Exchange rates and business cycles across countries.
Duarte, Margarida ; Restuccia, Diego ; Waddle, Andrea L. 等
Modern theories of exchange rate determination typically imply a
close relationship between exchange rates and other macroeconomic variables such as output, consumption, and trade flows. The intuition behind this relationship is that, in most models, optimization of
consumption between domestic and foreign goods implies conditions that
equate the real exchange rate between two countries to marginal rates of
substitution in consumption. (1) Effectively, these conditions bind
exchange rates to other contemporaneous macroeconomic aggregates,
implying a close relationship between these variables. (2)
The relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic variables
implied by models of exchange rate determination is weakly supported by
the data. For instance, Baxter and Stockman (1989) document that the
exchange rate regime has little systematic effect on the business cycle
properties of macroeconomic aggregates other than nominal and real
exchange rates. Given that the magnitude of exchange rate volatility is
substantially higher under a flexible exchange rate regime than under a
fixed regime, this evidence suggests that the relationship between
exchange rates and other macroeconomic variables is weak. Flood and Rose
(1995) extend these findings and conclude that the exchange rate
"appears to have a life of its own." (3) In their assessment
of the major puzzles in international economics, Obstfeld and Rogoff
(2000) term the weak relationship between nominal exchange rates and
other macroeconomic aggregates found in the data as the "exchange
rate disconnect puzzle." (4) In fact, the evidence on the
relationship of exchange rates and macroeconomic aggregates is puzzling,
not only from the point of view of modern theories, but also from a more
intuitive point of view. For many economies, the nominal exchange rate is an important relative price, which affects a wide array of economic
transactions. Hence, it is surprising that exchange rates are weakly
correlated with real variables when they play an important role in
determining relative prices in goods markets.
In this article, we present empirical evidence on the business
cycle relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic aggregates
for a set of 36 countries. Our goal is to provide direct evidence on the
relationship between exchange rates and other macroeconomic variables
that potentially can be used to evaluate the implications of exchange
rate models. (5) Open-economy models typically restrict the world
economy to two large countries or to a small open economy which
interacts with the rest of the world. In reality, however, countries
interact with many other countries. As a result, it is not
straightforward comparing the implications of models with data. We
choose to study the relationship between a country's nominal and
real effective exchange rates and its domestic macroeconomic variables.
The effective exchange rates of a country are averages of the
country's bilateral exchange rates against its trading partners.
(6) We use effective exchange rates rather than bilateral rates because,
in our view, they provide a better indicator of their role in the
economy. Hence, the evidence presented in this article can provide
discipline to the implications of open-economy models that capture
realistic interactions among countries.
We construct a data set with quarterly data on real macroeconomic
aggregates and nominal and real effective exchange rates for 36
countries. We investigate the business cycle properties of effective
exchange rates and macroeconomic aggregates for each country in our set.
We find that in some developed economies, such as the United States,
nominal effective exchange rates exhibit no correlation with
macroeconomic aggregates such as output and consumption. However, we
find that this behavior is not pervasive across our set of economies. In
fact, we find that movements in the nominal effective exchange rate are
correlated with movements in other macroeconomic variables in many
economies, both developed and developing. Moreover, we find that the
contemporaneous cross-correlations between nominal exchange rates and
trade flows (exports and imports) are not negligible for the vast
majority of countries, including the United States. Finally, we find
that exchange rates tend to co-move with gross domestic product (GDP),
consumption, investment, and net exports more so in poorer countries.
We also relate the volatility of exchange rates to their
co-movement with macroeconomic aggregates and to business cycles. The
volatility of exchange rates is much larger in developing economies than
in developed countries. The substantial volatility of exchange rates in
developing countries is related to the larger volatility of output,
consumption, and investment in these countries. Moreover, the volatility
of exchange rates is positively associated with the level of co-movement
between exchange rates and other variables.
Our findings highlight important differences in the business cycle
properties of exchange rates and other variables across developed and
developing economies. These differences (both in terms of relative
volatilities and the cross-correlations of nominal exchange rates with
other aggregates) may reflect systematic differences in their economic
structures and/or in the nature of the shocks they face. Understanding
the differences in the properties of both exchange rate fluctuations and
business cycles between developed and developing economies is an
important area for further research.
This article is organized as follows. In the next section, we
describe the construction of the data set. Section 2 presents the main
findings about the correlation between exchange rates and other
macroeconomic variables across our sample of countries. In Section 3, we
relate the correlation of exchange rates and macroeconomic variables to
the volatility level of exchange rates and other standard business cycle
statistics. We conclude in Section 4.
1. DATA
We construct a data set with quarterly data on GDP, private
consumption, investment, exports, imports, and nominal and real
effective exchange rates for a set of 36 countries. The time period
varies across countries but all have data for at least ten years. Table
1 lists the countries included in our data set, the data sources, and
the sample period. (7) The column for data sources has three entries:
the first refers to the data source for GDP and its components, while
the second and third refer to the data source for the nominal and real
effective exchange rates. Following the income classification of the
World Bank for 1998, our sample of countries includes middle- and
high-income economies. We associate high-income countries with developed
economies and middle-income countries with developing economies.
Specifically, in our sample, 19 countries are developed economies and 17
countries are developing economies. (8)
The series for GDP and its components were collected from three
sources: International Financial Statistics (IFS), Haver Analytics (HA),
and the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL).
The series for investment is gross fixed-capital formation. Some data
sources do not provide seasonally adjusted data or data at constant
prices, or both. Where needed, we seasonally adjusted the series using
the X-12 ARIMA routine from the Census Bureau. When the series for GDP
and its components were not available at constant prices, they were
converted into real values using the GDP deflator. The series for net
exports is constructed as the ratio of the difference between real
exports and real imports to real GDP. Effective exchange rates were
collected from three sources: IFS, Global Insight (GI), and the Bank for
International Settlements (BIS). Both real and nominal effective
exchange rates are expressed in quarterly averages and an increase in
the exchange rate index reflects an appreciation of the currency. We
took the log of all series (except net exports) and applied the
Hodrick-Prescott filter (with smoothing parameter 1,600) to each series.
(9)
2. EXCHANGE RATES AND REAL AGGREGATES
In this section, we document the cyclical co-movement between
nominal effective exchange rates and real aggregates in our data set of
36 countries. We also document the relationship between nominal and real
exchange rates and the relationship between real exchange rates and
aggregate variables. We conclude this section by relating the degree of
co-movement between nominal exchange rates and other macroeconomic
variables with the degree of openness to trade and income in each
country.
Columns 1 to 6 of Table 2 report the cross-correlations between a
country's nominal effective exchange rate and GDP, consumption,
investment, trade flows, and net exports for all countries in our data
set. We note that the cross-correlations between nominal exchange rates
and output, consumption, investment, and net exports reported in this
table are low for a few developed economies, such as the United States,
Norway, and Austria. For instance, for the United States, these
cross-correlations of the nominal exchange rate are all below 10 percent
(in absolute value). These low correlations attest to a weak
relationship between exchange rates and other macro variables at the
business cycle frequency in these countries. However, cross-correlations
between nominal exchange rates and other macroeconomic aggregates close
to zero are not pervasive across our data set. In fact, for most
countries in our data set, nominal exchange rates exhibit substantial
cross-correlations with other macroeconomic variables at the business
cycle frequency. For example, for Spain, the cross-correlations of the
nominal effective exchange rate with GDP, consumption, and investment
are all above 40 percent; for the Netherlands, the cross-correlations
with imports and exports are both above 50 percent. Interestingly, even
for the United States, where the cross-correlations of the exchange rate
with GDP, consumption, investment, and net exports are close to zero,
the cross-correlations with exports and imports are both above 20
percent (in absolute value).
Another notable feature of Table 2 is the diversity in the way
nominal exchange rates co-move with the other macroeconomic variables
across countries. For instance, for many countries in our data set,
exchange rates co-move the most with trade flows (either exports or
imports). Such is the case in the United States, the United Kingdom,
Denmark, or the Netherlands, among others. But, in contrast, in some
other countries, exchange rates co-move the strongest with other
macroeconomic variables such as investment (for example, Finland or
Belgium) or output (Spain or Chile, for example). In addition, there is
not a systematic pattern for the sign of the co-movement of nominal
exchange rates with other macro aggregates across countries. This
diversity is an indication that countries are subject to different
shocks and/or that the same type of shocks propagate differently in the
economy. We conclude from the evidence in Table 2 that there is
substantial diversity in the way nominal exchange rates co-move with
other macroeconomic aggregates in our data set, and that for many
countries the degree of co-movement is not negligible.
The nominal effective exchange rate is a summary measure of the
external value of a country's currency, relative to the currencies
of its trading partners. The real effective exchange rate adjusts the
nominal rate for the relative price level across countries. Therefore, a
real exchange rate provides a measure of the purchasing power of a
currency abroad relative to its domestic purchasing power. It is,
therefore, of interest to know how real exchange rates co-move with
aggregate macroeconomic variables.
Column 7 of Table 2 reports the cross-correlations between nominal
and real exchange rates in our data set. These correlations are very
high (above 90 percent) for several countries such as Chile, Italy,
Malaysia, New Zealand, and the United States, among others. Most other
countries, however, exhibit a lower degree of correlation between
nominal and real effective exchange rates. To illustrate the
relationship between nominal and real exchange rates, we derive some
analytical expressions focusing on bilateral exchange rates. (10) For
bilateral exchange rates, the cross-correlation between (the log of)
nominal and real rates is related to the ratio of the standard deviation
of nominal and real exchange rates, [sigma](e)/[sigma](q), and the
cross-correlation between the nominal exchange rate and the price ratio,
[rho](e, pr), and is given by
[rho](e, q) = [[sigma](e)/[sigma](q)] + [rho](e,
pr)[[sigma](pr)/[sigma](q)].
This equation indicates that, for bilateral rates, we should expect
the cross-correlation between the nominal exchange rate and the price
ratio [rho](e, pr) to be close to zero when [rho](e, q) and
[sigma](e)/[sigma](q) are both approximately equal to one. (11) Note
that, in this case, a strong cross-correlation between nominal and real
exchange rates is associated with a weak co-movement between the nominal
exchange rate and the relative price across countries. In addition, we
should expect a stronger (negative) cross-correlation [rho](e, pr) when
the ratio [sigma](e)/[sigma](q) is larger than [rho](e, q). (12) In this
case, a weaker cross-correlation between nominal and real exchange rates
is associated with a stronger co-movement between the nominal exchange
rate and the relative price across countries.
Figure 1 plots the ratios of the standard deviation of nominal and
real effective exchange rates against the cross-correlations between
these two variables for all countries in our data set. We find that, for
many countries, both variables are close to one and that a ratio
[sigma](e)/[sigma](q) above one tends to be associated with a lower
cross-correlation between nominal and real exchange rates. Although this
figure uses data on effective exchange rates, we argue that it suggests
a negative relationship between the degree of co-movement of nominal and
real exchange rates and the degree of co-movement of nominal exchange
rates and relative price levels. That is, for countries that observe
lower correlations between nominal and real rates, movements in the
nominal exchange rate are more strongly associated with movements in
relative prices across countries (in particular, nominal depreciations
of a country's currency are associated with increases in the price
level of that country relative to the price level in other countries).
As is the case with nominal exchange rates, low cross-correlations
between real effective exchange rates and other macroeconomic variables
are not pervasive in our data set. Figure 2 plots the cross-correlation
of output with the nominal exchange rate on the x-axis and with the real
exchange rate on the y-axis. For most countries, the two correlations
are similar. A similar pattern holds for the cross-correlations of
nominal and real exchange rates with other macroeconomic aggregates (see
Figure 3). We conclude that in our data set, there is substantial
diversity in the way real exchange rates co-move with other macro
variables and that for many countries these correlations are not
negligible.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Two possible factors behind differences in the co-movement of
exchange rates with other variables across countries are the
economy's degree of openness and level of development. We now
investigate how these two factors relate to the co-movement of the
nominal exchange rate with other aggregate variables in our data set.
Exchange Rates and Openness
We construct a measure of the degree of openness of an economy as
[omega] [equivalent to] [x+m]/[2(y+m)], where y denotes GDP, x denotes
exports, and m denotes imports. This measure computes the weight of
trade relative to the sum of the value of goods produced and imported in
an economy. In this formula, the degree of openness of the economy is
restricted to between zero and one. The measure of openness is zero when
both exports and imports are zero, and it takes the value 0.5 when the
value of exports equals output and the value of domestic spending (on
consumption and investment) equals imports. The measure of trade
approaches one as output and domestic spending (on consumption and
investment) approach zero and the value of exports equals the value of
imports.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
We compute the average value of [omega] in the sample period of
each country using the unfiltered data. This measure varies between 10
and 50 percent in our data set. We find that the weight of trade (as
measured by [omega]) has a weak relationship with the cross-correlation
of nominal exchange rates and other macroeconomic aggregates. The
correlation coefficients of [omega] with the (absolute value of the)
cross-correlation between nominal exchange rates and GDP, consumption,
investment, exports, imports, and net exports are -0.13, 0.12, 0.03,
0.01, -0.18, and -0.10, respectively. (13) That is, in our data set,
factors other than the weight of trade in the economy are associated
with the degree of co-movement of nominal exchange rates with other
macro variables.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Exchange Rates and Wealth
Figure 4 plots the absolute value of the cross-correlation between
the nominal exchange rate and output against a measure of the
country's relative wealth. The wealth measure we use is average GDP
per capita relative to that of the United States between 1980 and 1985.
(14) There is a negative relationship between our wealth measure and the
absolute value of the cross-correlation between the nominal exchange
rate and GDP, with a correlation coefficient of -0.46. That is, poorer
countries tend to exhibit stronger cross-correlations between the
nominal exchange rate and GDP than do richer countries.
Poorer countries also tend to have stronger cross-correlations
between the nominal exchange rate and consumption, investment, and the
ratio of net exports to GDP. The correlation coefficients between the
absolute value of each of these three series and our measure of wealth
are -0.41, -0.39, and -0.55. The cross-correlation of the nominal
exchange rate and exports tends to vary positively with wealth
(correlation coefficient of 0.47), while the cross-correlation with
imports does not vary systematically with wealth in our data set
(correlation coefficient of 0.08).
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
We obtain a similar characterization of the relationship between
the degree of co-movement of exchange rates with the economy and wealth
when we aggregate countries into a group of developed economies and a
group of developing economies. Table 3 reports the average
cross-correlations of nominal exchange rates across developed and
developing economies. The standard error is reported in parentheses. As
expected, the cross-correlations of the nominal exchange rate are
higher, on average, in developing economies than in developed economies,
particularly with respect to output, consumption, investment, and net
exports. For example, the average cross-correlation of the nominal
exchange rate with output across developing countries is 13 times that
of the United States and the average cross-correlation of the nominal
exchange rate with investment across developing countries is 18 times
that of the United States.
We should note that several countries in our data set experienced
currency crises during the sample period covered. These episodes are
characterized by sharp depreciations of the currency that are typically
associated with sharp decreases in output, consumption, investment, and
a current account reversal. Moreover, in our data set, all currency
crises occur in developing economies. We emphasize results for the data
set that include currency crises since we do not discriminate across
different sources of volatility across countries. Nevertheless, we check
whether the relationship between the co-movement of exchange rates and
wealth reported previously depends on the occurrence of currency crises
in our sample. To this end, we identify all episodes in which the
nominal effective exchange rate fell by more than 35 percent within one
year. From these episodes, we eliminate from our data set the entire
time series for Argentina, Brazil, Ecuador, Malaysia, and Thailand
because currency crises occurred in the middle of the sample period for
these countries, and the remaining time series was less than ten years
long. We reduce the sample period for Mexico, Philippines, South Africa,
and Uruguay because currency crises occurred either at the beginning or
end of the sample period for these countries, and the reduced sample
period was at least ten years long. In this restricted data set, the
cross-correlation of the nominal exchange rate with other variables
tends to vary with wealth, albeit less than in the original data set.
For example, the correlation coefficients between wealth and the
cross-correlation of nominal exchange rates with output, consumption,
and net exports are -0.24, -0.20, and -0.42. Thus, we conclude that the
relationship between wealth and the co-movement of nominal exchange
rates with other variables is also present when we restrict the data to
exclude currency crises.
3. EXCHANGE RATES AND BUSINESS CYCLES
We have focused on the contemporaneous business cycle movements
between exchange rates and other macroeconomic variables across
countries. In this section, we document the level of fluctuations of
exchange rates across countries and relate these observations to the
correlation of exchange rates with other macroeconomic variables and the
level of business cycle fluctuations of macroeconomic aggregates.
Table 4 reports business cycle statistics for all countries in our
sample and Table 5 reports the averages of those statistics across
developed and developing economies (standard errors are reported in
parentheses). One remarkable feature of exchange rate movements across
countries is that poorer countries tend to observe much larger
fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate than do richer countries (see
Figure 5). For instance, in our panel data, the average absolute
volatility of the nominal exchange rate is 4 percent across developed
countries and more than twice that rate in developing countries, 9.5
percent. Among the developing countries, the highest fluctuations in the
exchange rate are observed by Brazil (21.2 percent), Argentina (20.7
percent), Ecuador (17.6 percent), and Uruguay (13.2 percent). The
volatility of exchange rates in these countries is substantially larger
than the average of 4 percent in developed countries. The highest
fluctuations in exchange rates among the developed countries are
observed by Japan (7.6 percent), Australia (6.3 percent), and the United
States (5.2 percent). Developing countries also tend to observe larger
fluctuations in the real exchange rate relative to developed countries.
(15) However, we find that for lower levels of absolute volatility,
nominal and real rates tend to exhibit similar levels of volatility,
while for higher levels of absolute nominal volatility, real exchange
rates tend to be substantially less volatile than nominal rates (see
Figure 6). Therefore, in developed economies, nominal and real exchange
rates exhibit similar levels of absolute volatility, and in developing
countries the volatility of real exchange rates is, on average, lower
than the volatility of the nominal exchange rate.
The volatility of exchange rates relates systematically to the
volatility of other macroeconomic variables. In addition to the higher
volatility of exchange rates, poorer countries also tend to present more
volatile business cycles with larger fluctuations in output,
consumption, investment, trade flows, and net exports. The average
absolute volatility of GDP is 2.5 percent in developing countries and
1.4 percent in developed countries. Relative to GDP, the volatility of
consumption and investment is higher in developing countries than in
developed economies. (16) It is interesting to note that, relative to
GDP, the volatility of the real exchange rate is about the same in
developed and developing countries (2.9 and 2.8, respectively). This
finding is consistent with the fact that developing countries tend to
have more volatile nominal exchange rates and that, as we saw
previously, real exchange rates tend to be substantially less volatile
than nominal rates for these countries.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
We relate the absolute volatility of exchange rates to the
correlation of exchange rates and macroeconomic aggregates at the
business cycle frequency. Figure 7 documents this relationship for GDP,
where we separated developed and developing economies into two panels.
The correlation coefficient between the two variables is 43 percent for
all economies, 33 percent among developed economies, and 25 percent
among developing economies. (17) A similar correlation emerges for other
macroeconomic variables: 48 percent for net exports, 35 percent for
consumption, and 32 percent for investment.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The differences in international business cycles across developed
and developing economies (both in terms of relative volatilities and the
cross-correlations of nominal exchange rates with other aggregates) may
reflect systematic differences in their economic structures and/or in
the nature of the shocks they face. For instance, Da Rocha and Restuccia
(2006) study the business cycle implications of countries that have
different economic structures but face the same sectoral shocks. In
particular, these authors study economies that differ in the relative
importance of agriculture in the economy. Da Rocha and Restuccia (2006)
show that differences in the share of agriculture in the economy can
account for a large portion of the differences in business cycle
statistics across countries. (18) An alternative possibility is that
countries face different shocks. Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) abstract
from differences in the economic structure across countries and instead
study differences in the nature of exogenous real shocks between
emerging and developed economies. In particular, Aguiar and Gopinath
(2007) find that emerging economies face shocks to the growth rate of
total factor productivity, while developed economies face shocks to the
level of total factor productivity. Using the same economic framework in
which these different shocks propagate in the economy, Aguiar and
Gopinath (2007) find that differences in the nature of shocks account
for a large portion of the business cycle differences across emerging
and developed economies. Understanding the differences in both exchange
rate fluctuations and business cycles between developed and developing
economies is an important area for further research.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
4. CONCLUSION
We documented the cyclical behavior of exchange rates and real
macroeconomic aggregates for 36 economies. While in some economies (such
as the United States), contemporaneous business cycle movements in the
exchange rate are not correlated with movements in other macroeconomic
aggregates, this behavior is not pervasive across all economies in our
sample. Moreover, we found that the cross-correlations between nominal
effective exchange rates and trade flows (exports and imports) are not
negligible for the vast majority of countries, including the United
States. The volatility of exchange rates is more than twice as large in
developing economies than in developed economies, and we found this
volatility to be related to standard business cycle properties and the
level of co-movement with other macroeconomic aggregates.
In this article, we studied direct evidence on exchange rates and
other aggregate variables and found that negligible cross-correlations
between these variables are not pervasive in our data set. In contrast,
Baxter and Stockman (1989) and Flood and Rose (1995) use evidence on the
business cycle properties of macroeconomic aggregates across exchange
rate regimes and conclude that the relationship between exchange rates
and other macroeconomic aggregates is weak. Reconciling our findings
with those in Baxter and Stockman (1989) and Flood and Rose (1995)
remains an open question.
REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath. 2007. "Emerging Market
Business Cycles: The Cycle is the Trend." Journal of Political
Economy 115 (1): 69-102.
Baxter, Marianne, and Alan C. Stockman. 1989. "Business Cycles
and the Exchange-Rate Regime: Some International Evidence." Journal
of Monetary Economics 23 (3): 377-400.
Chari, V. V., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Ellen R. McGrattan. 2002.
"Can Sticky Price Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Real
Exchange Rates?" Review of Economic Studies 69 (3): 533-63.
Conesa, Juan, Carlos Diaz-Moreno, and Jose Galdon-Sanchez. 2002.
"Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Participation Rates and
Aggregate Fluctuations." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
26 (2): 333-45.
Da Rocha, Jose M., and Diego Restuccia. 2006. "The Role of
Agriculture in Aggregate Business Cycles." Review of Economic
Dynamics 9 (3): 455-82.
Devereux, Michael, and Charles Engel. 2002. "Exchange Rate
Pass-Through, Exchange Rate Variability, and Exchange Rate
Disconnect." Journal of Monetary Economics 49 (5): 913-40.
Duarte, Margarida. 2003. "Why Don't Macroeconomic
Quantities Respond to Exchange Rate Variability?" Journal of
Monetary Economics 50 (4): 889-913.
Duarte, Margarida, and Alan C. Stockman. 2005. "Rational
Speculation and Exchange Rates." Journal of Monetary Economics 52
(1): 3-29.
Flood, Robert, and Andrew Rose. 1995. "Fixing Exchange Rates:
A Virtual Quest for Fundamentals." Journal of Monetary Economics 36
(1): 3-37.
Hausmann, Ricardo, Ugo Panizza, and Roberto Rigobon. 2006.
"The Long-Run Volatility Puzzle of the Real Exchange Rate."
Journal of International Money and Finance 25 (1): 93-124.
Heston, Alan, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten. 2002. PennWorld
Table Version 6.1. Center for International Comparisons at the
University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Available at:
http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu. (accessed on May 17, 2006).
Kollmann, Robert. 2001. "The Exchange Rate in a
Dynamic-Optimizing Business Cycle Model with Nominal Rigidities: A
Quantitative Investigation." Journal of International Economics 55
(2): 243-62.
Lucas, Robert. 1982. "Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a
Two-Country World." Journal of Monetary Economics 10 (3): 335-59.
Meese, Richard, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1983. "Empirical Exchange
Rate Models of the Seventies: Are Any Fit to Survive?" Journal of
International Economics 14 (1-2): 3-24.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. "Exchange Rate
Dynamics Redux." Journal of Political Economy 103 (3): 624-60.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 2000. "The Six Major
Puzzles in International Macroeconomics: Is There a Common Cause?"
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, eds. Ben Bernanke and Kenneth
Rogoff. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press: 339-90.
Stockman, Alan C. 1980. "A Theory of Exchange Rate
Determination." Journal of Political Economy 88 (4): 673-98.
Stockman, Alan C. 1987. "The Equilibrium Approach to Exchange
Rates." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 73 (2):
12-29.
Stockman, Alan C. 1998. "New Evidence Connecting Exchange
Rates to Business Cycles." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 84 (2): 73-89.
We are grateful to Juan Carlos Hatchondo, Brian Minton, John
Walter, and John Weinberg for comments and suggestions. All errors are
our own. This article was written while Margarida Duarte and Diego
Restuccia were affiliated with the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
They are currently professors in the Department of Economics at the
University of Toronto. The views expressed in this article are those of
the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
margarida.duarte@utoronto.ca, diego.restuccia@utoronto.ca, and
andrea.waddle@rich.frb.org.
(1) These conditions are central to the equilibrium approach of
exchange rates. See, for instance, Stockman (1980, 1987) and Lucas
(1982).
(2) Another condition present in many exchange rate models equates
marginal rates of substitution of aggregate consumption across countries
to the real exchange rate (optimal risk sharing across countries),
implying a close relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic
aggregates (see, for instance, Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan 2002).
Nevertheless, the exact relationship between exchange rates and other
macroeconomic variables implied by exchange rate models depends on the
details of the model. See, for instance, Stockman (1987) and Obstfeld
and Rogoff (1995) for an analysis of two benchmark models and Stockman
(1998) for a general discussion. For the implications of quantitative
models, see, for instance, Kollmann (2001) and Chari, Kehoe, and
McGrattan (2002).
(3) The difficulty in forecasting exchange rates using standard
macroeconomic exchange rate models is also well known. See Meese and
Rogoff (1983), who show that a simple random-walk model of exchange
rates forecasts as well as do alternative standard macroeconomic
exchange rate models.
(4) See Devereux and Engel (2002), Duarte (2003), and Duarte and
Stockman (2005) for models that address the exchange rate disconnect
puzzle.
(5) Stockman (1998) provides direct evidence on the relationship
between bilateral exchange rates and the relative output of the two
countries.
(6) The nominal effective exchange rate of a country is defined as
a geometric-weighted average of the bilateral nominal exchange rates of
the country's currency against the currencies of its trading
partners. The real effective exchange rate is defined as a
geometric-weighted average of the price level of the country relative to
that of each trading partner, expressed in a common currency.
(7) We ended the sample period in 1998:Q4 for the European
countries in our data set that adopted the euro in 1999.
(8) The set of developed economies includes Australia, Austria,
Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Hong Kong, Italy, Japan, the
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,
the United Kingdom, and the United States. The set of developing
economies includes Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa
Rica, Ecuador, Hungary, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Poland, South
Africa, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey, and Uruguay.
(9) The Hodrick-Prescott filter is used to obtain the cyclical
component of each time series, that is, fluctuations about trend.
(10) In logs, the bilateral real exchange rate between countries A
and B is defined as [q.sub.B,A] [equivalent to] [e.sub.B,A] + pr, where
[e.sub.B,A] denotes the log of the nominal exchange rate between the
currencies of countries A and B (expressed as the number of currency
units of country B per unit of currency of country A) and pr denotes the
log of the consumer price level in country A relative to that of country
B.
(11) Intuitively, changes in the price ratio are small and changes
in the real exchange rate closely track changes in the nominal exchange
rate (i.e., the cross-correlation between nominal and real exchange
rates is close to one).
(12) When the ratio of the standard deviation of nominal to real
exchange rates is larger than the correlation of nominal and real
exchange rates, changes in the real exchange rate do not track changes
in the nominal rate as well because nominal exchange rates are
negatively correlated with the price ratio across countries.
(13) We use the absolute value as we are interested in the
distinction between a weak relationship of exchange rates with other
macroeconomic variables versus a strong relationship (positive or
negative). These results are similar to those obtained when the openness
measure is given by the ratio (x + m)/y.
(14) We use data on PPP-adjusted GDP per capita, obtained from the
Penn World Table Version 6.1 (see Heston, Summers, and Aten 2002).
(15) Hausmann, Panizza, and Rigobon (2006) report this fact using
annual data.
(16) For related evidence, see Aguiar and Gopinath (2007).
(17) The relationship between exchange rate volatility and the
co-movement of the nominal exchange rate and other macroeconomic
variables does not depend on the occurrence of currency crises in our
data set. For the reduced sample that excludes currency crises
(described in the previous section), we find that the correlation
coefficients between [sigma](e) and the absolute value of [rho](e, y)
are 35 percent for all economies, 33 percent for developed economies,
and 34 percent for developing economies.
(18) See also Conesa, Diaz-Moreno, and Galdon-Sanchez (2002) for a
study in which economies differ in the size of the informal sector.
Table 1 Data Sources
Country Sources Sample Period
Argentina HA, GI, BIS 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
Australia IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-2005:Q4
Austria IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-1998:Q4
Belgium IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-1998:Q4
Bolivia HA, IFS, IFS 1990:Q1-2005:Q4
Brazil CEPAL, GI, BIS 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
Canada IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-2005:Q4
Chile IFS, IFS, IFS 1996:Q1-2005:Q4
Colombia CEPAL, IFS, IFS 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
Costa Rica CEPAL, IFS, IFS 1991:Q1-2005:Q4
Denmark IFS, IFS, IFS 1977:Q1-2005:Q4
Ecuador HA, IFS, IFS 1990:Q1-2005:Q4
Finland IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-1998:Q4
France IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-1998:Q4
Hong Kong HA, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-2005:Q4
Hungary HA, IFS, IFS 1995:Q1-2005:Q4
Italy IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-1998:Q4
Japan IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-2005:Q4
Malaysia IFS, IFS, IFS 1991:Q1-2005:Q4
Mexico CEPAL, GI, BIS 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
the Netherlands IFS, IFS, IFS 1977:Q1-1998:Q4
New Zealand IFS, IFS, IFS 1987:Q2-2005:Q4
Norway IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-2005:Q4
Philippines HA, IFS, IFS 1981:Q1-2005:Q4
Poland IFS, IFS, IFS 1995:Q1-2005:Q4
Portugal IFS, IFS, IFS 1988:Q1-1998:Q4
South Africa IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-2005:Q4
Spain IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-1998:Q4
Sweden IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-2005:Q4
Switzerland IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q1-2005:Q4
Taiwan HA, GI, GI 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
Thailand HA, GI, BIS 1994:Q1-2005:Q4
Turkey HA, GI, GI 1987:Q1-2002:Q1
United Kingdom IFS, IFS, IFS 1975:Q2-2005:Q1
United States IFS, IFS, IFS 1980:Q1-2005:Q4
Uruguay CEPAL, IFS, IFS 1988:Q1-2005:Q4
Notes: BIS -- Bank for International Settlements; CEPAL -- Economic
Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean; GI -- Global Insight;
HA -- Haver Analytics; IFS -- International Financial Statistics.
Table 2 Cross-Correlations of Nominal Exchange Rates
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Country [rho](e,y) [rho](e,c) [rho](e,I) [rho](e,x)
Argentina 0.50 0.58 0.54 0.12
Australia 0.20 -0.24 0.22 -0.46
Austria -0.02 -0.08 -0.12 -0.55
Belgium 0.04 0.25 -0.27 0.15
Bolivia -0.26 -0.23 -0.43 0.14
Brazil -0.29 -0.19 -0.06 -0.44
Canada -0.15 -0.33 0.03 -0.39
Chile 0.47 0.20 0.17 -0.12
Colombia 0.38 0.44 0.23 0.11
Costa Rica 0.09 0.47 0.23 -0.31
Denmark 0.18 0.32 0.31 -0.65
Ecuador 0.63 0.69 0.56 -0.12
Finland 0.50 0.36 0.64 -0.24
France -0.31 -0.06 -0.03 -0.68
Hong Kong -0.19 -0.12 -0.03 -0.32
Hungary 0.18 0.55 -0.19 -0.58
Italy 0.08 0.10 0.29 -0.67
Japan -0.34 -0.35 -0.26 -0.64
Malaysia 0.54 0.76 0.65 -0.44
Mexico 0.71 0.82 0.75 -0.46
the Netherlands -0.17 0.09 -0.05 -0.69
New Zealand 0.54 0.52 0.47 -0.68
Norway -0.16 0.00 0.09 0.02
Philippines 0.47 0.22 0.43 0.14
Poland -0.40 -0.23 -0.31 -0.53
Portugal 0.14 0.15 0.16 -0.40
South Africa 0.22 0.13 0.13 -0.27
Spain 0.50 0.43 0.48 -0.28
Sweden 0.12 -0.08 0.28 -0.49
Switzerland -0.37 -0.43 -0.23 -0.58
Taiwan 0.18 0.20 0.07 0.20
Thailand 0.55 0.58 0.58 -0.28
Turkey 0.57 0.61 0.58 -0.28
United Kingdom -0.19 -0.12 0.03 -0.55
United States -0.03 -0.06 -0.02 -0.29
Uruguay 0.14 0.14 0.17 0.22
(5) (6) (7)
Country [rho](e,m) [rho](e,nx/y) [rho](e,q)
Argentina 0.66 -0.64 0.94
Australia -0.19 -0.24 0.97
Austria -0.39 -0.07 0.89
Belgium 0.16 -0.02 0.91
Bolivia -0.33 0.36 -0.21
Brazil 0.03 -0.44 0.22
Canada -0.42 0.11 0.79
Chile -0.06 0.01 0.99
Colombia 0.50 -0.45 0.97
Costa Rica 0.07 -0.32 0.54
Denmark -0.52 -0.21 0.95
Ecuador 0.54 -0.49 0.75
Finland 0.07 -0.30 0.78
France -0.58 -0.12 0.96
Hong Kong -0.34 0.03 0.74
Hungary -0.28 -0.27 0.79
Italy -0.39 -0.32 0.97
Japan -0.59 0.17 0.96
Malaysia 0.08 -0.63 0.99
Mexico 0.72 -0.91 0.94
the Netherlands -0.56 -0.37 0.95
New Zealand -0.54 -0.19 0.99
Norway 0.07 -0.09 0.87
Philippines 0.36 -0.23 0.65
Poland -0.69 0.49 0.93
Portugal -0.16 -0.27 0.91
South Africa -0.06 -0.18 0.90
Spain 0.17 -0.38 0.93
Sweden -0.42 -0.16 0.96
Switzerland -0.49 0.09 0.97
Taiwan 0.10 0.11 0.68
Thailand 0.55 -0.72 0.96
Turkey 0.65 -0.69 0.86
United Kingdom -0.57 0.24 0.93
United States -0.23 0.04 0.95
Uruguay 0.19 -0.08 0.56
Notes: [rho](x, y) -- cross-correlation between x and y; e -- nominal
effective exchange rate; y -- GDP; c -- consumption; I -- investment;
x -- exports; m -- imports; nx -- net exports; q -- real effective
exchange rate.
Table 3 Developed Versus Developing Countries
Developed Economies Developing Economies
[rho](e, y) 0.22 (0.04) 0.39 (0.05)
[rho](e, c) 0.22 (0.04) 0.41 (0.06)
[rho](e, I) 0.21 (0.04) 0.36 (0.05)
[rho](e, x) 0.46 (0.05) 0.28 (0.04)
[rho](e, m) 0.36 (0.04) 0.35 (0.06)
[rho](e, nx/y) 0.18 (0.03) 0.41 (0.06)
[rho](e, q) 0.92 (0.02) 0.76 (0.06)
Notes: See Table 2.
Table 4 Exchange Rates and Business Cycles
Country [sigma](e) [sigma](y) [sigma](nx/y)
Argentina 20.7 5.0 1.9
Australia 6.3 1.4 1.0
Austria 1.8 1.1 1.8
Belgium 3.2 1.3 1.2
Bolivia 8.5 1.3 2.6
Brazil 21.2 1.6 0.8
Canada 3.5 1.5 0.9
Chile 4.8 1.7 1.9
Colombia 6.2 1.9 1.7
Costa Rica 4.1 2.4 4.1
Denmark 2.4 1.5 1.0
Ecuador 17.6 2.1 4.0
Finland 4.8 2.3 1.6
France 2.5 0.8 0.6
Hong Kong 4.7 2.8 1.7
Hungary 3.4 1.0 2.2
Italy 4.0 1.2 0.9
Japan 7.6 1.2 0.5
Malaysia 5.7 2.9 4.7
Mexico 11.1 2.6 1.9
the Netherlands 2.7 1.3 1.1
New Zealand 5.3 1.4 1.3
Norway 2.5 1.7 3.4
Philippines 6.7 2.8 2.4
Poland 5.2 2.0 1.0
Portugal 4.7 1.7 2.4
South Africa 11.7 1.7 2.6
Spain 3.6 1.3 1.0
Sweden 4.3 1.4 0.9
Switzerland 3.8 1.3 1.0
Taiwan 2.9 1.7 1.5
Thailand 6.7 3.8 4.2
Turkey 11.9 3.5 3.3
United Kingdom 4.8 1.4 0.9
United States 5.2 1.3 0.4
Uruguay 13.2 4.1 2.8
Relative to [sigma](y)
Country [sigma](c) [sigma](I) [sigma](m)
Argentina 1.15 3.29 4.09
Australia 0.65 3.84 3.70
Austria 1.50 3.29 4.31
Belgium 0.89 3.34 3.70
Bolivia 1.24 8.81 6.70
Brazil 1.57 3.82 6.26
Canada 0.81 3.29 3.65
Chile 1.13 4.34 3.49
Colombia 1.06 6.61 4.48
Costa Rica 0.67 3.35 3.22
Denmark 1.18 3.89 3.20
Ecuador 1.11 3.98 4.61
Finland 0.65 3.56 3.05
France 1.42 3.82 5.68
Hong Kong 0.99 1.94 1.76
Hungary 2.27 9.03 4.33
Italy 0.99 2.93 4.91
Japan 0.83 2.70 8.41
Malaysia 1.60 4.61 2.38
Mexico 1.21 3.69 2.95
the Netherlands 1.66 3.50 3.85
New Zealand 1.00 4.31 3.29
Norway 1.87 4.57 3.50
Philippines 0.43 5.11 3.04
Poland 1.27 3.46 3.61
Portugal 2.29 5.17 4.39
South Africa 1.57 3.56 5.11
Spain 1.06 3.97 4.03
Sweden 0.98 4.04 3.96
Switzerland 0.70 3.97 4.04
Taiwan 0.69 4.30 3.38
Thailand 1.07 3.82 2.62
Turkey 1.11 2.91 3.43
United Kingdom 1.11 3.44 4.15
United States 0.81 2.75 3.70
Uruguay 1.49 3.30 2.54
Notes: [sigma](x) -- standard deviation of x. See also Table 2.
Table 5 Business Cycles Across Developed and Developing Economies
Developed Economies Developing Economies
[sigma](e) 3.9 (0.35) 9.5 (1.42)
[sigma](q) 4.0 (0.37) 6.4 (0.74)
[sigma](y) 1.4 (0,10) 2.5 (0.26)
[sigma](nx/y) 1.2 (0.15) 2.6 (0.28)
[sigma](c)/[sigma](y) 1.0 (0.07) 1.2 (0.10)
[sigma](I)/[sigma](y) 3.5 (0.15) 4.6 (0.45)
[sigma](m)/[sigma](y) 4.0 (0.30) 3.9 (0.30)
Notes: See Table 2.