The Phillips curve and U.S. macroeconomic policy: snapshots, 1958-1996.
King, Robert G.
The curve first drawn by A.W. Phillips in 1958, highlighting a
negative relationship between wage inflation and unemployment, figured
prominently in the theory and practice of macroeconomic policy during
1958-1996.
Within a decade of Phillips' analysis, the idea of a
relatively stable long-run tradeoff between price inflation and
unemployment was firmly built into policy analysis in the United States and other countries. Such a long-run tradeoff was at the core of most
prominent macroeconometric models as of 1969.
Over the ensuing decade, the United States and other countries
experienced stagflation, a simultaneous rise of unemployment and
inflation, which threw the consensus about the long-run Phillips curve into disarray. By the end of the 1970s, inflation was historically
high--near 10 percent--and poised to rise further. Economists and
policymakers stressed the role of shifting expectations of inflation and
differed widely on the costliness of reducing inflation, in part based
on alternative views of the manner in which expectations were formed. In
the early 1980s, the Federal Reserve System undertook an unwinding of
inflation, producing a multiyear interval in which inflation fell
substantially and permanently while unemployment rose substantially but
temporarily. Although costly, the disinflation process involved lower
unemployment losses than predicted by consensus macroeconomists, as
rational expectations analysts had suggested that it would.
By 1996, the central bank of the United States had constructed a
large-scale rational expectations model, without any long-run tradeoff,
which it began to use to evaluate alternative policy scenarios. Monetary
policymakers at that time accepted the idea that there was no long-run
tradeoff at, and above, the then-prevailing price inflation rate of 3
percent. Yet many felt that there were important tradeoffs over
short-run horizons, diversely defined, and some saw long-run tradeoffs
near zero price inflation.
This article reviews the evolving role of the Phillips curve as an
element of macroeconomic policy during 1958-1996, as well as academic
and central bank research on it, via a series of snapshots over this
roughly 40-year period. In conducting the research summarized in this
article, my motivation is to better understand the mindset about the
tradeoff between inflation and unemployment over an important period of
U.S. history with an eye toward ultimately better understanding the
joint behavior of the Federal Reserve and the U.S. economy during that
period. Diverse research in macroeconomics--notably Sargent (1999),
Orphanides (2003), and Primiceri (2006)--has sought an explanation of
inflation's role in the behavior of a central bank that has an
imperfect understanding of the operation of the private economy. The
perceived nature of the Phillips curve plays an important role in these
analyses, so that my reading of U.S. history may provide input into
future work along these lines. I draw upon two distinct and
complementary sources of information, published articles and documents
of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), to trace the evolving
interpretation of the tradeoff over this roughly 40-year period.
The discussion is divided into six sections that follow this
introduction. Section 1 provides a quick overview of the U.S. experience
with price inflation and unemployment during 1958-1996. As the objective
of this article is to provide a description of how policymakers'
visions of the Phillips curve may have evolved during this time,
resulting from empirical and theoretical developments, it is useful to
have these series in mind as we proceed. Section 2 describes the birth
of the Phillips curve as a policy tool, highlighting three core
contributions: Phillips' original analysis of U.K. data, Samuelson
and Solow's (1961) estimates of the curve on U.S. data and their
depiction of it as a menu for policy choice, and the econometric analysis by Klein et al. (1961) and Sargan (1964) of the
interrelationship between wage inflation, price inflation, and
unemployment, which formed the background for wage and price blocks of
macroeconomic policy models. Section 3 depicts the battle against
unemployment that the United States waged during the 1962-1968 period
and its relationship to the Phillips curve in then-prominent
macroeconomic policy models. Section 4 discusses the breakdown of the
empirical Phillips curve during 1969-1979, a period including intervals
of stagflation in which unemployment and inflation rose together, and
theoretical criticisms of the Phillips curve as a structural
macroeconomic relation. Section 5 indicates the role of the Phillips
curve during the unwinding of inflation in the United States during 1980
through 1986. Section 6 concerns several aspects of policy modeling and
policy targeting in 1996 as the United States returned to a sustained
interval of relatively low inflation. Section 7 concludes.
1. INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT, 1958-1996
Since my discussion focuses on studies of inflation and
unemployment that were written during 1958 through 1996, it seems useful
to start by providing information on U.S. inflation and unemployment
over that historical period, augmented by a few initial years, as in
Figure 1. As measured by the year-over-year percentage change in the
gross domestic product deflator, inflation averaged just under 4
percent, starting and ending the 1955-1996 interval at about 2.5
percent. Inflation twice exceeded 10 percent, in 1974-75 and 1981. The
unemployment rate averaged 6 percent, starting and ending the sample
period near 5 percent. Recession intervals, as dated by the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), are highlighted by the shaded lines
in Figure 1.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
My snapshots of the Phillips curve and its role in macroeconomic
policy are usefully divided into five periods.
* The formative years in which the initial studies were conducted,
1955-1961. During this interval, there were two recessions (August 1957
through April 1958 and April 1960 through February 1961), each of which
was marked by declining inflation and rising unemployment.
* The battle against unemployment from 1962 through 1968 during
which unemployment fell substantially, with inflation being at first
quiescent and then rising substantially toward the end of the period.
* The breakdown of the Phillips curve empirically and
intellectually came from 1969 through 1979. In this period, there were
two recessions. During December 1969-November 1970, both inflation and
unemployment rose but there was a brief decline in inflation within the
recession. During November 1973 through March 1975, inflation and
unemployment both rose dramatically. This period was a tumultuous one,
marked by departure from gold standard, wage and price controls, energy
shocks, as well as difficult political and social events.
* The unwinding of inflation took place during 1980 through 1985,
with a substantial reduction in inflation accompanied by a sustained
period of unemployment.
In the aftermath, 1986-1996, the Phillips curve assumed a new form
in monetary policy models and monetary policy discussions.
2. THE FORMATIVE YEARS
Figure 2 is the dominant image from Phillips' initial article:
a scatter plot of measures of wage inflation and unemployment in the
United Kingdom over 1861-1913 supplemented by a convex curve estimated
by a simple statistical procedure. During the 1960s, U.S. macroeconomic
policy analysis and models were based on a central inference from this
figure, which was that a permanent rise in inflation would be a
necessary cost of permanently reducing unemployment. However, as
background to that period, it is useful for us to understand how the
Phillips curve was estimated initially, how it crossed the Atlantic, and
how it was modified so that it could be imported into macroeconomic
policy models.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The Original Study
Phillips (1958) described the objective of his study as follows:
"to see whether statistical evidence supports the hypothesis that
the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom can be
explained by the level of unemployment and the rate of change of
unemployment, except in or immediately after those years in which there
was a very rapid rise in import prices, and if so to form some
quantitative estimate of the relation between unemployment and the rate
of change of money wage rates.'" He began with the study of
inflation and unemployment over multiyear periods, which he called trade
cycles, and then he assembled these intervals into the overall curve
that bears his name.
Trade cycles and the Phillips curve
The celebrated trade-off curve was derived by a complicated
procedure. First, Phillips explored the behavior of a measure of wage
change and unemployment over a series of historical United Kingdom
"trade cycles," an alternative label for the sort of business
cycles that Burns and Mitchell (1946) had identified for the United
States. (2) The cycle for 1868-1879 is shown in Panel A of Figure 3. It
begins with several years of falling unemployment and rising wage
inflation, then an interval of rapidly declining wage inflation and
modestly rising unemployment, then a number of years of wage declines
accompanied by substantially increasing unemployment. Over the course of
this cycle, there was an initial interval (1868-1872) during which
inflation rose by about 10 percent, while unemployment dropped by about
5 percent. Then, from 1872-1875, there was a period of sharply declining
inflation accompanied by modestly rising unemployment. Finally, from
1876-1879, there was a period of negative inflation (- 1 to -3 percent
per year) coupled with dramatically rising unemployment.
Phillips' identification of the tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment did not rely on the shape of the cyclical pattern over the
course of this and other individual trade cycles. Instead, the wage
inflation and unemployment observations over the 1868-1879 trade cycle
were averaged by Phillips to produce one of the "+" points in
Figure 2, with the long-run curve adjusted so that it fit through these
cycle averages. (3) The curve, fitted to six "+" points,
contained three free parameters and implied that very low values of
unemployment would lead to very high inflation, while very high values
of unemployment would lead to very low inflation. (4)
Thus, the Phillips curve was based on average inflation and
unemployment observations over the course of trade cycles of varying
lengths. Although it was sometimes criticized as capturing short-run
relations, Phillips' procedure contained significant lower
frequency information. Yet, these cycle averages were drawn from the
period when the United Kingdom was on the gold standard so that there
were limits to the extent of price inflation or deflation.
Exploration of subsequent periods
After estimating the long-run curve on l861-1913 data, Phillips
then examined the extent to which the subsequent behavior of wage
inflation and unemployment could be understood using the curve.
Looking at 1913-1948 as shown in Panel B of Figure 3, Phillips
concluded that the general approach worked well. In particular, the
trade cycle of 1929-1937 fit his general pattern, but he puzzled
somewhat over the relatively high rates of inflation in 1935-1937. Other
parts of the 1913-1948 interval fit in less well. As potential
explanations of the behavior of wage inflation during both the First
World War and the subsequent deflation to return the pound to its
pre-war parity, Phillips discussed the potential importance of
cost-of-living changes (effects of price inflation on wage-setting) as
contributing to wage inflation in the wartime period and to wage
deflation during the post-WWI interval). The sharp declines in nominal
wage rates in 1921 and 1922, as Britain returned to pre-war parity with
gold, stand out dramatically in Panel B of Figure 3. Although these
points lie far from the curve based on 1861-1913 data, they are dramatic
outliers that nevertheless show a negative comovement of inflation and
unemployment in line with Phillips' general ideas.
Phillips also explored the consistency of the period following the
Second World War, 1948-1957, with his long-run curve. During this
period, U.K. unemployment was at a remarkably low level (between 1 and 2
percent) and inflation varied widely, as shown in Panel C of Figure 3.
Phillips commented on several aspects of this interval. First, he noted
that a governmental policy of wage restraint was in place in 1948 and
apparently temporarily retarded wage adjustments. Second, he noted that
the direction of the trade-cycle "loop" had reversed from the
earlier period, which he suggested might be due to a lag in the
wage-setting process. Third, he used this period to show how his curve
could be used to partition wage inflation into a "demand-pull"
component, associated with variation in unemployment along the curve and
other factors, which induced departures from the curve. After looking at
retail price inflation during this period, Phillips suggested that some
of the wage inflation observations, such as the 1948 value that lies
well above the curve, could have arisen from "cost-push"
considerations in which workers bargained aggressively for higher
nominal wages. However, Phillips concluded that the post-WWII period was
broadly consistent with the curve fit to the 1861-1913 data.
U.S. Background to a Vast Experiment
In 1960, Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow examined U.S. data on the
rate of change in average hourly earnings in manufacturing and the
annual average data on unemployment over an unspecified sample period,
which is most likely 1890 through the late 1950s. (5) Their empirical
analysis most closely resembles the 1861-1913 Phillips analysis that we
have just looked at, but the overall association was looser, as
dramatically displayed in Panel A of Figure 4.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Like Phillips, Samuelson and Solow looked at sub-samples, noting
that money wages rose or failed to fall during the high unemployment era
of 1933 to 1941, which they suggested might be due to the workings of
the New Deal. Further, they noted that the World War I period also
failed to fit into the expected pattern, in line with Phillips'
findings discussed above.
Overall, though, Samuelson and Solow argued that "the bulk of
the observations--the period between the turn of the century and the
first war, the decade between the end of that war and the Great
Depression, and the most recent ten or twelve years--all show a rather
consistent pattern. Wage rates do tend to rise when the labor market is
tight, and the tighter the faster." They noted with interest that
"the relation, such as it is, has shifted upward slightly but
noticeably in the forties and the fifties." In the early years,
before and after the first war, "manufacturing wages seem to
stabilize absolutely when 4 or 5 percent of the labor force is
unemployed; and wage increases equal to the productivity increase of 2
to 3 percent per year is the normal pattern at about 3 percent
unemployment" and described this finding as "not so terribly
different" from Phillips' results. In the later years,
1946-1959, Samuelson and Solow judged that it "would take more like
8 percent unemployment to keep money wages from rising and that they
would rise at 2 to 3 percent per year with 5 or 6 percent of the labor
force unemployed." (6) It is these later years that Samuelson and
Solow circled in Panel B of Figure 4.
To describe the policy implications of their findings, Samuelson
and Solow (1961) drew a version of the Phillips curve as representing
tradeoffs between price inflation and unemployment. Essentially, this
involved using the idea that price inflation and wage inflation were
different mainly by the growth of labor productivity, suggesting an
implicit model of relatively quick pass-through from wages to prices.
To obtain price stability under the assumption that real wages
would grow at 2.5 percent per year, they suggested that the American
economy would have to experience a 5 to 6 percent rate of unemployment
(this option is marked as point A in Panel B of Figure 4). By contrast,
they suggested that "in order to achieve the
nonperfectionist's goal of 3 percent unemployment, the price index
might have to rise by 4 to 5 percent per year" (this option is
marked as point B). (7)
Seeking to understand whether inflation originated from cost-push
or demand-pull factors, Samuelson and Solow described a "vast
experiment" in which "by deliberate policy one engineered a
sizeable reduction in demand" so as to explore the effects on
unemployment and inflation. Although they were not explicit about the
mechanism, they likely shared the prevailing Keynesian view of the time
that fiscal and other policies that cut aggregate demand would first
increase unemployment, with higher unemployment then reducing wage and
price inflation. One interpretation of the subsequent 30 years of U.S.
history is that versions of such experiments, with both increases and
decreases in demand, were repeatedly undertaken. (8)
The Samuelson and Solow analysis led to a detailed research program
of estimating the long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment
in the United States. Given that interpretation and the subsequent
development of macroeconometric models, it is interesting to note that
Samuelson and Solow (1961) included a foreshadowing of future critiques
of the long-run tradeoff: "aside from the usual warning that these
are simply our best guesses, we must give another caution. All of our
discussion has been phrased in short-run terms, dealing with what might
happen in the next few years. It would be wrong, though, to think that
our menu (Figure 4B) that relates obtainable price and unemployment
during the next few years will maintain its shape in the longer
run." They pointed to two reasons for potential instability--one
was that "wage and other expectations" might shift the
position of the Phillips curve and the other was that
"institutional reforms" including product and labor market
regulations or direct wage and price controls might shift the American
Phillips curve downward and to the left. (9) Both expectations and
wage-price controls were to play an important role in the subsequent
history of the Phillips curve in the United States and other countries.
Wages, Prices, and Lags
Macroeconomic models along Keynesian lines first aimed at capturing
the dynamics of aggregate demand. Thus, for example, the Duesenberry,
Eckstein, and Fromm (1960) simulation study of the U.S. economy in
recession used a quarterly econometric model with 14 equations governing
aggregate demand: it contained neither a monetary sector nor a
wage-price block. That is, the interaction between shocks and the
components of aggregate demand was viewed as first order for
understanding the behavior of the U.S. economy in a recession, with
implications for wages and prices or their influences taken as less
important. Fiscal policy measures rather than monetary policy measures
were introduced in many studies of the time, reflecting a professional
focus on fiscal rather than monetary policy tools.
Yet, after these first stages, U.K. and U.S. modelbuilders
introduced a block of equations for wages and prices, stimulated in part
by the work of Phillips (1958). The monograph by Klein et al. (1961)
reports on a multiyear project to construct quarterly U.K. data and to
estimate an econometric model with a wage-price sector. These authors
found that distributed lags were important in the wage and price
equations. (10)
In contrast to the specifications of Klein et al. (1961), one
notable element of Sargan's (1964) investigation was that he
required that his equations display homogeneity, so that the absolute
levels of wages and prices were not important for model properties.
Sargan, therefore, studied a wage equation of the form
[W.sub.t] - [W.sub.[t-1]] = [lambda] ([W.sub.[t-1]] -
[P.sub.[t-1]]) + [beta][u.sub.[t-1]] + [gamma]t + [xi] [[Florin].sub.t]
+ [phi] ([P.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-4]], (1)
where [W.sub.t] is the log nominal wage rate in quarter t,
[P.sub.t] is the log nominal price level, [u.sub.t] is the unemployment
rate, and [[Florin].sub.t] is a measure of the political party in power.
He divided the analysis of this equation into two components. First, an
equation that described wage changes as deriving from deviations from an
equilibrium real wage,
[W.sub.t] - [W.sub.[t-1]] = [lambda] [W.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-1]]
- [[bar.w].sub.[t-1]], (2)
and a specification for the equilibrium real wage
[[bar.w].sub.[t-1]] = [[beta]/[lambda] [u.sub.[t-1]] +
[gamma]/[lambda] t + [xi]/[lambda] [[Florin].sub.t] + [phi]/[lambda]
([P.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-4]])]. (3)
This is simply an algebraic decomposition, but Sargan (1964) was
insistent that the elements of the equilibrium wage process made
internal sense, for example requiring that the coefficient
[gamma]/[lambda] is interpretable as the effect of productivity growth
on the real wage. He also interpreted the parameter [lambda] as a speed
of adjustment toward the equilibrium."
Following the work of Klein et al., Sargan also estimated a price
equation that linked prices to wages. Sargan explored measures of
productivity, demand, and relative input costs as additional
determinants of prices. Combining the wage and price equations, Sargan
was able to trace out dynamic consequences of changes in the
unemployment rate on wages and prices. These were influenced by the
strength of the equilibrating tendencies ([lambda]) and the influence of
the price terms ([phi]) from the wage equation. For example, even if
there were no lags of wages in the wage equation, there still could be
indirect effects coming from the presence of price lags.
Sargan (1964) concluded that there was a long-run tradeoff between
wage inflation and unemployment, but that there were also lengthy
average lags so that changes in unemployment and other variables would
take several years to be fully reflected in wage inflation. These broad
properties were widely built into Keynesian macroeconometric models, as
wage and price sectors were added to the initial aggregate demand
constructions.
3. THE BATTLE AGAINST UNEMPLOYMENT
The 1962 Economic Report of the President was the first prepared by
the Kennedy Council of Economic Advisors (CEA), which was eager to
implement "The New Economics" originating in the work of
Keynes.(12) The 1962 Report discussed the origins of unemployment in
labor market frictions and in aggregate demand conditions, concluding
that the "objective of maximum employment" would have to use
policies aimed principally at labor market conditions. The 1962 Report
argued that "in the existing economic circum-stances, and
unemployment rate of about 4 percent is a reasonable and prudent full
employment target for stabilization policy," further stressing that
additional policy interventions to reduce structural unemployment would
make it possible to further reduce that target. At the same time, the
Report built the case that the macroeconomic conditions of the late
1950s and early 1960s had led to an "output gap" of between 4
and 10 percent. As shown in the top panel of Figure 5, the output gap
was the difference between actual output and a smooth trend line, based
on an assumed level and rate of growth of capacity. Based on the work of
a young economist at the CEA (Okun 1962), unemployment was linked to the
output gap, so that a 2-percentage-point higher unemployment rate was
related to an output gap of 5 percent. That is, the Report built in an
Okun's Law coefficient of 2.5 to produce the second panel of Figure
5. While the "Phillips curve tradeoff" is now frequently
discussed in terms of inflation and the output gap using some version of
Okun's Law, this article will maintain the original linkage between
inflation and unemployment as its focus.
In fact, the Kennedy-Johnson administration did deliver a
substantial decline in unemployment, as a look back at Figure 1
confirms. In keeping with the tenor of the times, in which a package of
fiscal, structural, and monetary policies was viewed as necessary for
and capable of producing this decline, the present article will not seek
to separately identify the contributions of different types of policies.
Histories of the period, such as Hetzel (2008, chapters 6 and 7), stress
the coordination of fiscal and monetary decisionmaking, so that such an
identification could be quite subtle.
The 1962 Report did note that "the economy last experienced 4
percent unemployment in the period May 1955-August 1957. ... During this
period, wages and prices rose at rates which impaired the
competitiveness of some U.S. goods in world markets. However, there is
good reason to conclude that upward pressures of this magnitude are not
a permanent and systematic feature of our economy when it is operating
in the neighborhood of 4 percent unemployment." Looking back at
Figure 1, the reader will notice that the inflation rate rose by several
percentage points during the 1955-1957 period alluded to in the CEA
report, while unemployment averaged about 4 percent.
By the late 1960s, some version of the long-run Phillips curve
tradeoff had become a cornerstone of economic policy. It entered
centrally in macro-economic models and more ephemerally in macroeconomic
reports. (13)
Macroeconomic Models
In fall 1970, the Federal Reserve System sponsored a major
conference on "The Econometrics of Price Determination," which
contained a wide range of studies and later appeared in 1972 as a volume
edited by Otto Eckstein. Drawn from one of these studies, Figure 6
displays the long-run relationship between price inflation and
unemployment as of 1969 within three prominent macroeconomic models of
the sort used by the U.S. private sector for forecasting purposes, by
the executive branch of the U.S. government, and by the U.S. central
bank. This figure is reproduced from the Hymans (1972) survey of the
price dynamics within the Office of Business Economics (OBE) model used
by the executive branch, the Federal Reserve-MIT-Penn (FMP) model used
by the central bank, and the DHL-III model developed by Hymans and
Shapiro at the University of Michigan.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
As Hymans explains (1972, 313), this figure was produced by taking
the wage-price block of the various models and evaluating these
equations at alternative unemployment rates. One first finds the
long-run inflation rate when the unemployment rate is constant at, say 5
percent, and then one finds the long-run inflation rate at 4 percent and
so on.
By and large, these estimates of the long-run relationship accord
well with that portrayed by Samuelson and Solow (1961) and reproduced as
Panel B of Figure 4 in this article. Further, the increase in the
inflation rate from about 1 percent in 1960-61 to about 4.5 percent in
1968-69 is particularly well captured by the FMP and DHL models.
Although each long-run Phillips curve is nonlinear and there are
differences in models, the "average" tradeoff over this range
is that lowering unemployment by 2.5 percent (from 6 to 3.5) costs about
3.5 percent in terms of inflation (from 1 percent to 4.5 percent).
Smaller changes in inflation and unemployment feature a roughly
one-for-one tradeoff.
The dynamics of wages and prices were studied by many authors under
a variety of assumptions within the FMP and other large models. For
example, de Menil and Enzler (1972) considered the effect of changing
the unemployment rate from 4 percent to 5 percent in the FMP model: The
results of their investigations are shown in Figure 7. The economy is
assumed to be in an initial steady state with price inflation of 3.4
percent per year (wage inflation is just over 6 percent) and
unemployment of 4 percent. Then, unemployment increased to 5 percent at
date 1 and at all future dates. The inflation rate declines to 2.7
percent after four quarters, to 2.2 percent after three years and to 1.9
percent after five years. Compensation per man-hour (the wage measure)
drops from 6 percent to 4.9 percent after a year, to 4.6 percent after
three years, and to 4.4 percent after five years. The more rapid
response of wage inflation is related to the fact that unemployment
affects wages immediately, with effects of wages on prices occurring
only with a distributed lag. (14)
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Overall, the short-run Phillips curve reported by de Menil and
Enzler (1972) is flatter than the long-run one that they report
(essentially that for the FMP in Figure 6): a 1 percent increase in
unemployment brings about a .7 percent change after a year's time,
but a 1.5 percent decline in inflation after five year's time. From
the standpoint of the econometric modelers of the time, this was a
natural result of the lags in the wage-price components of their model,
built in along Klein-Sargan lines. Looking at Figure 6, economists such
as de Menil and Enzler likely saw a consistency with the dynamic
specification of the macroeconomic policy model: the historical
inflation rate initially lies below the long-run Phillips curve in the
early 1960s during the start of the transition to lower unemployment.
Macroeconomic Reports
The 1969 Economic Report of the President was the last report of
the Kennedy-Johnson era and was prepared under the leadership of Arthur
Okun. With inflation rising, early 1968 saw a new cabinet-level
Committee on Price Stability charged to recommend actions to contain
inflation. President Johnson's introductory remarks in the Report
distinguished between "roads to avoid" and "roads to
reducing inflation." The roads to avoid were an "overdose of
fiscal and monetary restraint" or "mandatory wage and price
controls." The "roads to follow" included a combined
fiscal and monetary program--including a continuation of the 1968 tax
surcharge--as a "first line of defense," but also voluntary
cooperation in wage and price setting to aid the process of reducing
inflation.
The 1969 Report portrayed the U.S. economy as running at or
slightly above potential output, with associated unemployment in the
neighborhood of 4 percent. As portrayed in Figure 8, the potential
output series resembles that presented in the 1962 Report (Figure 5),
but the detailed notes make clear that potential output grew at 3.5
percent over 1955-1962; at 3.75 percent over 1963-1965; and at 4 percent
over 1966-1968. Thus, an acceleration of potential output growth was
necessary to fit together the 1962 Report's view of 4 percent as
the unemployment target, which finally was hit in the latter years of
the Kennedy-Johnson era, with the behavior of output during those years.
With more modest potential output, there would have been a very negative
output gap during the final years of the Kennedy-Johnson era, whereas it
is only slightly negative in Figure 8.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The 1969 Report also featured a Phillips scatter plot, from
1954-1968, highlighting the historical relationship between "price
performance and unemployment" during the Kennedy-Johnson years,
although no trade-off curve was displayed. The decline in unemployment
from the 5.5 percent level of 1963 to the 3.5 percent level of 1968 was
associated with a rise in inflation from 1.5 percent to close to 4
percent. The Report's accompanying discussionof the historical
record stresses the importance of a wage-price spiral arising from
demand growth in excess of capacity growth. It argued that "once
such a spiral starts, it becomes increasingly difficult to arrest, even
after productive capacity has caught up with demand and the initial
pressures have largely subsided."
Thus, the Report's explicit stand is that the U.S. economy in
1969 was operating close to capacity, with a rate of unemployment that
was not necessarily inflationary, a viewpoint that echoes the appraisal
in the 1962 Report. The rise in inflation over the eight years of the
Kennedy-Johnson administration is, therefore, implicitly portrayed as
arising from the effects of a wage and price spiral, not a purposeful movement along a long-run Phillips curve.
4. BREAKDOWN, 1969-1979
The breakdown of the consensus concerning the long-run Phillips
curve involved a major revision of macroeconomic theory along with an
unusual pattern of inflation and unemployment, with these intertwined
developments reinforcing each other.
Macroeconomic Theory
As the Phillips curve played an increasing role in macroeconomic
models, and as inflation rose during the mid-1960s, economists began to
take a harder look at its theoretical underpinnings. The implications of
new models were then compared to unemployment and inflation data, with
results that sparked a major empirical controversy and a revolution in
macroeconomic modeling.
The natural rate hypothesis
In the late 1960s, Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps made separate
arguments about why the long-run Phillips curve should be vertical.
Friedman (1968) began from a vision of the labor market in which real
wages and employment (or unemployment) were jointly determined in
response to local and aggregate conditions of supply and demand. His
natural rate of unemployment was "the level that would be ground
out by the Walrasian system of general equilibrium equations, provided
there is imbedded in them the actual structural characteristics of the
labor and commodity markets, including market imperfections, stochastic variability in demands and supplies, the cost of gathering information
about job vacancies and labor availabilities, the costs of mobility, and
so on." He then imagined a situation in which firms offered workers
nominal rather than real wages, with workers evaluating labor supply
opportunities based on their best estimate of the purchasing power of
those wages. With a known path for the price level, this calculation is
easy for workers, but it becomes harder when the price level is
changing. Friedman (1968) imagined the central bank increasing the
growth of the money supply and stimulating the demand for the final
product. To hire additional workers, firms would offer higher nominal
wages. Faced with higher nominal wages that were interpreted as higher
real wages, workers would supply more hours and potential workers would
accept more jobs. So, it was possible for Friedman's model to
reproduce a Phillips curve of sorts. However, if workers correctly
understood that the general level of prices was increasing as a result
of a monetary expansion, there would be no real effects: The rate of
inflation and the rate of wage growth would jointly neutralize the
effect of a higher rate of monetary growth, leaving real activity
unaffected.
Phelps (1967) analyzed the problem in more Keynesian terms, based
on a specification of a price equation of the following type: (15)
[P.sub.t] - [P.sub.[t-1]] = [[pi].sub.t] = [beta]([u.sub.t] - u *)
+ [[pi].sub.t.sup.e], (4)
where u * is the "natural rate of unemployment," in
Friedman's terminology, and [[pi].sup.e] is the expected rate of
inflation. Phelps argued for this sort of "expectations-augmented
Phillips curve" specification on grounds similar to those of
Friedman that we have already discussed: labor suppliers should make
their decisions on real, not nominal grounds.
Further, Phelps studied this inflation equation under the
assumption of adaptive expectations,
[[pi].sub.t.sup.e] = [theta][[pi].sub.[t-1]] + (1 -
[theta])[[pi].sub.[t-1].sup.e], (5)
where 0 < [theta] < 1 governs the weight placed on recent
information in forming expectations. This specification implies that if
inflation were maintained at any constant level, [bar.[pi]], then
expected inflation would ultimately catch up to it since the sum of
coefficients in the distributed lag representation of expected
inflation,
[[pi].sub.t.sup.e] = [theta] [[infinity].summation over (j=0)]
[(1-[theta]).sup.j] [[pi].sub.[t-j-1]],
is equal to one.
The "expectations-augmented Phillips curve" means that
unemployment would be low (u < u*) only if agents are surprised.
Thus, a policy of maintaining low unemployment requires consistent
underforecasting of inflation, [pi] < [[pi].sup.e]. But low
unemployment could only be brought about by raising the inflation rate
to a higher and higher level, with expectations always lagging behind
because of the adaptive mechanism (5). Hence, the view of Friedman and
Phelps became known as the "accelerationist hypothesis" in
some quarters.
Phelps also stressed that the accelerationist model meant that a
temporary period of low unemployment would bring about a permanently
higher rate of inflation. He recognized that this led to an important
new dynamic element in policy design, relative to traditional work that
had stressed the Phillips curve as a stable "menu of policy
choice" for the long run. Generally, a period of temporarily high
unemployment would be necessary to permanently reduce inflation and some
basic economic mechanisms--such as a momentary social planner objective
that attributes increasing cost to high unemployment--making it
desirable to smooth the adjustment process.
Overall, the natural rate/accelerationist hypothesis moved the
worries of Samuelson and Solow (1961) about the effects of expectations
on the Phillips curve from second-order to first-order status.
Tests of Solow and Gordon
From the perspective of wage and price adjustment equations of the
form prominent in Keynesian theoretical and empirical models, the
arguments of Friedman and Phelps suggested that there were important
omitted expectational terms. Solow (1969) and Gordon (1970) devised
tests to determine whether there was a long-run tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment. To capture the spirit of these tests,
consider a wage equation along the Klein-Sargan lines, such as (1)
above. As above, the nominal wage at a given date will be [W.sub.t], and
the real wage will be [w.sub.t], = [W.sub.t], - [P.sub.t], . However,
the inflation terms in (1) are replaced by expected inflation,
[[pi].sub.t.sup.e], with a coefficient [alpha] attached,
[DELTA][W.sub.t], = [lambda]([w.sub.[t-1]] - [w *.sub.[t-1]]) +
[beta]([u.sub.t] - [u *.sub.t]) + [alpha][[pi].sub.t.sup.e]; (6)
other time-varying terms will be omitted for simplicity. (16)
The tests of Solow and Gordon made diverse use of price and wage
equations, but the essential features can be simply described using this
expression. First, in the wage equation above, the Friedman-Phelps
conclusion obtains if [alpha] = 1 since this is simply a restriction on
expected real wages and unemployment,
[w.sub.t] - [w.sub.[t-1]] = [lambda]([w.sub.[t-1]] - [w
*.sub.[t-1]]) + [beta]([u.sub.t] - [u *.sub.t]) - [[pi].sub.t] -
[[pi].sub.t.sup.e]. (7)
There is, thus, no influence of inflation if expectations are
correct and no tradeoff between real and nominal variables. Solow and
Gordon proposed to directly estimate the parameter [alpha] and to
evaluate the accelerationist view by testing whether [alpha] differed
significantly from unity. Second, this test is challenging to implement
because expectations are unobservable. However, if expectations are
formed adaptively, as in (5), then it is possible to conduct the test.
Solow (1969) estimated parameters such as [alpha] for a range of
different values of [theta], while Gordon (1970) used a more general
distributed lag but maintained the requirement that the coefficients
summed to unity. This sum of the coefficients restriction was
rationalized by the Phelpsian thought experiment, comparing a zero
inflation steady state to a positive inflation steady state at rate
[pi]: If the sum of coefficients is one, then expected inflation is
[[pi].sup.e] = 0 in the first case and [[pi].sup.e] = [pi] in the second
case.
All of their diverse estimates suggested values of [alpha] that
were positive, but significantly less than one. Thus, an aggregate
demand policy that lowered unemployment in a sustained manner would
create rising inflation over time, as expectations increased, but it
would not ultimately be unsustainable.
Rational expectations critique
Sargent (1971) and Lucas (1972a) criticized the tests of Solow and
Gordon by invoking two arguments. First, Sargent and Lucas insisted that
expectations formation should be rational along the lines of Muth
(1961). Second, they constructed example economies in which the
accelerationist position was exactly correct, but in which an
econometrician using the methods of Solow and Gordon would reach an
incorrect conclusion.
A valuable example arises when inflation ([pi]) has a persistent
(x) and temporary ([eta]) component, so that it is generated according
to
[[pi].sub.t] = [x.sub.t] + [[eta].sub.t]
[x.sub.t] = [rho][x.sub.[t-1]] + [e.sub.t],
where [[eta].sub.t] and [e.sub.t] are serially uncorrelated, zero
mean random variables and [absolute value of ([rho])] < 1.
As analysis along the lines of Muth (1960) determines, rational
expectations then are formed according to
[E.sub.[t-1]][[pi].sub.t] = [rho][[theta][pi].sub.[t-1]] + (1 -
[theta])[E.sub.[t-2]][[pi].sub.[t-1]] =
[rho][theta][[infinity].summation over (j=0)] [(1 -
[theta]).sup.j][[pi].sub.[t-j-1]], (8)
with 0 < [theta] < l. This is broadly the same form as the
adaptive expectations formula above, except that the distributed lag now
is multiplied by [rho], which captures the degree of persistence of
inflation. (17)
In particular, suppose that inflation is somewhat persistent but
stationary so that 0 < [rho] < 1, and that there is no effect of
inflation on the real wage, i.e., [alpha] = 1. Then, an econometrician
constructing a measure of expectations [^.[pi].sub.[t-1]] = [theta]
[[infinity].summation over ([j=0])] [(1 - [theta]).sup.j]
[[pi].sub.[t-j-1]] for any [theta] < 1 = [rho][[pi].sub.[t-1]] would
face data generated according to
[W.sub.t] - [W.sub.[t-1]] = [gamma]([w.sub.[t-1]] - [w
*.sub.[t-1]]) + [beta]([u.sub.t] - [u *.sub.t]) +
[rho][[^.[pi]].sub.[t-1]], (9)
and would conclude that [alpha] = [rho]. That is, the
econometrician would estimate that there was a long-run tradeoff,
[alpha] < 1, even though none, in fact, existed.
The critique played an important role in the evolution of
macroeconomic modeling. Lucas (1972b) built a small-scale general
equilibrium macroeconomic model with a short-run Phillips curve arising
without any long-run tradeoff, providing an analytical interpretation of
Friedman's (1968) suggestion about the nature of the link between
inflation and real activity. Lucas (1976) expanded the critique of the
policy invariance of parameters within 1970s macroeconomic models into a
general challenge, noting that similar difficulties were contained in
the consumption function and the investment function, as well as the
wage-price block. He stressed that rational expectations and dynamic
optimization, which seemed useful as basic postulates for model
construction, inevitably led to such problems. A major revolution in
econometric model construction ensued, leading central banks around the
world to develop new models for forecasting and policy analysis during
the 1990s, as we discuss in Section 6.
Shifting unemployment-inflation tradeoffs
What is wrong with the sum of coefficients restriction employed by
Solow and Gordon? Sargent (1971) notes that inflation through the
mid-1960s did not display much serial correlation, so it is not well
forecasted by a moving average with weights that sum to unity.
Intuitively, in an economy in which there are never any permanent
changes in inflation, rational expectations are not designed to guard
against this possibility.
Yet, as inflation rose and stayed high through the 1970s, empirical
model-builders found estimates of parameter values drifting toward one
and were more open to accelerationist models of the Phillips curve. I
have searched for, but have not found, a 1970s study that succinctly shows this drift in coefficients. McCallum (1994) calculates the sum of
coefficients implied by a fifth-order autoregression for inflation
estimated over various periods: it is about one-third in 1966-67,
two-thirds in 1968-70, and between .88 and 1.02 for 1973-1980.
McCallum's exercise indicates why econometric modelers found
increasing evidence for the accelerationist hypothesis as the evidence
from the 1970s was added.
Up a derivative: NAIRU models
As inflation rose during the mid-1970s, the wage and price blocks
of standard macroeconometric models were augmented in various ways. One
route was to include expectations terms explicitly but to make these
expectations respond sluggishly to macroeconomic conditions. Another,
arguably initially more popular strategy originates in the work of
Modigliani and Papademos (1975). These authors argued that empirical
models of price and wage dynamics would have better success if they
related changes in inflation measures to levels of real variables.
Modigliani and Papademos viewed inflation as likely to accelerate if
unemployment was low relative to a benchmark value and as likely to
decelerate if unemployment was high relative to a benchmark. They argued
that this feature, as indicated by points A and C in Figure 9, was far
more important for policy analysis than the question of whether the
long-run Phillips curve had a negative slope (as in P P') or was
vertical (as in F F').(18) Further, they stressed that "the
shading of an area on either side of NAIRU indicates both uncertainty
about the exact location of NAIRU and the implausibility that any single
unemployment rate separates accelerating and slowing inflation."
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The NAIRU model has been commonly captured by a simple model of the
form,
[[pi].sub.t] = [[pi].sub.[t-1]] + [beta] ([u.sub.t] - [u.sup.n]),
(10)
a specification closely related to that of Phelps (equation [4]),
but with past inflation replacing expected inflation. Moving up a
derivative allowed for a continuation of empirical research on price and
wage inflation, which investigated the consequences adding lags of
inflation and unemployment as well as adding shift variables to the
basic NAIRU model. Thus, such empirical investigations built in a
particular assumption on the "accelerationist hypothesis" that
differed from the earlier research following Phillips, but continued to
study many similar questions. However, uncertainty about the location of
the NAIRU, as Modigliani and Papademos had suggested, led to challenges
in the application of this approach in forecasting and policy
analysis.(19)
Macroeconomic Policy
The Nixon administration came into office in 1969 with the aim of
reducing inflation via a combination of orthodox fiscal and monetary
methods, but sought to do so without prolonging the recession that the
country was then experiencing.
Gradualism
The Nixon administration initially embarked on a course of
"policy gradualism" in an attempt to reduce inflation while
maintaining real activity and unemployment at relatively constant
levels. In a mid-course appraisal, Poole (1970) provides a useful
definition of such policies: "The prescription of gradualism
involves the maintenance of firm but mild restraint until the objectives
of anti-inflationary policy are realized. Real output is to be
maintained some-what below potential until the rate of inflation
declines to an acceptable level." The policies outlined in the 1970
Economic Report of the President, produced under the leadership of CEA
chairman Paul McCracken, contained both fiscal and monetary components
designed to generate a modest reduction in output for the purpose of
reducing inflation. (20)
Rising understanding of the importance of expectations
Arthur Burns became head of the Federal Reserve System in early
1970, replacing William McChesney Martin, who had served since 1951.
During 1969, Martin had undertaken restrictive monetary policy to reduce
inflation, indicating that "expectations of inflation are deeply
imbedded. ... A slowing in expansion that is widely expected to be
temporary is not likely to be enough to eradicate such
expectations" and "a credibility gap has developed over our
capacity and willingness to maintain restraint." (21) The phrase
"credibility gap" had a particularly harsh ring to it, even as
part of a self-criticism, as it had been widely used to describe the
Vietnam policies of the Johnson administration: The Tet offensive of
September 1968 had convinced many that there was no credibility to the
administration's previous upbeat forecasts for military success or
its description of the offensive as a disastrous defeat for the Viet
Cong. Martin believed that unemployment was unsustainably low and that
economic growth would need to slow to reduce inflation, which was at
about 5 percent during late 1968 when Richard Nixon was elected
president. But the restrictive monetary policy of 1969-1970 started by
Martin, envisioned as part of a gradualist strategy by McCracken, and
continued by Burns, resulted only in a slowing of inflation, but not a
major decline, during the recession of December 1969-November 1970.
As Hetzel (1998) stresses, Burns had a long-standing belief that
expectations were important for inflation, writing in the late 1950s
that: "One of the main factors in the inflation that we have had
since the end of World War II is that many consumers, businessmen, and
trade union leaders expected prices to rise and therefore acted in ways
that helped to bring about this result." (22) After taking over the
Fed, he made the case that it was possible to side-step the Phillips
curve through the imposition of wage and price controls, which he
believed would exert a substantial effect on expectations. (23)
Incomes policies
By the middle of 1971, the Nixon administration lost patience with
gradualism, imposing a 90-day temporary freeze on prices on August
15,1971, and ending the convertibility of the dollar into gold. The
temporary freeze evolved into a multiyear incomes policy with various
phases differing in intensity and coverage. The 1973 Economic Report of
the President noted that "1972 was the first full year in American
history that comprehensive wage and price controls were in effect when
the economy was not dominated by war or its immediate aftermath"
(page 51). The Report indicated that there had been three purposes for
the controls (page 53). First, the controls were intended to directly
affect the rate of inflation, lower the probability of its increase, and
raise the probability of its decline. Second, the controls were aimed at
"reducing the fear that the rate of inflation would rise or not
decline further." Third, the controls were designed to
"strengthen the forces for expansion in the private economy and to
free the Government to use a more expansive policy." In describing
the conditions in the spring and summer of 1971 that led to the
imposition of the controls, the Report specifically discussed
"anxiety" about increasing inflation as holding back consumer
spending and rising long-term interest rates that "may have
signalled rising inflationary expectations." Overall, a key
motivation for the controls was to affect expectations of inflation and
their incorporation into price and wage setting.
Many analysts see the incomes policy period as involving
expansionary monetary policy--as in the third Report point above--with
fiscal policy under the Nixon team and monetary policy under Burns
producing an economic expansion. Unemployment hovered in the 6 percent
range through 1971, dropping to 5 percent by the end of 1972 as Nixon
won a landslide re-election. Inflation, according to the gross domestic
product deflator shown in Figure 1, had fallen from 5 percent in 1971 to
4 percent in 1972, but it then rose to a 7 percent annual rate by the
end of 1973.
Skepticism about government goals
By the time of the publication of the 1973 Economic Report of the
President, many economists were becoming more skeptical about both the
long-run Phillips curve and, more specifically, about whether government
plans were consistent with the available information on the historical
linkage between inflation and unemployment. The review of the 1973
Report by the mainstream economist Carl Christ provided one clear
presentation of this skepticism. He noted that every economic report
contains an overall statement of objectives by the President followed by
a more detailed and nuanced report by his economic advisors.
An initial quote from Christ's review summarized the condition
of the previous year for us: "Mr. Nixon's report begins with a
review of the good things about 1972: a 71/2 percent rise in real
output, a reduction of the inflation rate (measured by the consumer
price index) to about 3 percent from about 6 percent in 1969, and a
reduction of the unemployment rate to 5.1 percent in December 1972 from
6 percent in December 1971."
The 1973 goals of the Nixon administration were summarized by
Christ using a series of quotations from Nixon's message:
"Output and incomes should expand. Both the unemployment rate and
the rate of inflation should be reduced further, and realistic
confidence must be created that neither need rise again. The prospects
for achieving these goals in 1973 are bright--if we behave with
reasonable prudence and foresight" (p. 4); "We must prepare
for the end of wage and price controls ..." (p. 6). Christ notes
that this buoyant optimism on inflation and unemployment is
"reminiscent of Mr. Nixon's statement in January 1969, shortly
after taking office, that he would reduce inflation without increasing
unemployment and without imposing wage and price controls."
Christ then proceeded to argue that the optimism was unwarranted:
"The evidence strongly suggests it is not possible for the American
economy, structured as it has been since World War II, to achieve
simultaneously unemployment rates that remain at 4.75 percent or less,
and consumer price increases that remain at 2.4 percent a year or less,
without wage or price controls. In the 25 years since consumer prices
leveled off at the end of World War II, this has been achieved in only 4
years: 1952, 1953, 1955, and 196 ... In those same 25 years, the average
unemployment rate was 4.8 percent, and the average increase in consumer
prices was 2.4 percent a year."
Figure 10 was produced by Christ using data from the 1972 Report.
Notice that Christ's argument is not that the long-run Phillips
curve is vertical, although that view is not inconsistent with his
figure. Instead, it is that public policy goals ought to be consistent
with the available evidence and that unemployment far below the 1972
level of 5 percent and inflation below the 1972 level of 3 percent did
not seem consistent with U.S. experience.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Christ's warning was a timely one: The remainder of the
Nixon-Ford administration saw the onset of stagflation, as a look back
at Figure 1 reminds us. The United States was not to see 5 percent
unemployment and 3 percent inflation at any time in the next two
decades.
Humphrey-Hawkins
While Christ may have been skeptical about the internal consistency of the Economic Report of the President in 1973, the debates over the
legislation put forward by Representative Augustus Hawkins and Senator
Hubert H. Humphrey five years later illustrated that other elements of
government and society continued to seek very low unemployment.
As initially passed by the House in March 1978, the Full Employment
and Balanced Growth Act specified the goal of lowering the unemployment
rate to 4 percent for all working age individuals and 3 percent for all
individuals over the age of 20. Early drafts of the House bill had
mandated that the government be an "employer of last resort"
for the long-term unemployed, but this provision was dropped, while the
focus on unemployment was maintained. The national unemployment goal was
to be reached within five years and the bill called for cooperation
between the executive branch, Congress, and the Federal Reserve Board in
working toward the specified target. It also specified that the
President should submit an annual economic report to Congress including
numerical goals for employment, unemployment, and inflation, as well as
some other macroeconomic indicators. Amendments to add budget balance as
a goal at the five-year horizon and to include an inflation goal of 3
percent at that time were defeated. The bill evolved substantially in
order to gain Senate approval. In the process, inflation objectives were
reinstated. It was signed into law by President Jimmy Carter on October
27, 1978.
The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act in final form
established national goals of full employment, growth in production,
price stability, and balance of trade and public sector budgets. More
specifically, it specified that by 1983, unemployment rates should be no
more than 3 percent for persons aged 20 or over and no more than 4
percent for persons aged 16 or over. Inflation should be no more than 4
percent by 1983 and 0 by 1988. Thus, in its nonbinding goals, it
displays the same tendencies that Christ identified in the Economic
Report of the President.
While these goals were nonbinding, the Humphrey-Hawkins Act did
require that the Federal Reserve Board of Governors transmit a report to
Congress twice a year outlining its monetary policy.
5. UNWINDING INFLATION
By the late 1970s, a wide range of economists and politicians were
becoming concerned about high inflation and recommending disinflation.
However, economists and politicians differed widely on the costs of
reducing inflation.
Forecasting the Costs of Disinflation
Surveying six estimates of "macroeconomic Phillips
curves," Okun (1978) found that the experience of the 1970s had led
to the abandonment of the long-run Phillips curve. Yet, he also stressed
that "while they are all essentially accelerationist, implying no
long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, they all point to
a very costly short-run tradeoff." Thinking about the Phelpsian
question of how fast unemployment should be raised from a situation of
initially low capacity utilization, in terms of the consequences for
long-run inflation, he calculated "for an extra percentage point of
unemployment maintained for a year, the estimated reduction in the
ultimate inflation rate." Comparing the various studies, he found
that this disinflation gain for a given amount of unemployment ranged
between 1/6 and 1/2 of a percent, with an average estimate of 0.3
percent.
To put Okun's numbers in a specific context, consider the
unemployment cost attached to a 5 percent reduction in long-run
inflation. The estimates reported by Okun meant that this cost would be
between 10 = [5/(1/2)] and 30 = [5/(1/6)] "point years of
unemployment," with an average estimate of 16.7[5/.3]. That is, if
the cost of eliminating a 5 percent inflation was spread evenly over
four years, then each year would see an unemployment rate that was
between 2.5 and 7.5 percent above the natural rate with a mean estimate
of over 4 percent.
It is now more standard to discuss disinflation costs as a ratio of
point years of unemployment arising from a one percent change in
inflation, which is called the "sacrifice ratio." (24)
Okun's estimates were that the sacrifice ratio was in the range of
2 to 6, with a mean of 3.3 in that each percentage point reduction in
inflation would involve very major economic costs.
Put another way, by the late 1970s, policymakers may have abandoned
the long-run Phillips curve in the face of evidence and theory. But most
major econometric models continued to maintain a tradeoff over horizons
of four or more years, as originally described by Samuelson and Solow.
Just as there had been a protracted period of low unemployment as
inflation had risen, so too did Okun envision a protracted period of
high unemployment as inflation was reduced.
The perceived severity of a potential reduction in inflation is
perhaps best illustrated in an excerpt from James Tobin's (1980)
review of stabilization policies at the close of the first decade of the
Brooking's Panel. To put the excerpt in context, Tobin's
review described the accelerationist hypothesis as having been a core
part of macroeconomics for the better part of the previous decade. Tobin
wrote that it was broadly recognized that "inflation accelerates at
high employment rates because tight markets systematically and
repeatedly generate wage and price increases in addition to those
already incorporated in expectations and historical patterns. At low
utilization rates, inflation decelerates, but probably at an
asymmetrically slow pace. At the Phelps-Friedman "natural rate of
unemployment," the degrees of resource utilization and market
tightness generate no net wage and price pressures up or down and are
consistent with accustomed and expected paths, whether stable prices or
any other inflation rate. The consensus view accepted the notion of a
nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) as a practical
constraint on policy, even though some of its adherents would not
identify NAIRU as full, equilibrium, or optimum employment." (25)
To put the potential costs of a disinflation in front of his
audience, Tobin used a very simple inflation model with a NAIRU of 6
percent unemployment and assumed that the economy originated from an
inflation rate of 10 percent. As displayed in Figure 11, he studied a
gradual disinflation in which the central bank reduced the growth rate
of nominal aggregate demand smoothly so that it falls by 1 percent each
year for 10 years. Thus, after a decade, the conditions for price
stability are met from the aggregate demand side. Tobin also assumed
that the expectations term was an eight-quarter, backward-looking
average of recent inflation rates. Tobin stressed that the result was
"not a prediction! ... but a cautionary tale. The simulation is a
reference path, against which policy-makers must weigh their hunches
that the assumed policy, applied resolutely and irrevocably, would bring
speedier and less costly results." The cautionary tale of Figure 11
involves an initial decade in which unemployment looks to average about
8.5 percent, 2.5 percent higher than its equilibrium value, so that the
sacrifice ratio during this period is about 2.5 since inflation is being
reduced by 10 percent. So, while the tale was cautionary, the message
was consistent with the range of Okun's sacrifice ratio estimates
and, hence, meant to depict some potential consequences of disinflation.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
There were some skeptics. William Fellner (1976) viewed the
government policies of the 1970s as sharply inconsistent with the
objective of bringing about low inflation, echoing Christ's 1973
concerns. Fellner argued that households and firms would be similarly
skeptical and that the disinflation process was costly in part because
of the imperfect credibility of policies, so he endorsed a policy of
gradualism like that which Tobin explored in his simulation coupled with
strong announcements about future policy intentions. However, economists
like Tobin were quite skeptical about the practical importance of this
line of argument, while accepting the basic logical point that
expectations effects could mitigate some of the output losses associated
with his gradualist simulation. Considering the benefits of preannounced
stabilization plan credibility, Tobin (1980) wrote: "The question
is how much. One obvious problem is that a long-run policy commitment
can never be it-revocable, especially in a democracy. Important economic
groups will not find it wholly credible, and some will use political
power to relax or reverse the policy. Even assuming credibility and
understanding by private agents, their responses are problematic. In the
decentralized but imperfectly competitive U.S. economy, wage and price
decisions are not synchronized but staggered. It is hard to predict how
individual firms, employees, and unions will translate a threatening
macroeconomic scenario into their own demand curves. If each group
worries a lot about its relative status, each group will decide that the
best strategy is to disinflate very little." Thus, Tobin (1980)
argued that it would be "recklessly imprudent to lock the economy
into a monetary disinflation without auxiliary incomes policies. The
purpose of these policies would be to engineer directly a deceleration of wages and prices consistent with the gradual slowdown of dollar
spending." In contrast to Fellner's case for gradualism,
rational expectations theorists like Sargent began to explore actual
disinflation experiences, using the lessons of the models that they had
developed in the mid-1970s. In particular, in his "Ends of Four Big
Inflations," no later than spring 1981, Sargent argued that
dramatic, sustained anti-inflation policies could bring about reductions
in inflation with relatively low unemployment costs, as long as such
policy changes were credible and that their dramatic nature enhanced
their credibility.
The Volcker Disinflation
Paul Volcker assumed the chairmanship of the Federal Reserve System
(FRS) in August 1979. Looking back at Figure 1, we can see that
inflation was substantially reduced, while there was a lengthy period of
high unemployment. As cataloged in many discussions, the Federal Reserve
made a high-profile announcement of a shift to monetary targeting in
October 1979 in the face of rapidly rising inflation; there were two
recessions during the period, one short and relatively mild, one lengthy
and severe, and the inflation rate had declined dramatically by 1984.
There are many questions about the Phillips curve during this
important historical period, but our focus in this section will be
limited to two. First, how did the unemployment cost of the actual
disinflation line up with the suggestions of Okun and others? Second,
how did the Federal Reserve perceive the menu of policy choice during
this period?
The unemployment cost
Mankiw (2002, 369-701) calculates the unemployment cost of the
Volcker disinflation under the assumption that there was a 6 percent
natural rate of unemployment during 1982-1985, with the inflation rate
falling from 9.7 percent in 1981 to 3 percent in 1985. His annual
average unemployment numbers were 9.5 percent in 1982 and 1983, 7.4
percent in 1984, and 7.1 percent in 1985 so that there was a total
cyclical unemployment cost of 9.5 percent of unemployment. One can argue
about details of this calculation, for example with whether the
disinflation should be viewed as starting in 1980 or in 1981, about the
natural rate of unemployment, and so on. But it is a reference textbook
calculation familiar to many: The sacrifice ratio during the Volcker
disinflation is estimated by Mankiw to be about 9.5/6.7 = 1.5.
Mankiw's sacrifice ratio is about one-half of that which Okun
suggested on the basis of his mean estimate and lies below the low end
of the range in the studies that he reviewed. The 6.7 percent decline in
the inflation rate should have had the effect of raising the
unemployment rate by a total of 22 percent over the period according to
the average estimate, 13.4 percent according to the low estimate, and
over 40 percent for the high estimate. Put another way, the mean
estimate implies that unemployment should have been higher by more than
5 percent over each year of a four-year disinflation period.
Some have suggested that this lower cost was due to increased
credibility of the Fed and its disinflationary policies under Volcker;
others have suggested that the cost was largely due to the central
bank's imperfect credibility. (26) However, as McCallum (1984)
points out, the testing of hypotheses about credibility is subtle
because the measures of private expectations about policy that must be
constructed are more involved than in standard rational expectations
models.
The Fed's Perceived Unemployment Cost
One key question about this disinflation period is "How did
the Federal Reserve System view the tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment?" The developments reviewed above, in which the nature
of the tradeoff was subject to substantial controversy and evaluated in
an evolving model, makes this a particularly interesting question. It is
also not an easy question to answer, as any central bank is a large
organization with many differing viewpoints and its policymakers do not
file survey answers about their perceived tradeoffs.
However, the question can be answered in part because the
Humphrey-Hawkins legislation requires testimony by the FRS chairman
twice a year, in late January or early February and again in July. For
the six FOMC meetings each year, the research staff under Volcker
prepared a basic forecast of the economy's developments within the
"Green Book" under a particular benchmark set of policy
assumptions. For the FOMC meetings that precede the chairman's
testimony, the staff also prepared a set of alternative policy options
within the "Blue Book" of which Table 1 provides examples at
two FOMC meetings. In both cases, then, the alternative strategies were
framed in terms of growth rates for the M1 concept of money and were
based on the Board's quarterly macroeconometric (MPS) model along
with staff judgemental adjustments, so that they reflected the effects
of pre-existing economic conditions as well as alternative paths of
policy variables. (27) Projections under alternative strategies during
the Volcker deflation also took into account forecasted developments in
fiscal policy, which were being revamped by the Reagan administration at
the time.
Table 1 FRB Economic Projections Associated with Alternative
Monetary Growth Strategies
January 1980
Strategy 1980 1981 1982
Money Growth 1 6.0 6.0 6.0
2 4.5 4.5 4.5
[DELTA]= 1-2 -1.5 -1.5 -1.5
Inflation 1 9.5 8.7 7.7
2 9.1 8.2 6.8
[DELTA] = 1-2 -0.4 -0.5 -0.9
Unemployment 1 8.1 8.9 9.3
2 8.4 10.1 11.6
[DELTA]=1-2 0.7 1.2 2.3
January 1982
Strategy 1982 1983 1984
Money Growth 1 4.0 3.5 3.0
2 5.5 5.0 4.5
[DELTA] = 2-l -1.5 -1.5 -1.5
Inflation 1 6.4 5.1 4.2
2 6.5 5.4 5.3
[DELTA] = 2-l -0.1 -0.3 -0.9
Unemployment 1 9.3 9.1 8.9
2 9.0 8.2 6.9
[DELTA] = 2-l 0.3 0.9 2.0
T-Bill 1 13.0 12.5 11.0
2 9.7 8.3 8.4
[DELTA] = 2-l 3.3 4.2 2.6
Notes: These table items are drawn from the Federal Reserve Blue
Books "Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions," January 4,
1980, page 11, and "Monetary Policy Alternatives," January 29, 1982,
page 7.
The first meeting is the January 1980 FOMC session, at which the
benchmark strategy (called strategy 1 in this meeting) was for 6 percent
money growth over each of three years: 1980, 1981, and 1982. Under this
benchmark policy, as can be seen by reading across the relevant row of
the table, the forecast was that U.S. inflation would gradually decline
from 9.5 percent in 1980 to 7.7 percent in 1982, but that there would be
high and rising unemployment in each year (8.1 percent in 1980, 8.8
percent in 1981, and 9.3 percent in 1982). In this general sense, the
forecast incorporated a Phillips curve but one that depended in a
complex manner on initial conditions and shocks. However, the staff also
forecasted unemployment and inflation under an alternative policy, 4.5
percent money growth. Hence, it is possible to use the difference in
forecasts to gain a sharper sense of the tradeoff under alternative
monetary policies. The forecast differences are listed as the row
[DELTA] in the table. The January 1980 FOMC meeting corresponded with
the onset of a recession, as later dated by NBER researchers.
The second meeting is the January 1982 FOMC session, at which the
benchmark strategy (again called strategy 1 in this meeting) was for a
gradually declining path of money growth: 4.0 percent in 1982, 3.5
percent in 1983, and 3.0 percent in 1984. Again, the FRS staff
forecasted declining inflation (from 6.4 in 1982 to 4.2 in 1984) but
this time with declining unemployment (from 9.3 percent in 1982 to 8.9
percent in 1984). The perceived Phillips curve was less evident in these
forecasts, but an opportunity to appraise its nature is afforded by the
fact that the staff also prepared forecasts under the assumption of
higher money growth (strategy 2).
There are a number of aspects of the benchmark policy projections
that are notable. First, in each case, strategy 1 is the assumption
under which the Federal Reserve staff made its "Green Book"
forecast for inflation and real activity for the coming years. In both
1980 and 1982, inflation was expected to decline by about two percentage
points under the benchmark forecast. Second, in both 1980 and 1982, the
projections implied that a policy change (lowering money growth by 1.5
percent for three years) would have no effect on inflation within the
first year. Third, looking out two years after such a policy change, the
alternative Blue Book policy scenarios suggested substantial effects on
both unemployment and inflation of changing monetary policy. A shift
from strategy 1 to strategy 2 in 1980 was projected to produce a .9
percent decline in inflation in 1982 and a 2.3 percent increase in
unemployment in 1982. Seen in terms of a "menu of policy
choice," the unemployment cost in two years of a 1 percent
reduction in inflation was 2.3 percent. A 1982 shift from strategy 1 to
strategy 2 was predicted to have the same effect on inflation at a
two-year horizon, at an unemployment of 2.0 percent.
Proceeding further, we can set a lower bound on the perceived
unemployment cost of disinflation by cumulating the "deltas"
over the three-year period and viewing the result as the first part of a
transition to a 1.5 percent lower inflation rate. (28) From that
standpoint, in 1980 and 1982, the Fed's perception was that the
first three years of restrictive monetary policy would cost about 4
point years of unemployment to lower the inflation rate by 1.5 percent.
Thus, a 6.7 percent decline in the inflation rate was perceived to cost
no less than 18 point years of unemployment and it could have been a
good bit higher once fourth-year costs were included.
Overall, in 1980 and 1982, it seems that the Fed's perception
was that the disinflation would be at least twice as costly as the
cyclical unemployment that was actually experienced. The perceived cost
was not too much different across these years, although it was modestly
smaller in 1982, and it was in line with the consensus estimates of Okun
(1978). Accordingly, it does not seem that the Fed undertook the
disinflation because its research staff, at least, believed that the
costs would be small.
The Consolidation of Disinflation Gains
The reduction in inflation during the early 1980s had to be
followed up by a lengthy period of inflation fighting, as discussed in
Goodfriend (1993). In particular, upon taking over as chairman in 1987,
Alan Greenspan had to fight a series of inflation scares. Yet, by
1994-1995 it seemed that the United States had settled into a period of
low inflation (about 3 percent) and low unemployment (about 5 percent),
essentially returning to conditions that resembled those in the
mid-1950s, where we started our Phillips curve documentary.
6. IN THE AFTERMATH
The year 1996 saw two novel developments on the Phillips curve
front, which are closing snapshots: the completion of version 1 of a new
quarterly Federal Reserve Board macroeconometric model of the United
States and an explicit discussion of Phillips curve tradeoffs by the
FOMC.
The Model
The structure and results of large-scale models are notoriously
difficult to convey in a compact and coherent manner. In that regard,
the 1996 "Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United
States," edited by Brayton and Tinsley, is a remarkable document.
It provides the reader with a clear model-building vision and a set of
clean experiments that can be used to learn about the model.
The wage-price block of the new model combines the sort of
forward-looking price-setting and wage-setting specifications that are
standard in modern macroeconomic analysis, with a set of gradual
adjustment specifications of the variety that applied econometricians
have found useful for fitting data since the days of Fisher, Klein, and
Sargan. The specific modeling is in the tradition of the approach to
time series econometrics initiated by Sargan and refined by Hendry and
others.
For example, the price-level specification of the model contains a
long-run relationship that makes
[P *.sub.t] = .98 * ([W.sub.t] - [a.sub.t]) + .02 *
[P.sub.t.sup.[Florin]] - .003[u.sub.t],
so that the "equilibrium" price level strongly depends on
the gap between the log nominal wage rate (W) and productivity (a) with
weaker effects from the nominal energy fuel price
([P.sub.t.sup.[Florin]] ), consistent with factor share data. Further,
the unemployment rate has a small effect, via an effect on the desired
markup (the units of measurement imply that a 1 percent increase in
unemployment lowers the desired markup by .3 percent). The adjustment
dynamics indicate that inflation is high as the price level adjusts
gradually toward this target level, via
[P.sub.t] - [P.sub.[t-1]] = .10([P.sub.*[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-1]] ) +
.57[lags.sub.2] [[P.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-2]] ]
+.43[leads.sub.[infinity]] [[P*.sub.[t+1]] - [P *.sub.t].sup.e].
That is, there is a gradual elimination of 1 of the gap ([P
*.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-1]] ) each quarter, some additional
backward-looking adjustment terms with substantial weight, and
variations in the expected target. The requirement that the structural
lead and lag coefficients sum to one, along with similar restrictions in
the companion wage equation, means that the FRB/US model features no
long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.
Thus, the new model represented a blend of the Klein-Sargan
approach, with a new macroeconomic theory that stresses expectational
elements of pricing and other behavior. The new FRB/US model also had
common elements with a set of small, fully articulated dynamic models
then being developed in academia (King and Wolman [1996] and Yun
[1996]), which were early examples of the types of new macroeconomic
models explored elsewhere in this Economic Quarterly issue.
The frictions in the model are substantial, as Brayton and Tinsley
(1996) make clear, in that they apply to changes as well as levels. The
associated distributed lags and leads are lengthy, averaging 3.3
quarters for unanticipated shocks. Hence, there is a short-run Phillips
curve in the model that involves dynamics over many quarters. Figure 12
shows the response to a permanent decline in the inflation rate within
the FRB/US model, essentially obtained by shifting down the constant
term in an interest rate rule along Taylor (1993) lines.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
The FRB/US model can be solved under alternative assumptions about
expectation formation, with rational expectations being one
specification and a modern version of adaptive expectations being the
other. More precisely, the second specification is expectations based on
a vector-autoregression estimated from a model's data for a subset
of just three of that model's variables. The model implies a
gradual disinflation process as a result of the lags in the price and
wage specification, but the transition to the new lower inflation rate
is completed within about two years, although the real consequences are
present for several years. Overall, since the reported simulations are
in terms of an output gap, they cannot be directly compared to those
considered above. Yet a back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that
they are quite major but smaller than those experienced in the Volcker
period or in the MPS model discussed above. To see why, suppose that we
summarize the figure as indicating that an upper bound on the output
loss is a .5 percent output gap on average for 6 years; this is a 3
percent cumulative output loss. Suppose also that we use the same
Okun's Law coefficient of 2.5 that links unemployment to output
gaps as in the 1962 Economic Report. Then, the unemployment cost of a
permanent disinflation is about 1.2 point years of unemployment for each
point of inflation, a number that is in line with ratios reported by
Brayton, Tinsley, and collaborators. The FRB/US team also reported that
imperfect credibility of monetary policy actions can more than double
the unemployment cost of a disinflation.
A notable feature of the disinflation simulation displayed in
Figure 12 is that monetary policy initially works heavily through
expectational channels. On impact, at date 0, the long-term bond rate
drops dramatically (say, 80 basis points), while the federal funds rate moves by much less and only averages about a 40-basis-point decline over
the first year. By contrast, the MPS model simulations of a lower money
growth rate displayed nominal interest rate increases by an average of
over 300 basis points for the first three years as shown in Table 1.
Thus, the FRB/US model differs importantly from its MPS predecessor in
terms of other areas, notably the term structure of interest rates, in
ways that are important for monetary policy.
The Background to the Meeting
In 1996, the FOMC conducted a remarkable discussion of its long-run
policy goals, stimulated by earlier calls for an increased emphasis on
price stability by some of its members, as well as the adoption of
inflation-targeting systems by other countries around the world.
Notably, at a January 1995 meeting, Al Broaddus, the then-president of
the Richmond Fed, had called within the FOMC for a system of inflation
reports each year to accompany the Fed chairman's Humphrey-Hawkins
testimony. (29) Broaddus' suggestion was opposed by FRB Governor
Janet Yellen in January 1995, but the FOMC had agreed to continue the
discussion in the context of future meetings that preceded the
Humphrey-Hawkins testimony.
When the FOMC met in January 1996, the U.S. economy had been
experiencing low inflation and strong macroeconomic activity for some
time. In the first quarter of 1996, inflation was running at about 2
percent per year, with unemployment in the neighborhood of 5.5 percent.
Since 1980, the United States had experienced the major decline in
inflation described in the last section, during which unemployment had
ranged over 10 percent in the last quarter of 1982 and the last two
quarters of 1983. In the last year of Volcker's chairmanship and
during the first few years of Greenspan's, a rise in inflation had
taken place--from the 2 percent range in 1986 to about 4 percent in
1990--which had been accompanied by a decline in unemployment. (30)
Subsequently, during 1991 and 1992, there had been a rise in
unemployment while inflation fell back in the 2 percent range. Most
recently, from mid-1992 through the end of 1995, there had been about 2
percent inflation, while unemployment was between 5.5 and 6 percent.
These developments are shown in Figure 13, which is a
Phillips-style plot of unemployment and inflation during 1980 through
1996. Observations during the Volcker period are marked with a circle
(o) and those during the Greenspan period are marked with a diamond (*).
This figure captures the background to the FOMC's 1996 discussion.
The major disinflation is the first half-loop: an interval of declining
inflation and rising unemployment between 1980 and mid-1983, followed by
an interval of declining inflation and declining unemployment with
inflation reaching the 4 percent range by the second quarter of 1984.
Subsequently, there was a year in which inflation fell in the 2 percent
range, with little accompanying change in unemployment. The increase in
inflation between mid-1985 through 1989 was followed by a decline in
inflation to the 2 percent range during late 1991 and early 1993,
accompanied by increases in unemployment. In late 1993 through early
1995, unemployment fell sharply, with little change in inflation. Thus,
the late-Volcker and early-Greenspan years trace out a full clockwise loop, after the disinflation of 1980-1984. The negative association
between inflation and unemployment during the first stages of each of
these three episodes (one of increasing inflation and one of decreasing
inflation) corresponds to periods that FOMC members would have viewed as
reflecting the phenomena isolated by Phillips.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
The Meeting
At the time of the January 1996 meeting, there were two important
economic conditions that occupied the FOMC's attention. First,
there was a sense that key aspects of the U.S. economy were changing,
with the possibility of a "New Economy" based on computer and
Communications advances. Second, and most important for the meeting, the
inflation rate for personal consumption expenditures was running at
about a 3 percent rate and its "core" component--that stripped
of food, energy, and other volatile price components-was running at
about 2.5 percent, but staff forecasts suggested that it was poised to
rise to the 3 percent range as well. The strong real growth in the
economy, coupled with a decline in unemployment to the range of 5.5
percent, had led some FOMC members to express concerns about inflation.
In detailed prepared remarks, Governor Janet Yellen discussed a
cost-benefit approach to determining the optimal long-run rate of
inflation and the transition path. She noted that the Board's new
model indicated a cost of 2.5 point years of unemployment for every 1
percent decline in the long-run inflation rate, under imperfect
credibility. To warrant a reduction in inflation, she argued that such a
cost of permanently lower inflation had to be less than the discounted
value of a stream of future benefits. However, Yellen also returned to a
theme suggested by Phillips' original research, which was that
there could be particular costs to low rates of inflation. Citing
research by Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry (1996) which argued that
worker-resistance to nominal pay cuts produced a long-run Phillips curve
with a negative slope at low rates of inflation, Yellen also argued for
a positive rate of long-run inflation "to grease the wheels of the
labor market."
As they considered the appropriate long-run rate of inflation, the
FOMC decisionmakers took into account their perceived transition costs,
their sense of the benefits from permanently low inflation, and their
sense of the costs of permanently low inflation. There was diversity in
the views reflected in the statements of various members on each of
these topics. But, as Broaddus noted, there was a consensus that the
long-run inflation rate should not be higher than the current level of 3
percent. Broaddus and then-Cleveland Fed President Jerry Jordan stressed
the importance of explicit public discussion of inflation objectives as
a means of enhancing Fed credibility and thus lowering the cost of
further reductions in inflation.
The FOMC discussed how to define price stability as an objective of
monetary policy. Greenspan suggested that "price stability is that
state in which expected changes in the general price level do not
effectively alter business or household decisions," but Yellen
challenged him to translate that general statement into a specific
numerical value. He responded that "the number is zero, if
inflation is properly measured." Yellen said that she preferred 2
percent "imperfectly measured."
The FOMC settled on 2 percent inflation as an interim goal, with a
policy of deliberately moving toward that lower level. Presumably, some
members viewed it as the natural first step toward a lower ultimate
inflation objective, while others thought of it as an end point. On the
second day of the two-day meeting, Greenspan cautioned the committee
that the 2 percent objective was included within "the highly
confidential nature of what we talk about at an FOMC meeting." He
noted that "the discussion we had yesterday was exceptionally
interesting and important" but warned that "if the 2 percent
inflation figure gets out of this room, it is going to create more
problems for us than I think any of you might anticipate." He did
not elaborate on whether he was concerned about market or political
reactions to the inflation goal.
7. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
With a series of snapshots over a nearly 40-year period, this
article has reviewed the evolution of the Phillips curve in
macroeconomic policy analysis in the United States. During this period,
U.S. inflation rose dramatically, initially during a decade of
glittering economic performance and then further during an interval of
stagflation. The reversal of inflation beginning in the early 1980s was
associated with a major recession, although perhaps not as large a one
as policymakers and economists had feared.
The rise and fall of inflation brought about a major change in the
style of macroeconometric models that were used to evaluate policy
choices. The earliest versions of these models featured a substantial
long-run tradeoff consistent with the findings of Phillips over a
near-century of U.K. data. The subsequent evolution of models first
involved altering their wage-price block so that there was no long-run
tradeoff and then, later, a more comprehensive rational expectations
revision that included forward-looking wage and price-setting structured
so that there was no long-run tradeoff.
More generally, the rise and fall of inflation led monetary
policymakers to place greater weight on the role of expectations in
governing macroeconomic activity, with central banks working to extract
information in long-term interest rates about market expectations of
inflation. Toward the end of the historical period examined here, the
Federal Reserve System had decided to maintain a goal of a low, but
positive rate of inflation. Yet, it also chose not to communicate that
long-run target directly to the public. The decision to choose a
positive rate of inflation was traced, in part, to a concern about the
transitory unemployment costs of moving to a zero rate of inflation and
in part to a concern about high long-run costs of low inflation, in the
spirit of Phillips' analysis.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, George A., William R. Dickens, and George L. Perry. 1996.
"The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation." Brookings Papers on
Economics Activity 1: 1-76.
Brayton, Flint, and Peter C. Tinsley. 1996. "A Guide to
FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United States." FEDS Working
Paper 96-42.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr. 2004. "Macroeconomic Principles and
Monetary Policy." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 90 (Winter): 1-9.
Burns, Arthur F., and Wesley C. Mitchell. 1946. Measuring Business
Cycles. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Castle, Jennifer, and David F. Hendry. Forthcoming. "The
Long-Run Determinants of UK Wages, 1860-2004." Journal of
Macroeconomics: Advances in Historical Analyses.
Christ, Carl F. 1973. "The 1973 Report of the President's
Council of Economic Advisers: A Review." American Economic Review
63 (September): 515-26.
de Menil, G., and Enzler, J. 1972. "Prices and Wages in the
FR-MIT-PENN Econometric Model." In The Econometrics of Price
Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Federal
Reserve Board of Governors.
Duesenberry, James S., Otto Eckstein, and Gary Fromm. 1960. "A
Simulation of the United States Economy in Recession." Econometrica
28 (October): 749-809.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 1998. "The FOMC Meeting:
Developing a Policy Directive." In U.S. Monetary Policy and
Financial Markets. Available at
www.newyorkfed.org/education/addpub/monpol/.
Fellner, William. 1976. Towards a Reconstruction of Macroeconomics.
Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute.
Fisher, Irving. 1926. "A Statistical Relationship between
Unemployment and Price Changes." International Labor Review 47
(June): 785-92.
Friedman, Milton. 1968. "The Role of Monetary Policy."
American Economic Review 58 (January): 1-17.
Goodfriend, Marvin. 1993. "Interest Rate Policy and the
Inflation Scare Problem: 1979-1992." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 91 (Winter): 1-23.
Goodfriend, Marvin, and Robert G. King. 2005. "The Incredible
Volcker Disinflation." Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (July):
981-1015.
Gordon, Robert J. 1970. "The Recent Acceleration of Inflation
and Its Lessons for the Future." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1: 8-47.
Hetzel, Robert. 1998. "Arthur Burns and Inflation."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 84 (Winter): 21-44.
Hetzel, Robert. 2008. The Monetary Policy of the Federal Reserve: A
History. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Hymans, Saul H. 1972. "Prices and Price Behavior in Three U.S.
Econometric Models." In The Econometrics of Price Determination,
edited by Otto Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Board of
Governors, 309-24.
King, Robert G., and Alexander L. Wolman. 1996. "Inflation
Targeting in a St. Louis Model of the 21st Century." Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 78 (Fall): 83-107.
Klein, L. R., R. J. Ball, A. Hazelwood, and P. Vandome. 1961. An
Econometric Model of the United Kingdom. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1972a. "Econometric Testing of the
Natural Rate Hypothesis." In The Econometrics of Price
Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Federal
Reserve Board of Governors, 50-9.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1972b. "Expectations and the Neutrality
of Money." Journal of Economic Theory 4 (April): 103-24.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1976. "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A
Critique." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1
(January): 19-46.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2002. Macroeconomics, fifth edition. New York:
Worth Publishers.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1984. "Credibility and Monetary
Policy." In Proceedings. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
105-35.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1994. "Identification of
Inflation-Unemployment Tradeoffs in the 1970s a Comment."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 41 (December):
231-41.
Meltzer, Allan M. 1980. "The Case for Gradualism in Policies
to Reduce Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
April: 127-54.
Modigliani, Franco, and Lucas Papademos. 1975. "Targets for
Monetary Policy in the Coming Year." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 6: 141-65.
Muth, John F. 1960. "Optimal Properties of Exponentially Weighted Forecasts." Journal of the American Statistical
Association 55 (June): 299-306.
Muth, John F. 1961. "Rational Expectations and the Theory of
Price Movements." Econometrica 29 (July): 315-35.
Okun, Arthur M. 1962. "Potential GNP: Its Measurement and
Significance." In Journal of the American Statistical Association;
reprinted with slight changes in The Political Economy of Prosperity by
Arthur M. Okun. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Okun, Arthur M. 1978. "Efficient Disinflationary
Policies." American Economic Review 68 (May): 348-52.
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2003. "The Quest for Prosperity
without Inflation." Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (April):
633-63.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1967. "Phillips Curves, Expectations of
Inflation, and Optimal Inflation over Time." Economica 34 (August):
254-81.
Phillips, A. W. 1958. "The Relationship between Unemployment
and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom
1861-1957." Economica 25 (November): 283-99.
Poole, William. 1970. "Gradualism: A Mid-Course View."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 271-301.
Primiceri, Giorgio. 2006. "Why Inflation Rose and Fell:
Policymakers' Beliefs and U.S. Postwar Stabilization Policy."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (August): 867-901.
Samuelson, Paul A., and Robert M. Solow. 1961. "Analytical
Foundations of Anti-Inflation Policy." American Economic Review 50
(May): 177-94.
Sargan, John D. 1964. "Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom:
A Study in Econometric Methodology." In Econometric Analysis for
National Economic Planning, edited by P. E. Hart, G. Mills, and J. K.
Whitaker. London: Butterworth and Co. Ltd., 25-54; Reprinted as chapter
8 in Contributions to Econometrics: John Denis Sargan, edited by
Esfandiar Maasoumi, Cambridge University Press.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1971. "A Note on the Accelerationist
Controversy." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 3 (August):
721-25.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1981. "The Ends of Four Big
Inflations." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper 158
(May).
Sargent, Thomas J. 1999. The Conquest of American Inflation.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Solow, Robert M. 1969. Price Expectations and the Behavior of the
Price Level. Manchester, U.K.: Manchester University Press.
Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 1997.
"The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary Policy." The Journal of
Economic Perspectives 11 (Winter): 33-49.
Taylor, John B. 1993. "Discretion versus Policy Rules in
Practice." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39
(November): 195-214.
Tobin, James. 1980. "Stabilization Policy Ten Years
After." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 11:19-78.
Yun, Tack. 1996. "Nominal Price Rigidity, Money Supply
Endogeneity, and Business Cycles." Journal of Monetary Economics 37
(April): 345-70.
The author is affiliated with Boston University, National Bureau of
Economic Research, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Thanks to
Michael Dotsey, Andreas Hornstein, Mark Watson, and Alexander Wolman for
valuable comments. Devin Reilly helped with the figures. The views
expressed herein are the author's and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
rking@bu.edu.
(1) Phillips (1958. 284).
(2) Phillips' annual wage inflation observations are
effectively a two-period average of the inflation rate in the future
year and the current year.
(3) To explain the cyclical pattern around the long-run curve,
Phillips developed a theory in which wage inflation was affected
negatively both by the rate of change and level of unemployment. That
part of his analysis was less broadly taken up by subsequent
researchers, although there was a significant literature on
"Phillips loops" during the 1970s.
(4) As in Phillips, letting y be the wage inflation and x be
unemployment, the fitted curve took the form y = -.9 +
9.638[x.sup.-1.394], with the paremeters selected by a combination of
least-squares and trial-and-error (Phillips 1958. 285).
(5) Samuelson and Solow (1960) indicate that their study is based
on the data of Rees, which is most likely his 1961 monograph on real
wages in manufacturing, where the earliest data is 1890.
(6) All quotations in this paragraph are from Samuelson and Solow
(1961, 189).
(7) Samuelson and Solow (1961. 192).
(8) All quotations in this paragraph are from Samuelson and Solow
(1961, 191).
(9) All quotations in this paragraph are from Samuelson and Solow
(1961) page 193 except for the final one. which is from page 194.
(10) These results echoed the earlier findings of Fisher (1926) who
had, in fact, invented the concept of a distributed lag for the purpose
of empirical analysis of inflation and interest rates. More generally,
the estimation of wage-price blocks has provided the basis for many
advances in time series econometrics. In particular, Sargan (1964) used
the wage-price block of Klein et al. (1961) as the basis for an
investigation that was the starting point for the so-called London
School of Economics (LSE) approach to econometric dynamics. For a recent
study of the UK Phillips curve, using Sargan's work as its starting
point, see Castle and Hendry (Forthcoming).
(11) Sargan also investigated generalization of the first
specification to allow for additional lags of wage changes, [W.sub.t] -
[W.sub.[t-1]] = [lambda] [[W.sub.[t-1]] - [P.sub.[t-1]] -
[w.sub.[t-1].sup.e] + [[SIGMA].sub.[j=1].sup.J] [[delta].sub.j]
([W.sub.[t-j]] - [W.sub.[t-j-1]]) to enrich this dynamic adjustment
process toward equilibrium.
(12) Walter Heller was the chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisors from 1961-64. with the other members being Kermit Gordon and
James Tobin. The terminology "new economics" was widely used
at the time and apparently dates back to a 1947 volume by Seymour
Harris.
(13) As, for example, in the "Phillips plot without a Phillips
curve" of the 1969 Report, discussed further below. Presumably, the
economists at the CEA were not too interested in taking
"credit" for the effect of low unemployment on inflation,
while the economists at the Federal Reserve Bank (FRB) had a model that
featured the tradeoff and could not escape the connection.
(14) Note that de Menil and Enzler's (1972) experiment assumes
an immediate and permanent change in unemployment induced by
macroeconomic policies. Given the nature of the wage-price block in the
FMP model, it was conceptually feasible to simply change unemployment
and trace out the implications for wage and price inflation. However,
since changes in fiscal and monetary instruments had only a gradual
effect on aggregate demand and unemployment within the FMP and similar
models, responses to more standard policy changes were more complicated
and had gradual effects on both inflation and unemployment.
(15) There are several cosmetic differences with Phelps'
(1967, equation 3) specification. First, Phelps worked in continuous
time while the text equation is in discrete time. Second, Phelps'
specification is in terms of a general utilization variable rather than
unemployment. Third, Phelps worked with the expected return on money,
which is the negative of the expected inflation rate. Fourth, Phelps
employed a nonlinear (convex) specification of the link from utilization
to inflation rather than a linear one as in the text.
(16) In this expression, w* would be the "natural" real
wage, similar to the natural rate of unemployment, u*.
(17) The inflation process implies [[pi].sub.t] =
[rho][[pi].sub.[t-1]] +[e.sub.t] +[[eta].sub.t] -
[rho][[eta.sub.[t-1]].A "Wold representation" is [[pi].sub.t]
= [rho][[pi].sub.[t-1]] + [a.sub.t] -[rho](1 - [theta])[a.sub.[t-1]],
with [a.sub.t] a forecast error for [[pi].sub.t] relative to its own
past history. These two processes are observationally equivalent if they
imply the same restrictions on the variance and first-order
autocorrelation of [[pi].sub.t] - [rho][[pi].sub.t-1] (All other
autocovariances are zero.) Using the Wold representation, the forecast
is
[E.sub.[t-1]][[pi].sub.t] = [rho][[pi].sub.[t-1]] - [rho](1 -
[theta])[a.sub.[t-1]] = [rho][[pi].sub.[t-1]] - [rho(1 - [theta])
([[pi].sub.[t-1]] - [E.sub.[t-2]][[pi].sub.t]) =
[rho][[theta][[pi].sub.[t-1]] + (1 - [theta])
[E.sub.[t-2]][[pi].sub.[t-1]]]
as reported in the text. The covariance restrictions imply
var([a.sub.t]) = var([[eta].sub.t]) + [1/1+[[rho].sup.2] var [e.sub.t]
and [theta] = 1 - [var([[eta].sub.t])/var([a.sub.t]).
(18) In the original unnumbered figure early in the Modigliani and
Papademos (1975) article, the non-accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment is marked "NIRU," but Figure 9 follows the
now-standard acronym. It also corrects a typo in the labelling of the
vertical axis.
(19) Staiger, Stock, and Watson (1997) document the considerable
uncertainty surrounding estimates of the NAIRU.
(20) Gradualist policies were advocated by a range of economists
and policymakers. On this dimension, the monetarist economists of the
Shadow Open Market Committee (SOMC) shared some of the reservations of
their Keynesian counterparts. See Meltzer (1980) for a discussion of the
SOMC perspective on gradualism.
(21) Martin's February 26, 1969, testimony to Congress, quoted
in Hetzel (2008, 75).
(22) Bums 1957, p. 71, quoted in Hetzel (1998).
(23) Bums had played a leading role in the Council of Economic
Advisors during the Eisenhower administration and knew Nixon well. As
chairman of the Fed. he played an important role in administration
policy more broadly, including the mid-August 1971 meetings at Camp
David that formulated major changes in Nixon administration economic
policies.
(24) The sacrifice ratio is now perhaps more commonly described as
the output gap.
(25) Thus, Tobin uses the "natural rate" and the
"NAIRU" interchangeably when it comes to the analysis of
inflation. However, many Keynesian economists did not want to assume
that the level of real activity consistent with constant inflation was
an efficient level. As discussed above, Friedman had written that the
natural rate was to include "the actual structural characteristics
of the labor and commodity markets, including market imperfections,
stochastic variability in demands and supplies, the cost of gathering
information about job vacancies and labor availabilities, the costs of
mobility, and so on," but these conditions had sometimes been
ignored in the debate over the efficiency and inevitability of the
natural rate.
(26) To my mind, the role of imperfect credibility in the Phillips
curve in U.S. history remains an open, essential area of research at
present. Goodfriend and King (2005) argue that Volcker's actions
were based significantly on his perception that his policy actions were
not perfectly credible and that the nature of the disinflation dynamics
was also substantially influenced by imperfect credibility of policy.
(27) The Federal Reserve Bank of New York (1998, 123) describes the
preparation of "blue book" material, from which the Table 1
entries are taken, as follows: "The blue book provides the Board
staff's view of recent and prospective developments related to the
behavior of interest rates, bank reserves, and money. The blue books
written for the February and July meetings contain two extra sections to
assist the Committee in its preparation for the Humphrey-Hawkins
testimony. The first of these sections provides longer-term simulations,
covering the next five or six years. One of these simulations represents
a judgmental baseline, while two or three alternative forecasts use a
Board staff econometric model to derive the deviations from the
judgmental baseline under different policy approaches. Typically, at
least two scenarios are explored: one incorporates a policy path that is
designed to bring economic activity and employment close to their
perceived long-run potential paths fairly quickly, and another is
intended to achieve a more rapid approach to stable prices. The section
also offers estimates of how different assumptions about such factors as
fiscal policy, the equilibrium unemployment rate, or the speed of
adjustment to changed inflationary expectations would affect the
predicted outcome."
(28) It is a lower bound because the staff projection would
certainly have viewed unemployment as remaining high beyond the
three-year projection in the Blue Book; the unemployment [DELTA] is
highest in the third year.
(29) Broaddus (2004) used his proposals at this meeting as one of
three examples of his use of macroeconomic principles in practical
monetary policy discussion.
(30) At the time of Greenspan's appointment in August of 1987,
inflation was at 2.8 percent, while unemployment was 5.8 percent.