ratios for males only and
females only. It shows that 90-10 inequality for males has been growing
since the late 1960s and that the rate of growth has been higher since
the second half of the 1970s. It also shows that 90-10 inequality grew
more among males than in the entire population. As in the entire
population, the inequality trend for males only is explained by a
continuous increase in the 90-50 ratio (which accelerated in the second
half of the 1970s) and a rise in the 50-10 ratio concentrated in the
1980s. This is consistent with results presented in previous studies
(see, for instance, Katz, Autor, and Kearney 2007).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figure 5 also shows that the level of inequality is lower among
females than among males. The timing of the increase in female
inequality is similar to that among males. As in the male population,
the increase in inequality among females is mainly explained by an
increase in 90-50 inequality and a rise in 50-10 inequality concentrated
in the 1980s.
Figure 6 presents the ratios between real incomes in 2002 and 1978
for different percentiles for both males and females (Figure 3 presents
the same ratios in the whole population). It shows that the bottom 50
percent of the male income distribution saw no more than a 5 percent
increase in real income from 1978 to 2002. The picture is different for
females, who have seen rising real wages between 1978 and 2002 across
all deciles. Thus, Figure 6 shows that females are driving the income
growth at the bottom of the income distribution presented in Figure 3.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
While inequality among both males and females has been increasing,
inequality between the two groups has been decreasing. Figure 7 presents
the evolution of the ratio of female income to male income at the 10th,
50th, and 90th percentiles in the CPS March Supplement data set--the
behavior of these ratios in the CPS ORG data set is similar. It shows
that, in general, the gender gap is larger at higher levels of income
distribution. This is consistent with the fact that inequality is higher
among males, as seen in Figure 5. Figure 7 also shows that the gender
gap closed substantially over time. The relative increase in female
incomes started in the 1970s for the 10th percentile and in the 1980s
for the 50th and 90th percentiles. This increase stopped in the
mid-1990s. The change in the gender gap implies that overall inequality
has been lowered as female incomes caught up with male incomes.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
5. INEQUALITY TRENDS AND EDUCATION
In this section we show that inequality has increased both between
education groups and within education groups. That is, real labor income
increased more for people with more years of education (an increase in
between-group inequality) and the dispersion in labor incomes increased
within education groups (within-group inequality increased).
Table 1 presents the evolution of CPS March Supplement male and
female labor income for different levels of education. Inequality trends
are similar in the CPS ORG data set. This table shows a substantial
increase in within-group inequality. For example, for males with a
college degree, the 10th percentile income increased 11 percent and the
90th percentile income increased 71 percent between 1963 and 2002. The
importance of within-group inequality illustrated in Table 1 is
consistent with results in previous studies that show that observable
characteristics--mainly education and experience--can only explain a
small fraction of observed inequality (see, for example, the discussion
in Lemieux 2006b).
Table 1 Real Labor Income (1963=1)
1972 1982 1992 2002
Postgraduate
Males 90th Percentile 1.43 1.65 TC TC
Males 50th Percentile 1.31 1.29 1.44 1.78
Males 10th Percentile 1.40 1.38 1.50 1.64
Females 90th Percentile 1.19 1.25 1.49 1.98
Females 50th Percentile 1.22 1.14 1.33 1.55
Females 10th Percentile 1.22 1.25 1.51 1.74
College Graduate
Males 90th Percentile 1.34 1.28 1.34 1.71
Males 50th Percentile 1.27 1.15 1.23 1.41
Males 10th Percentile 1.13 1.02 0.95 1.11
Females 90th Percentile 1.14 1.17 1.47 1.86
Females 50th Percentile 1.18 1.15 1.31 1.50
Females 10th Percentile 1.11 1.00 1.09 1.20
Some College
Males 90th Percentile 1.28 1.20 1.22 1.41
Males 50th Percentile 1.18 1.12 1.06 1.17
Males 10th Percentile 1.15 0.97 0.91 1.04
Females 90th Percentile 1.21 1.32 1.52 1.72
Females 50th Percentile 1.19 1.20 1.33 1.45
Females 10th Percentile 1.15 1.14 1.14 1.23
High School Graduate
Males 90th Percentile 1.24 1.23 1.20 1.31
Males 50th Percentile 1.25 1.17 1.06 1.11
Males 10th Percentile 1.16 0.95 0.83 0.89
Females 90th Percentile 1.27 1.34 1.45 1.62
Females 50th Percentile 1.18 1.16 1.21 1.33
Females 10th Percentile 1.21 1.18 1.13 1.21
High School Dropout
Males 90th Percentile 1.31 1.24 1.11 1.14
Males 50th Percentile 1.24 1.07 0.91 0.90
Males 10th Percentile 1.28 1.07 0.88 0.98
Females 90th Percentile 1.19 1.14 1.19 1.25
Females 50th Percentile 1.20 1.15 1.07 1.23
Females 10th Percentile 1.31 1.25 1.15 1.24
Notes: TC indicates that data was topcoded.
An increase in between-group inequality is also present in Table 1.
For example, between 1963 and 2002, the median male income increased 78
percent for postgraduates, 41 percent for college graduates, 17 percent
for some college, and 11 percent for high school graduates; it decreased
10 percent for high school dropouts. Table 1 also shows that the
increase in between-group inequality has been larger for males than for
females.
One can also see in Table 1 that there are periods characterized by
declines in real income for certain groups. The largest decline is a 27
percent decrease in the median income of high school dropouts between
1972 and 1992. Note that since the 1960s, the percentage of the labor
force without a high school degree has halved for both males and
females, falling to around 10 percent for each gender by 2006. The
declines in real income seem to have stopped in the 1990s.
A common explanation for the increase in the education premium is
skill-biased technological change (SBTC). The SBTC hypothesis suggests
that the introduction of computers increased returns to skills,
education, and experience, and therefore, resulted in a rise in
inequality (see, for example, Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce 1993). However,
more recent studies challenge this hypothesis by nothing that the return
to skills grew only in the 1980s and SBTC should have resulted in an
increase in the demand for skills in both the 1980s and the 1990s since
technological improvements continued into the 1990s (see, for example,
Card and DiNardo 2002).
6. WAGE INEQUALITY, WELFARE INEQUALITY, AND WEALTH INEQUALITY
So far, our analysis has focused on annual income inequality
trends. In this section we present brief discussions of hourly wage
inequality, welfare inequality, and wealth inequality.
Wage Inequality
Wage inequality trends may be different from the annual income
inequality trends discussed in previous sections because of different
trends in hours worked across the income distribution.
We construct wage inequality trends using CPS ORG data--as
discussed by Lemieux (2006b), CPS March Supplement data only includes
intervals of hours worked (e.g., 20-25 hours). The CPS ORG asks hourly
workers for their hourly earnings and it asks salaried workers for usual
weekly earnings and usual weekly hours worked.
Figure 8 presents logged 90-50 and logged 50-10 wage ratios for all
workers, males only, and females only. The figure shows that bottom-tail
inequality rose among all groups around the early 1980s, and it
increased more among females. Like 90-50 income inequality, 90-50 wage
inequality rose continuously from 1978 to 2005. The comparison of Figure
8 with Figures 2 and 5 shows that wage inequality trends are similar to
income inequality trends (note that the scale for the horizontal axis in
Figure 8 is different the scales in Figures 2 and 5 and, thus, it may
appear that inequality increases less in Figure 8 even though this is
not the case).
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Figure 9 presents the ratio between the real wage in 2005 and the
real wage in 1978 for each decile and for all workers, males only, and
females only. It also presents the same ratios for real income. The
figure shows that the distribution of real wage growth is similar to the
distribution of real income growth.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Welfare Inequality
Changes in welfare inequality should not be naively inferred from
trends in income inequality. Welfare measures depend on the consumption
of goods and leisure. It could very well be that while income inequality
has increased, consumption inequality has not increased, or that
individuals who benefited from higher consumption growth also
experienced a smaller increase in leisure.
Regular surveys on individual consumption have existed since the
early 1980s. Krueger and Perri (2006) find both that the level of
consumption inequality is lower than the level of income inequality and
that consumption inequality increased less than income inequality. They
find that, between 1980 and 2003, household income (after-tax labor
earnings plus transfers) inequality, measured as the variance of the
logs of income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) data set,
increased 21 percent. (8) They also find that during the same period,
depending on the treatment of durable goods, consumption inequality
increased between 2 and 10 percent. Blundell, Pistaferi, and Preston
(2006) argue that the difference between the rise in income inequality
and the rise in consumption inequality is explained by an increased in
the variability of transitory income shocks. They also explain that it
is more problematic for low wealth households to insure against these
shocks. Attanasio, Battistin, and Ichimura (2004) find a larger increase
in consumption inequality than Kreuger and Perri (2006) but nonetheless
argue that consumption inequality has increased less than income
inequality. These findings indicate that welfare inequality may have
increased less than income inequality.
Aguiar and Hurst (2007) examine leisure inequality by aggregating
irregular time-use surveys going back to 1965. Leisure is defined as
time not spent at work or on household production. They find that the
income-poor have seen the largest increase in leisure time. Table 2
shows that, since 1965, leisure has increased the most for those with
less education. (9) Since people with more education have, on average,
higher incomes, Aguiar and Hurst's (2007) findings imply relatively
larger gains in leisure at the bottom of the income distribution. (10)
Thus, these findings also imply that welfare inequality may have
increased less than income inequality.
Table 2 Mean Leisure Hours per Week for Males (Aguiar and Hurst 2007)
Years of
Schooling
Year/Category 0-1 1 12 13-15 16+
1965 104.12 101.66 99.21 101.64
1985 106.94 107.53 105.03 107.02
2003 116.34 108.94 105.42 101.44
Change 1965-2003 12.22 7.28 6.21 -0.20
Change 1985-2003 9.40 1.41 0.39 -5.58
Wealth Inequality
Wealth data is not as readily available as data on income, but
surveys such as the Federal Reserve's Survey of Consumer Finances and estate tax returns filings are analyzed in studies of wealth
inequality. It is well known that wealth is distributed much more
unequally than income. For instance, Castenada, Diaz-Gimenez, and
Rios-Rull (2003) find that in the United States, while the top 1 percent
of the wealth distribution holds 26 to 30 percent of the wealth, the
income share of the top 1 percent of the income distribution is only 10
to 15 percent of total income.
Trends in income inequality may influence trends in wealth
inequality through savings. However, studies have shown that the
increase in income inequality observed in recent decades has not been
reflected in an increase in wealth inequality. For example, Kopczuk and
Saez (2004) find that there has been very little change in the holdings
of the top of the wealth distribution since 1970 and that the only major
change in the wealth distribution during the 20th century is a massive
reduction in the wealth share of the top of the distribution between
1929 and 1945.
7. INEQUALITY TRENDS BEFORE THE 1960S
In this section, we summarize findings of studies of the evolution
of income inequality in the United States before the 1960s. There are no
large-scale regular population surveys that include individual labor
income data during this period. Before 1940, even the decennial U.S.
Census did not ask about income (see Williamson and Lindert 1980 and
Margo 1999 for discussions of these data limitations). Thus, income
inequality before 1940 can only be roughly estimated from sources such
as irregular local surveys, state censuses, and tax returns.
Kuznets (1955) famously discusses the basic trends in American
income inequality for this period: rising inequality before World War I
and falling inequality since the 1920s. Later studies confirmed these
trends.
Table 3 Standard Deviation of Manufacturing Wages (Margo 1999, Censuses
of Manufacturing)
1860 1880 Change
Log Wage 0.23 0.36 0.13
Log Wage with State Dummies 0.23 0.32 0.09
There is evidence of increasing wage inequality before the Civil
War. For instance, Margo (2000) identifies a compilation for wages paid
at government forts for hired labor (clerks, manual laborers, cooks,
etc.) from 1820 to 1860. He finds that in this period, wages of clerks
rose over a half percentage point more per year than wages of manual
laborers. This trend suggests that wage inequality rose--recall that
clerks were relatively educated workers in that period. Related wage
ratios for skilled artisans and other broad occupation classes show
similar patterns. Margo (2000) suggests that this increase in inequality
may have been driven in part by a change in the education premium.
Studies also find that income inequality continued to increase, and
the premium to skilled labor continued to rise until the end of the 19th
century. For example, Table 3 presents the increase in the dispersion of
manufacturing wages in the United States from 1860 to 1880 documented by
Margo (1999). This increase shows that not only did wage inequality grow
across industries, but it also grew within some
industries--manufacturing, in this case. Margo (1999) explains that this
increase is partially driven by changes in wages across regions after
the Civil War. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) report similar trends in
their study of the convergence in incomes among states during the
postbellum period, documenting a large drop in manufacturing wages in
the South. Williamson (2006) provides further evidence of these trends,
which he argues are explained in part by the increase in the supply of
unskilled labor resulting from high levels of immigration from Europe.
It has also been shown that wage differentials between blue-collar
and white-collar workers as well as inter-industry wage differentials
shrank around World War I and were stable until the end of the Great
Depression. Goldin and Katz (1999a) examine wage series for
manufacturing workers, university professors, engineers, and
bookkeepers. They find a decrease in the wage premium of the
high-education professions over manufacturing wages. Table 4 presents
examples of this decrease. The same data show a 20 to 30 percent
decrease in the 90-10 wage ratio among manufacturing workers in a number
of different industries from 1890 to 1940. Most of this change is
concentrated in the bottom half of the distribution. Further, a 1915
Iowa Census was conducted containing information on both income and
education, which can then be compared to 1940 United States census data
restricted to include only entries in Iowa. Goldin and Katz (1999b) use
this data to estimate the return in wages to a year of high school
education and find a decrease in this return from 13 percent in 1915 to
around 9.5 percent in 1940.
Table 4 Ratio of Wages of Educated Workers over the Average
Manufacturing Wage (Goldin and Katz 1999a)
Starting Engineers Male Clerical Workers
1895 -- 1.691
1909 1.202 1.652
1914 1.149 1.696
1919 1.005 1.202
1929 1.037 1.128
1939 1.008 1.150
1949 1.012 1.076
1959 -- 1.019
The period around World War II is characterized by decreases in
income inequality, an event often called "The Great
Compression." Goldin and Margo (1992) explain that this compression
is accounted for in part by the National War Labor Board's control
of wages during the war. They study public use microdata samples from
the 1940 and 1950 censuses and find a large drop in income inequality
during this decade, with a low level of income inequality persisting
through the 1960s. The return to a year of education computed by Goldin
and Katz (1999b) fell two to four percentage points between 1940 and
1950. Piketty and Saez's (2003) data on annual labor income
reported in tax returns to the IRS, and Kopczuk, Saez, and Song's
(2007) Social Security data show a large drop of the relative income of
the top earners around World War II. Figure 10 presents the behavior of
the income shares in these two data sets. Although IRS data uses tax
units income rather than individual income, the behavior of the two
series is quite similar.
8. CONCLUSIONS
This article documents an increase in income inequality in the
United States in recent decades. Furthermore, the article documents
periods characterized by a decline in real income for lower income
groups. We show that this increase in inequality is explained mainly by
an increase in inequality at the top of the income distribution.
Significant increases in inequality within lower incomes are only
observed during the 1980s. We also explain that welfare inequality may
have increased less than income inequality. Finally, we show that the
recent period of increasing inequality followed a period of decreasing
inequality since World War I, which in turn followed a period of
increasing inequality in the 19th century.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Achenbach, Joel. 2007. "Clinton and Inequality." The
Trail.
http://blog.washingtonpost.com/the-trail/2007/10/12/post_134.html.
Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst. 2007. "Measuring Trends in
Leisure: The Allocation of Time over Five Decades." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 122 (August): 969-1006.
Attanasio, Orazio, Erich Battistin, and Hidehiko Ichimura. 2004.
"What Really Happened to Consumption Inequality in the US?"
Working Paper 10338. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research. (March).
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1992.
"Convergence." Journal of Political Economy 100 (April):
223-51.
Bernanke, Ben. 2007. "The Level and Distribution of Economic
Well-Being." Speech delivered to Greater Omaha Chamber of Commerce,
Omaha, February 6.
Blundell, Richard, Luigi Pistaferi, and Ian Preston. 2006.
"Consumption Inequality and Partial Insurance." Mimeo,
Stanford University.
Borghans, Lex, and Bas ter Weel. 2004. "The Diffusion of
Computers and the Distribution of Wages." IZA Discussion Paper No.
1107 (April).
Card, David, and John E. DiNardo. 2002. "Skill-Biased
Technological Change and Rising Wage Inequality: Some Problems and
Puzzles." Journal of Labor Economics 20 (October): 733-83.
Castenada, Ana, Javier Diaz-Gimenez, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull.
2003. "Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth
Inequality." Journal of Political Economy 111 (August): 818-57.
Cowell, Frank. 1995. Measuring Inequality. London: Prentice Hall.
Cutler, David, and Lawrence Katz. 1991. "Macroeconomic Performance and the Disadvantaged." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1991.2: 1-74.
Diaz-Gimenez, Javier, Santiago Budria, Vincenzo Quadrini, and
Jose-Victor Rios-Rull. 2002. "Updated Facts on the U.S.
Distributions of Earnings, Income and Wealth." Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Summer): 2-35.
Eckstein, Zvi, and Eva Nagypal. 2004. "The Evolution of U.S.
Earnings Inequality: 1961-2002." Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis Quarterly Review (December): 10-29.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1999a. "The Returns to
Skill Across the Twentieth Century United States." Working Paper
No. 7126. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
(June).
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1999b. "Human Capital
and Social Capital: The Rise of Secondary Schooling in America, 1910 to
1940." Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29 (Spring): 683-723.
Goldin, Claudia, and Robert A. Margo. 1992. "The Great
Compression: The Wage Structure of the United States at
Mid-century." Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 1-34.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1999. "Changing Inequality in Markets for
Workplace Amenities." Quarterly Journal of Economics 114
(November): 1085-123.
Ip, Greg, and John D. McKinnon. 2007. "Bush Reorients
Rhetoric, Acknowledges Income Gap." Wall Street Journal, March 26,
A2.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin Murphy, and Brooks Pierce. 1993. "Wage
Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill." Journal of Political
Economy 101 (June): 410-42.
Katz, Lawrence, David Autor, and Melissa Kearney. 2007.
"Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists."
Working Paper (March).
Kopczuk, Wojciech, and Emmanuel Saez. 2004. "Top Wealth Shares
in the United States 1916-2000: Evidence from Estate Tax Returns."
Working Paper No. 10399. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research. (March).
Kopczuk, Wojciech, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song. 2007.
"Uncovering the American Dream: Inequality and Mobility in Social
Security Earnings Data since 1937." Working Paper No. 13345.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. (August).
Krueger, Dirk, and Fabrizio Perri. 2003. "On the Welfare
Consequences of the Increase in Income Inequality in the United
States." Working Paper No. 9993. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research. (September).
Krueger, Dirk, and Fabrizio Perri. 2006. "Does Income
Inequality Lead to Consumption Inequality? Evidence and Theory."
Review of Economic Studies 73: 163-93.
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. "Economic Growth and Income
Inequality." American Economic Review 45 (March): 1-28.
Lee, David S. 1999. "Wage Inequality in the United States
During the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling Minimum Wage?"
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (August): 977-1023.
Lemieux, Thomas. 2003. "Residual Wage Inequality: A
Re-examination." Manuscript, University of British Columbia.
Lemieux, Thomas. 2006a. "Post-secondary Education and
Increasing Wage Inequality." American Economic Review 96 (May):
195-9.
Lemieux, Thomas. 2006b. "Increasing Residual Wage Inequality:
Composition Effects, Noisy Data, or Rising Demand for Skill?"
American Economic Review 96 (June): 461-98.
Luxembourg Income Study. 2007. United States 2000: Survey
Information. www.lisproject.org/techdoc/us/us00survey.pdf (October).
Margo, Robert A. 1999. "The History of Wage Inequality in
America, 1820 to 1970." Levy Economics Institute Working Paper 286
(November).
Margo, Robert A. 2000. Wages and Labor Markets in the United
States: 1820 to 1860. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mishel, Lawrence, Jared Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto. 2006. The
State of Working America 2006-2007. Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy
Institute.
Pierce, Brooks. 2001. "Compensation Inequality."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (November): 1493-525.
Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. 2003. "Income Inequality
in the United States, 1913-1998." Quarterly Journal of Economics
118 (February): 1-39.
Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. 2006. "How Progressive is
the U.S. Federal Tax System?" Working Paper 12404. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. (August).
Weinberg, John, and Aaron Steelman. 2005. "What's Driving
Wage Inequality?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly (Summer): 1-17.
Williamson, Jeffrey G. 2006. "Inequality and Schooling
Responses to Globalization Forces: Lessons from History." Working
Paper 12553. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
(October).
Williamson, Jeffrey G., and Peter H. Lindert. 1980. American
Inequality: A Macroeconomic History. New York: Academic Press.
The authors would like to thank Kartik Athreya, Andreas Hornstein,
Nashat Moin, and Alex Wolman for helpful comments. The views expressed
in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System. E-mails: Kevin. Brayn@rich.frb.org and
Leonardo.Martinez@rich.frb.org.
(1) For instance, it has been discussed recently by George W. Bush,
Hillary Clinton, and Ben Bernanke--see Ip and McKinnon (2007), Achenbach
(2007), and Bernanke (2007).
(2) Note that in Figure 1, per-worker income and percentile incomes
are obtained from different sources. As explained later, the Current
Population Survey, our source of percentile incomes, cannot be used to
compute total income because income in this survey is topcoded. In order
to check whether using different sources is problematic, we also
calculated per-worker labor income by using the Current Population
Survey to obtain the income for the bottom 90 percent of the
distribution and by using the labor income shares of the top 10 percent
of the distribution, as computed by Kopczuk, Saez, and Song (2007). We
found that the growth of this measure of per-worker income is very
similar to the growth of the measure reported in Figure 1.
(3) This file can be found at
http://faculty.wcas.northwestern.edu/~een461/QRproject/.
(4) We use summary statistics made available by Wojciech Kopczuk at
http://www.columbia.edu/~wk2110/uncovering/.
(5) See http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/.
(6) The real minimum wage fell 30 percent between 1980 and 1988. It
was roughly stable during the 1990s (Card and DiNardo 2002, Figure 22).
(7) In Figure 3, CPS ORG income growth is lower than CPS March
income growth. Although several studies examine differences between CPS
ORG data and CPS March data (see, for example, Lemieux 2003, 2006a, and
2006b; Borghans and ter Weel 2004; and Katz, Autor, and Kearney 2007),
we are not aware of a comprehensive explanation of the differences
between the income growth rates in the two data sets.
(8) Krueger and Perri (2003) find that trends in household income
are very similar in equivalent samples of the CPS ORG, the PSID, and the
Consumer Expenditure Survey.
(9) This table reports Aguiar and Hurst's (2007)
"median" measure of leisure, which includes time sleeping,
eating, and activities "pursued solely for direct enjoyment."
Note that this definition of leisure does not discriminate between
individuals who voluntarily choose not to work and those who are
involuntarily unemployed.
(10) The increase in leisure inequality documented by Aguiar and
Hurst (2007) is not inconsistent with the trends in income and wage
inequality being similar in Figures 2, 5, 8, and 9. These figures are
constructed by considering only full-time workers, and Aguiar and Hurst
(2007) construct leisure trends by considering both full-time and
part-time workers.
Kevin A. Bryan and Leonardo Martinez