A Taylor rule and the Greenspan era.
Mehra, Yash P. ; Minton, Brian D.
There is considerable interest in determining whether monetary
policy actions taken by the Federal Reserve under Chairman Alan
Greenspan can be summarized by a Taylor rule. The original Taylor rule
relates the federal funds rate target to two economic variables: lagged
inflation and the output gap, with the actual federal funds rate
completely adjusting to the target in each period (Taylor 1993). (1) The
later assumption of complete adjustment has often been interpreted as
indicating the policy rule is "non-inertial," or the Federal
Reserve does not smooth interest rates. Inflation in the original Taylor
rule is measured by the behavior of the GDP deflator and the output gap
is the deviation of the log of real output from a linear trend. Taylor
(1993) shows that from 1987 to 1992 policy actions did not differ
significantly from prescriptions of this simple rule. Hence, according
to the original Taylor rule, the Federal Reserve, at least during the
early part of the Greenspan era, was backward looking, focused on
headline inflation, and followed a non-inertial policy rule.
Recent research, however, suggests a different picture of the
Federal Reserve under Chairman Greenspan. English, Nelson, and Sack
(2002) present evidence that indicates policy actions during the
Greenspan period are better explained by an "inertial" Taylor
rule reflecting the presence of interest rate smoothing. (2) Blinder and
Reis (2005) state that the Greenspan Fed focused on a "core"
measure of inflation in adjusting its federal funds rate target.
Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2000), among others, have shown that a
forward-looking Taylor rule that relates the current funds rate target
to "expected" inflation and output developments appears to fit
the data quite well over the period spanning the tenures of Chairmen
Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan. Orphanides (2001) argues that policy
evaluations using policy rules estimated with the final revised data may
be misleading.
This article estimates a Taylor rule that address three key
features of the Greenspan period highlighted in recent research: the
Federal Reserve under Greenspan was forward looking, focused on core
inflation, and smoothed interest rates. Furthermore, this article uses
the real-time data for economic variables and investigates whether
results based on the final, revised data change when the real-time data
are used. We also examine whether the use of real-time data leads to a
better explanation of policy actions during the Greenspan period.
A Taylor rule incorporating the above-noted three features is shown
below in equation (1.3).
[FR*.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t,j.sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y](ln [y.sub.t,k]
- ln [y*.sub.t,k]), (1.1)
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]) [FR*.sub.t] +
[v.sub.t], (1.2)
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t,j.sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y] (ln [y.sub.t,k]
- ln[y*.sub.t,k])} + [v.sub.t], (1.3)
where [FR.sub.t] is the actual federal funds rate, [FR*.sub.t] is
the federal funds rate target, [[pi].sub.t,j.sup.c] is the j-period
ahead forecast of core inflation made at time t, ln y is the log of
actual output, ln y* is the log of potential output, and [v.sub.t] is
the disturbance term. Thus, the term (ln [y.sub.t,k] - ln [y*.sub.t,k])
is the k-period ahead forecast of the output gap. Equation (1.1) relates
the federal funds rate target to expected values of two economic
fundamentals: core inflation and the output gap. The funds rate target
is hereafter called the policy rate. The coefficients [[alpha].sub.[pi]]
and [[alpha].sub.y] measure the long-term responses of the funds rate
target to the expected inflation and the output gap. They are assumed to
be positively signed, indicating that the Federal Reserve raises its
funds rate target if inflation rises and/or the output gap is positive.
Equation (1.2) is the standard partial adjustment equation, expressing
the current funds rate as a weighted average of the current funds rate
target [FR*.sub.t] and last quarter's actual value [FR.sub.t-1]. If
the actual funds rate adjusts to its target within each period, then
[rho] equals zero, which suggests that the Federal Reserve does not
smooth interest rates. Equation (1.2) also includes a disturbance term,
indicating that in the short run, the actual funds rate may deviate from
the value implied by economic determinants specified in the policy rule.
If we substitute equation (1.1) into (1.2), we get (1.3), a
forward-looking "inertial" Taylor rule. (3)
This article estimates the Taylor rule (1.3) using final as well as
real-time data. The real-time data consists of the Greenbook forecasts
of core CPI inflation and the Congressional Budget Office (CBO)
estimates of the output gap. (4) The policy rule estimated using the
final data covers all of the Greenspan period from 1987:1 to 2005:4,
whereas the rule estimated using the Greenbook forecasts spans part of
the Greenspan period from 1987:1 to 2000:4, given the five-year lag in
release of the Greenbook forecasts to the public. (5)
The empirical work presented here suggests several conclusions.
First, policy response coefficients in the estimated inertial Taylor
rule ([[alpha].sub.[pi]], [[alpha].sub.y], [rho]) are all positively
signed and statistically significant. The key points to note are: (a)
the estimated long-term inflation response coefficient [[alpha].sub.[pi]] is well above unity, which suggests that the
Greenspan Fed responded strongly to expected inflation; (b) the
estimated output gap response coefficient [[alpha].sub.y] is generally
below unity, suggesting the presence of a relatively weak response to
the output gap; and (c) the estimated partial adjustment coefficient
[rho] is well above zero, indicating the presence of interest-rate
smoothing. The conclusion suggested by the estimated Taylor rule,
namely, the Greenspan Fed responded strongly to expected inflation
developments ([[alpha].sub.[pi]] > 1) but relatively weakly to the
output gap ([[alpha].sub.y] < 1), is in line with the recent work by
Boivin (2006), who, using a different estimation methodology, reports
time-varying estimates of inflation and the output gap response
coefficients from 1970 to 1995. For the period since the mid-1980s, the
reported estimated policy coefficients are stable and close to values as
reported in this article. (6)
Second, the hypothesis that the Greenspan Fed paid attention to
expected inflation and output gap developments is supported by
additional test results. Those tests favor a forward-looking inertial
Taylor rule over the one in which the Federal Reserve focuses on lagged
inflation and the output gap. Furthermore, the results somewhat support
the hypothesis that the Greenspan Fed was focused on core rather than on
headline inflation.
Third, the Taylor rule estimated using the Greenbook core CPI
inflation forecasts and the CBO's estimates of real-time output gap
has a lower standard error of estimate and predicts policy actions
better than the Taylor rule estimated using actual future inflation and
the final, revised data on the output gap. However, there still remain
several periods during which policy actions differ significantly from
prescriptions of the simple Taylor rule. Hence, despite its better fit,
the forward-looking inertial Taylor rule estimated here may not be
considered a complete description of policy actions taken by the
Greenspan Fed.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 1
discusses estimation of the Greenspan policy rule and the real-time data
that underlie the estimated policy rule. Section 2 discusses estimation
results, and concluding observations are in Section 3.
1. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY
Estimation of the Forward-Looking Inertial Taylor Rule
One key objective of this article is to investigate whether
monetary policy actions taken by the Federal Reserve under Chairman
Greenspan can be summarized by a Taylor rule according to which the
Federal Reserve was forward looking, focused on core inflation, and
smoothed interest rates. We model the forward-looking nature of the
policy rule by relating the current value of the funds rate target to
the four-quarter-average expected inflation rate and the contemporaneous output gap. The policy rule incorporating these features is reproduced
below in equation (2.3).
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y](ln
[y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])}, + [v.sub.t] (2.3)
where [bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] is the average of
one-to-four-quarter-ahead forecasts of core CPI inflation made at time t
and other variables as previously defined. (7)
The estimation of the policy rule in equation (2.3) raises several
issues. The first issue relates to how we measure expected inflation and
the output gap. The second issue relates to the nature of data used in
estimation, namely, whether it is the real-time or final, revised data.
As discussed earlier, the use of revised as opposed to the real-time
data may affect estimates of policy coefficients and may provide a
misleading historical analysis of policy actions (Orphanides 2001,
2002). The third issue is an econometric one, arising as a result of the
potential presence of serial correlation in the error term [v.sub.t].
Rudebusch (2006) points out that the Federal Reserve may respond to
other economic factors besides expected inflation and the output gap,
and hence a Taylor rule estimated omitting those other factors is likely
to have a serially correlated error term. The presence of serial
correlation in the disturbance term, if ignored, may spuriously indicate
that the Federal Reserve is smoothing interest rates.
To further explain that a serially correlated disturbance term may
mistakenly indicate the presence of partial adjustment, note first that
if the funds rate does partially adjust to the policy rate as shown in
(1.2) and the disturbance term has no serial correlation, then the
reduced-form policy rule in (1.3 or 2.3) has the lagged funds rate as
one of the explanatory variables. Hence, the empirical finding of a
significant coefficient on the lagged funds rate in the estimated policy
rule may be interpreted as indicating the presence of interest-rate
smoothing. Now assume that there is no partial-adjustment, [rho] = 0 in
(2.3), but instead the disturbance term is serially correlated as shown
below in equation (3.1).
[v.sub.t] = s[v.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (3.1)
[FR.sub.t] = s [FR.sub.t-1] + {[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y] (ln
[y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} - s{[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t-1,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y] (ln
[y.sub.t-1] - ln [y*.sub.t-1])} + [[epsilon].sub.t]. (3.2)
If we substitute equation (3.1) into (2.3), it can be easily shown
that we get the reduced-form policy rule in equation (3.2), in which
among other variables lagged funds rate also enters the policy rule.
Hence, the empirical finding of a significant coefficient on the lagged
funds rate in the estimated policy rule may be interpreted arising as a
result of interest rate smoothing when in fact, it is not present. In
view of these considerations, this policy rule is estimated allowing for
the presence of both interest rate smoothing and serial correlation,
namely, we allow both partial adjustment and a serially correlated
disturbance term. It can be easily shown that the policy rule
incorporating both partial adjustment and serial correlation can be
expressed as in equation (4).
[FR.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0](1 - s)(1 - [rho]) + (s +
[rho])[FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho])
{[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y](ln
[y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} - s{(1 -
[rho])[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t-1,[bar.4].sup.c] + (1 -
[rho])[[alpha].sub.y](ln [y.sub.t-1] - ln [y*.sub.t-1])} -
s[rho][FR.sub.t-2]
+ [[epsilon].sub.t]. (4)
Note that if there is no serial correlation (s = 0 in [4]), we get
the reduced-form policy rule shown in equation (2.3), and if there is no
partial adjustment ([rho] = 0 in [4]), we get the policy rule shown in
(3.2). Of course, if both s and [rho] are not zero, we have a policy
rule with both partial adjustment and serial correlation.
In previous research, the forward-looking policy rule similar to
the one given in equation (2.3) has often been estimated assuming
rational expectations and using a generalized method of moments procedure (Clarida, Gali, and Gertler 2000). We follow this literature
and estimate the policy rule assuming rational expectations; namely, we
substitute actual future core inflation and actual current output gap
for the expected inflation and output gap terms and use an instrumental
variables procedure to estimate policy coefficients. However, we also
estimate the policy rule using the Greenbook inflation forecasts as
proxy for expected inflation. In contrast to previous work, we estimate
the policy rule allowing for the presence of both interest-rate
smoothing and serial correlation as in equation (4). We use a nonlinear instrumental variables procedure when rational expectations are assumed
and nonlinear ordinary least squares procedure when the Greenbook
forecasts are used. The instruments used are three lagged values of
inflation, the federal funds rate, levels and first differences of the
output gap, and the spread between the ten-year Treasury bond yield and
the federal funds rate.
In previous work, as in Boivin (2006), ordinary least squares have
been employed to estimate the Taylor rule that uses the Greenbook
forecasts. However, the use of ordinary least squares requires the
assumption that the Greenbook forecasts are contemporaneously uncorrelated with the policy shock [[epsilon].sub.t]. As noted in Boivin
(2006), while some casual arguments can be made to support this
assumption, (8) they cannot be directly verified, and hence would not be
enough to convince a skeptic that the Greenbook forecasts may
potentially be correlated with the policy surprise. This correlation may
arise if the Green-book forecasts reflect some contemporaneous
information and the FOMC also reacts to such information by adjusting
the policy rate, as argued in Rudebusch (2006). This endogeneity could
introduce some bias in parameter estimates. In view of this
consideration, we check the robustness of our results to the presence of
potential endogeneity, using instrumental variables. In particular, we
also estimate the Taylor rule, using the Greenbook forecasts made in
previous quarters as instruments. We find our main results are robust
with respect to this change in the estimation procedure.
Data
We estimate the policy rule in equation (4) over the period from
1987:1 to 2005:4 using the data on core CPI inflation and the output
gap. For expected inflation, we also use the Greenbook inflation
forecasts of core CPI inflation, prepared by the Board staff for the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meeting held near the second month
of the quarter. There is considerable evidence that the Greenbook
forecasts are most appropriate in capturing policymakers' real-time
assessment of future inflation developments. Romer and Romer (2000) show
that the Federal Reserve has an informational advantage over the private
sector, producing relatively more accurate forecasts of inflation than
does the private sector. Bernanke and Boivin (2003) argue one needs a
large set of conditional information to properly model monetary policy.
In that respect, the Greenbook forecasts include real-time information
from a wide range of sources, including the Board staff's
"judgment," not otherwise directly measurable. The policy rule
that uses the Greenbook forecasts is estimated over the period from
1988:1 to 2000:4.
Unlike inflation forecasts the Board staff's estimates of the
output gap are not readily available. Here we follow the previous
research using estimates of potential output prepared by the
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). (9) However, we also construct a
real-time series on the output gap using the Congressional Budget
estimates of actual and potential output series available in real time.
(10) Unlike the data on the output gap, the data on CPI is not
significantly revised, and hence we use the 2006 vintage dataset for
core CPI.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 charts real-time estimates of the output gap from 1987 to
2005. The most recent vintage (2006) estimates of the output gap are
also charted. The main observation is that the real-time estimates of
the output gap are not too different from their recent vintage estimates
with the exception of periods 1990 to 1993 and 1995 to 1998. The
real-time estimates of the output gap during the period surrounding the
1990-1991 recession indicate the presence of considerably more slack in
the economy than what is indicated by current estimates. Hence, a policy
rule that uses the real-time estimates of the output gap is likely to
prescribe a lower funds rate target than what is indicated by the use of
revised estimates. Similarly, real-time estimates of the output gap from
1995 to 1998 indicate far less slack in the economy than what is
suggested by the current vintage estimates, due to the ongoing
productivity acceleration that was not recognized by most economists at
the time. Hence, for the subperiod 1995 to 1998 the funds rate target
prescribed by the policy rule with the real-time output gap is higher
than what is suggested by the current vintage estimate of the output
gap, ceteris paribus. Given the size of output gap revisions, policy
evaluation is likely to be affected whether one uses the real-time or
revised data on the output gap.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 2 charts the actual and Greenbook forecasts of the
four-quarter-average core CPI inflation rate. As shown, the Greenbook
forecasts track actual inflation fairly well, with the exception of
periods, 1988:2 to 1989:2 and 1995 to 1997. In both these subperiods,
the Greenbook was "too pessimistic" about future inflation. As
some analysts have noted, during the first subperiod the Board staff may
have worried about future inflation because the Greenspan Fed had kept
interest rates low following the stock market crash of October 1987.
During the second subperiod, productivity acceleration was underway, and
most economists, including the Board staff, were slow in recognizing the
favorable effects of productivity acceleration on inflation.
2. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
This section presents and discusses estimates of a Taylor rule
fitted over the Greenspan period.
Estimates of Policy Response Coefficients
Table 1 presents estimates of policy response coefficients
([[alpha].sub.[pi]], [[alpha].sub.y], [rho]) from the Taylor rule in
equation (4) estimated using the final as well as the real-time data on
core CPI inflation and the output gap. Row 1 contains estimates derived
using the current vintage data on the output gap, whereas row 2 contains
estimates derived using the real-time data on the output gap. Row 3
contains ordinary least squares estimates using the Greenbook core CPI
inflation forecasts and the real-time data on the output gap. We also
present estimates of the first-order serial correlation coefficient s.
The estimates in rows 1 through 3 of Table 1 suggest the following
observations. First, all estimated policy response coefficients are
correctly signed and statistically significant. In particular, the
inflation response coefficient [[alpha].sub.[pi]] is generally well
above unity and the output response coefficient [[alpha].sub.y] is below
unity, which suggests that the Greenspan Fed responded strongly to
expected inflation and relatively weakly to output.
Second, the estimated serial correlation coefficient s is generally
positive and statistically significant, indicating the presence of
serially correlated errors in the estimated policy rules. As noted in
Rudebusch (2006), the presence of serial correlation may reflect
influences on the policy rate of economic variables to which the Federal
Reserve may have responded but which are omitted from the estimated
policy rule.
Third, even after allowing for the presence of serial correlation,
the estimated partial adjustment coefficient [rho] is positive and well
above zero, which suggests the continued role of partial adjustment in
generating a significant coefficient on the lagged value of the funds
rate. This result is similar to that of English, Nelson, and Sack
(2002). However, the magnitude of the estimated partial adjustment
coefficient [rho] reported here is somewhat smaller than what is found
in previous research. As discussed later in this article, the point
estimates of the partial adjustment coefficient range from .5 to .7 when
the Taylor rule is alternatively estimated using the Greenbook forecasts
of headline CPI and GDP inflation rates.
These estimates indicate a faster convergence of the funds rate to
its desired level over this sample period (see Panels A and B in Table
3). (11)
Forward- Versus Backward-Looking Specifications
The maintained hypothesis in this article is that the Greenspan Fed
was forward looking, responding to expected inflation rather than lagged
inflation. As noted at the outset, the original Taylor rule relates the
actual federal funds rate to lagged inflation and the output gap. In
order to investigate which specification better explains the Greenspan
period, we also estimate the backward-looking specification. Rows 4 and
5 in Table 1 contain estimates of policy response coefficients from this
backward-looking specification, using core CPI inflation and the
real-time data on the output gap. Row 4 reports estimates for the
subperiod 1988:1 to 2000:4, as does row 5 for the complete sample period
1988:1 to 2005:4.
One key feature of the backward-looking specifications reported in
Table 1 is that the estimated inflation response coefficient
[[alpha].sub.[pi]] is close to or below unity and not always
statistically significant. These estimates suggest that the Greenspan
Fed did not respond strongly to inflation. (12) This conclusion is in
sharp contrast to the one suggested by forward-looking specifications,
according to which the Greenspan Fed responded strongly to inflation.
How does one decide which one of these two alternative
specifications better describes the Greenspan period? The first to note
is that the forward-looking specification better fits the data, because
the forward-looking specification based on the Greenbook forecasts has a
lower standard error of estimate than the backward-looking
specification, (compare SERs across rows 3 and 4 in Table 1). We
investigate this issue further by testing the validity of alternative
specifications, using a general specification that nests both backward-
and forward-looking specifications. In particular, consider a general
specification given in equation (5.1).
[FR*.sub.t] = a + [[alpha].sub.[pi]]
GB[bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.j].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y](ln [y.sub.t] - ln
[y*.sub.t]) + [[alpha].sub.[pi]2][bar.[pi].sub.t-1.sup.c] +
[[alpha].sub.y2](ln [y.sub.t-1] - ln [y*.sub.t-1]), (5.1)
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]) [FR*.sub.t] +
[v.sub.t], and
[v.sub.t] = s [v.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (5.2)
where all variables are defined as before. Equation (5.1) relates
the federal funds rate target to variables suggested by both the
specifications. The key assumption underlying the general specification
(5.1) is that lagged inflation and the output gap may directly influence
the current federal funds rate target, in addition to influencing it
indirectly through the Greenbook inflation forecast. The
backward-looking specification allows for the direct influence of lagged
inflation and the output gap on the current funds rate target. If
[[alpha].sub.[pi]] and [[alpha].sub.y] are zero in (5.1), we get the
backward-looking specification, and if [[alpha].sub.[pi]2] and
[[alpha].sub.y2] are zero, we get the forward-looking specification.
Table 2 contains nonlinear ordinary least squares estimates of
policy response coefficients from the general policy rule (5) estimated
over the period from 1988:1 to 2000:4. In addition to using the
four-quarter-average Green-book inflation forecast, we also report
estimates using the one-quarter and two-quarter-average inflation
forecasts. As shown, estimated coefficients on the Greenbook forecast
[[alpha].sub.[pi]] and the current output gap [[alpha].sub.y] are
correctly signed and statistically significant, whereas estimated
coefficients on lagged inflation [[alpha].sub.[pi]2] and lagged output
gap [[alpha].sub.y2] are not. The p-value of the null hypothesis that
[[alpha].sub.[pi]2] and [[alpha].sub.y2] are zero is .89 to .94, leading
to the conclusion that the data favors the forward-looking
specification. (13)
Robustness Issues: Core Versus Headline Inflation and Ordinary
Least Squares Versus Instrumental Variables
Another key aspect of the maintained hypothesis is that the
Greenspan Fed was focused on core rather than headline inflation.
Furthermore, the analysis using the Greenbook forecasts used ordinary
least squares to estimate the Taylor rule. We now investigate the
robustness of our results to a few changes in the specification of the
Taylor rule and the choice of the estimation procedure.
Table 3 presents the Taylor rule estimated using the Greenbook
forecasts of three alternative measures of inflation: core CPI, headline
CPI, and the GDP implicit deflator. The measure of real-time output gap
used is from the Congressional Budget Office and remains the same across
these three inflation specifications. Panel A presents ordinary least
squares estimates and Panel B, instrumental variables estimates. For a
comparison, Panel C reports the Taylor rule estimated using actual
future inflation and the final data on the output gap. The estimates
presented in Table 3 indicate three main observations. First, focusing
on the Taylor rule with the Greenbook forecasts, the hypothesis--the
Greenspan Fed responded strongly to expected inflation and relatively
weakly to the output gap--is robust with respect to the use of headline
inflation forecasts and the instrumental variables procedure. The
estimated inflation response coefficient is well above unity and the
output gap response coefficient is below unity for all three measures of
inflation. The instrumental variables estimates of key policy response
coefficients yield conclusions that are qualitatively similar to those
based on ordinary least squares estimates (compare estimates across
Panels A and B). These results suggest that the bias in ordinary least
squares estimates, introduced as a result of the potential endogeneity
of the Greenbook forecasts, may be very small.
Second, as expected, the fit of the estimated Taylor rule as
measured by the standard error of regression (SER) is somewhat worse if
instrumental variables are used. However, the Taylor rule estimated with
the Greenbook forecasts always has a lower standard error of regression
than the Taylor rule estimated using actual future inflation and the
revised data on inflation and on the output gap (compare the SERs across
Panels A, B, and C).
Third, regarding core versus headline inflation, the results are
mixed. When the Greenbook forecasts are used, instrumental variables
estimates favor the core CPI, whereas ordinary least squares estimates
favor the headline GDP inflation (compare the SERs across Panels A and B
in Table 3). However, as reported in the next section, when we compare
the relative accuracy of the within-sample dynamic forecasts of the
funds rate generated by these different Taylor rules, the Taylor rule
with core CPI inflation forecasts yields slightly more accurate
forecasts of the funds rate than the Taylor rule with headline inflation
forecasts, supporting the maintained hypothesis that the Greenspan Fed
was focused on core inflation. (14)
Predicting the Actual Path of the Federal Funds Rate Using the
Greenbook Inflation Forecasts and the Real-Time Output Gap
In order to evaluate how well the forward-looking inertial Taylor
rule estimated here predicts actual policy actions, we focus on the
policy rule estimated using Greenbook core CPI inflation forecasts and
the real-time CBO estimates of the output gap from 1987:4 to 2000:4. For
this exercise we focus on ordinary least squares estimates. We carry out
this evaluation in two alternative ways. According to the inertial
Taylor rule estimated here, expected inflation (approximated by
Greenbook inflation forecasts) and the output gap are two major
determinants of the federal funds rate target. In order to see how well
the actual funds rate is predicted by these two economic fundamentals,
we generate the within-sample dynamic predictions of the funds rate from
1987:4 to 2000:4, using the estimated policy rule shown in equation (6).
[FR.sub.t.sup.p] = [^.[rho]] [FR.sub.t-1.sup.p] + (1 -
[^.[rho]]){[^.[alpha].sub.0] + [^.[alpha].sub.[pi]]
GB[bar.[pi].sub.t.[bar.4].sup.c] + [^.[alpha].sub.y] (ln [y.sub.t] - ln
[y*.sub.t])}, (6)
where [FR.sup.p] is the predicted funds rate and other variables
are defined as before. The key feature of the prediction equation (6) is
that in generating the current-quarter predicted value of the funds
rate, we use last quarter's predicted, but not actual value of the
federal funds rate, in addition to using current-period values of two
other economic fundamentals.
Figure 3 charts the within-sample dynamic predictions of the funds
rate. (15) Actual values of the funds rate and the prediction errors are
also charted. Two observations need to be highlighted. First, the actual
funds rate has generally moved in the direction suggested by these two
economic fundamentals (see Panel A). Second, the estimated policy rule
predicts very well the actual level of the funds rate. The mean absolute
error is .29 percentage points and the root mean squared error is .40
percentage points. Despite this good fit, however, there are few periods
when the actual funds rate is far away from the value prescribed by
economic fundamentals. Significant deviations, at least twice the root
mean squared error, occur in 1988 and 1995 (see Panel B, Figure 3).
Figure 4 charts the static predictions of the federal funds rate,
generated using the same policy rule but feeding in last quarter's
actual value of the funds rate as shown below in equation (7).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FR.sub.t.sup.p] = [^.[rho]] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 -
[^.[rho]]){[^.[alpha].sub.0] + [^.[alpha].sub.[pi]]
GB[bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [^.[alpha].sub.y] (ln [y.sub.t] - ln
[y*.sub.t])}. (7)
In static forecasts the current-period forecast of the funds rate
is determined, in part, by the current-period value of the desired
policy rate suggested by economic fundamentals and, in part, by the
one-period lagged value of the actual funds rate. So, in the static
exercise the current forecast is influenced, in part, by actual policy
actions, with the magnitude of the influence of policy on the forecast
being determined by the size of the partial adjustment coefficient
[^.[rho]]. Hence, the actual funds rate is likely better predicted by
static than dynamic forecasts, because the latter are generated ignoring
the recent history of actual funds rate changes.
A visual check of actual values of the funds rate and its static
predictions charted in Figure 4 is consistent with the estimated policy
rule. The mean absolute error is now .20 percentage points and the root
mean squared error is .26 percentage points. Panel B charts the
residuals. As shown, there are still a few periods of significant
deviations. We see deviations at least as large as twice the root mean
squared error occurring in 1988, 1989, 1995, and 1998:4. Thus, Figures 3
and 4 suggest that the Taylor rule estimated using Greenbook inflation
forecasts and the real-time data on the output gap well predict actual
policy actions, with the caveat that few episodes remain when the actual
funds rate is significantly far from what is prescribed by this policy
rule.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Using Actual Future Core Inflation and the Revised Output Gap
It is worth pointing out that in the prediction exercise the Taylor
rule estimated using the Greenbook inflation forecasts and the real-time
data on the output gap predicts actual policy actions better than the
Taylor rule estimated using actual future inflation (core CPI) and the
current vintage estimate of the output gap. In particular, we
re-estimate the Taylor rule over the period from 1988:1 to 2000:4 and
generate the within-sample, static and dynamic predictions of the funds
rate, using the current vintage estimate of the output gap. For static
predictions, the mean absolute error and root mean squared error are .30
and .37 percentage points, respectively. For dynamic predictions, the
corresponding mean absolute error and the root mean squared errors are
.72 and .84 percentage points. These prediction errors are substantially
higher than those generated using the Greenbook inflation core CPI
forecasts and the real-time output gap.
Core Versus Headline Inflation
The use of core inflation forecasts in the estimated Taylor rule
produces slightly more accurate forecasts of the funds rate than those
based on the headline inflation. For dynamic predictions of the funds
rate generated using alternatively the Taylor rules based on core CPI,
CPI, and GDP inflation forecasts, the mean absolute errors are .29, .35,
and .33 percentage points, respectively. The corresponding root mean
squared errors are .40, .44, and .41 percentage points. These summary
statistics do favor core CPI, though the Taylor rule based on GDP
inflation forecasts is a serious contender. (16,17)
Policy Residuals: Role of Additional Factors in the Estimated
Taylor-Type Rule
As stated above, even though the use of Greenbook inflation
forecasts and real-time data on the output gap enables the estimated
policy rule to predict policy actions very well, there remain few
periods when the actual funds rate is significantly away from values
prescribed by the rule, with significant deviations occurring in 1988,
1989, 1995, and 1998:4. Many analysts contend that significant
deviations represent episodes when the Greenspan Fed responded to a
variety of macroeconomic developments that are not included in the
simple policy rule (Blinder and Reis 2005, Rudebusch 2006). To
illustrate this point, consider the following narrative history of those
developments.
The first episode occurs in 1988 and 1989. Following the stock
market crash of October 1987, the Greenspan Fed kept interest rates low
as an insurance against the heightened risk of a recession, so that in
1988 the actual funds rate is below what is prescribed by the
Taylor-type rule. Inflation worries then may have led the Greenspan Fed
to tighten more in 1989, which suggests that greater-than-policy-rule
tightening in 1989 followed a somewhat looser policy of the previous
year. Some support for this view emerges if we examine the Greenbook
inflation forecasts in the period leading to 1989. As shown in Figure 2,
for the period surrounding mid-to-late 1988 and early 1989, the
Greenbook inflation forecasts turned out to be too pessimistic.
The second episode occurs in 1995 when the actual funds rate is
higher than what is prescribed by the rule. The reasons for this
greater-than-policy-rule tightening are not very clear. Taylor (2005)
notes this may reflect preemptive policy tightening that began in 1994,
whereas Rudebusch (2006) attributes it to an inflation scare that
occurred at the end of 1994 evidenced by a rapid rise in long-term
interest rates. Some limited support for the inflation scare argument
appears in Figure 2, which shows that beginning in 1994:3, the Greebook
inflation forecasts turned somewhat pessimistic about inflation. (18)
Finally, in 1998:4 the actual funds rate is below what is
prescribed by the policy rule. This is the period when the international
financial system was rocked by the Russian default and the demise of the
Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM), which led the Greenspan Fed to
lower interest rates. Together, these episodes suggest that the
particular Taylor rule estimated in this article may not be considered a
complete description of policy actions taken by the Greenspan Fed.
3. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
The main objective of this article is to investigate whether
monetary policy actions taken by the Greenspan Fed can be summarized by
a Taylor rule. Recent research highlights three aspects of the policy
rule followed by the Greenspan Fed; namely, the Greenspan Fed was
forward looking, focused on core inflation, and smoothed interest rates.
The empirical work presented here supports the above-noted general
characterization of the policy rule followed by the Greenspan Fed.
Using the Greenbook inflation forecasts and real-time Congressional
Budget estimates of the output gap, this article reports evidence
indicating that the Greenspan Fed reacted strongly to expected inflation
and relatively weakly to the output gap. The evidence also indicates the
Greenspan Fed smoothed interest rates, though the degree of
interest-rate smoothing exhibited is considerably less than what is
documented in previous research. The hypothesis that the Greenspan Fed
was focused on core CPI inflation receives some support, as the Taylor
rule based on the Greenbook forecasts of core CPI inflation does produce
slightly more accurate forecasts of the funds rate than the Taylor rule
that uses the Greenbook forecasts of headline CPI or GDP inflation.
This article finds that a Taylor rule estimated using the Greenbook
core CPI inflation forecasts and real-time Congressional Budget
estimates of the output gap predicts very well the actual path of the
federal funds rate from 1987 to 2000. The Taylor rule estimated
alternatively with the Greenbook GDP inflation forecasts seems to do as
well. However, there are few periods when the Greenspan Fed is off the
estimated rule, arising perhaps as a result of the Federal Reserve
response to special macroeconomic developments not captured by the
simple rule.
REFERENCES
Bernanke, Ben S., and Jean Boivin. 2003. "Monetary Policy in a
Data-Rich Environment." Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (3):
525-46.
Blinder, Alan S., and Ricardo Reis. 2005. "Understanding the
Greenspan Standard." Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City Economic Symposium, "The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the
Future." Jackson Hole, WY.
Boivin, Jean. 2006. "Has U.S. Monetary Policy Changed?
Evidence from Drifting Coefficients and Real-Time Data." Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 38 (4): 1,149-173.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler. 2000.
"Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and
Some Theory." Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (1): 147-80.
Congressional Budget Office. 2001. "CBO's Method for
Estimating Potential Output: An Update." The Congress of the United
States (August).
English, William B., William R. Nelson, and Brian P. Sack. 2002.
"Interpreting the Significance of the Lagged Interest Rate in
Estimated Monetary Policy Rules." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank Board
of Governors (April 24).
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2001. "Monetary Policy Rules Based on
Real-time Data." American Economic Review 91 (4): 965-85.
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2002. "Monetary Policy Rules and the
Great Inflation." American Economic Review 92 (2): 115-20.
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2006. "Monetary Policy Rules,
Macroeconomic Stability and Inflation: A View from the Trenches."
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36 (2): 151-75.
Reifschneider, David L., David J. Stockton, and David W. Wilcox.
1997. "Econometric Models and the Monetary Policy Process."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 47 (December):
1-37.
Romer, Christina, and David Romer. 2000. "Federal Reserve
Information Advantage and the Behavior of Interest Rates." American
Economic Review 90 (3): 429-57.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 2002. "Term Structure Evidence on Interest
Rate Smoothing and Monetary Policy Inertia." Journal of Monetary
Economics 49 (6): 1,161-87.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 2006. "Monetary Policy Inertia: Fact or
Fiction?" International Journal of Central Banking 2 (4): 85-135.
Taylor, John B. 1993. "Discretion Versus Policy Rules in
Practice." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39
(December): 195-214.
Taylor, John B. 2005. "Commentary: Understanding the Greenspan
Standard." Remarks presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Economic Symposium, "The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the
Future." Jackson Hole, WY.
Woodford, Michael. 2005. "Central Bank Communication and
Policy Effectiveness." Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City Economic Symposium, "The Greenspan Era: Lessons for
the Future." Jackson Hole, WY.
We would like to thank Andreas Hornstein, Robert Hetzel, Roy Webb,
and Nashat Moin for their comments. The views expressed in this article
are those of the authors and do no necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) Taylor (1993) did not estimate the policy rule but chose
specific values for the policy response coefficients, the real rate, and
the inflation target.
(2) English, Nelson, and Sack (2002) provide empirical evidence for
the hypothesis that the Greenspan Fed smoothed interest rates. Woodford
(2005) suggests the Federal Reserve under Greenspan, in fact,
communicated its interest-smoothing intentions to financial markets by
including descriptive, forward-looking sentences in its policy
statements to ensure that policy expectations of the financial sector
remain aligned with its own outlook for policy. For example, in order to
deal with the threat of deflation in 2003, policy statements in that
year included sentences such as "... policy accommodation can be
maintained for a considerable period of time," meaning the Federal
Reserve would not raise its funds rate target in response to increases
in real growth given the threat of deflation. The intent was to hold
long-term interest rates low by quashing expectations that the Fed was
on the verge of increasing the funds rate. In 2004, policy statements
included phrases such as "... the Committee believes that it can be
patient in removing policy accommodation," and "... the
Committee believes that policy accommodation can be removed at a pace
that is likely to be measured." The latter came to mean 25 basis
points at each FOMC meeting. These considerations suggest the Greenspan
policy rule should be estimated allowing for the presence of
interest-rate smoothing. Blinder and Reis (2005) also argue that the
Greenspan Fed used frequent small changes in the funds rate to hit its
target for the policy rate suggested by economic fundamentals such as
inflation and unemployment.
(3) As is well known, the constant term in the Taylor rule has
embedded in it the Federal Reserve's estimates of the short-term
real rate and the inflation target. For further explantion, rewrite equation (1.1) of the text as [FR*.sub.t] = rr* + [pi]* +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]]([[pi].sub.t,j.sup.c] - [pi]*) + [[alpha].sub.y](ln
[y.sub.t,k] - ln [y*.sub.t,k]) where rr* is the real rate and [pi]* is
the inflation target. If we substitute the above equation into equation
(1.2) of the text, we get equation (1.3) of the text, where the constant
term is now defined as [[alpha].sub.0] = rr* + (1 -
[[alpha].sub.[pi]])[pi]*. However, one cannot recover estimates of both
rr* and [pi]* without bringing some additional information. See footnote 17.
(4) The preferred measure of real economic activity (say, the
output gap) should be the one used in generating the Greenbook
forecasts. However, for a major part of the sample period covered here,
the Greenbook has not published estimates of the output gap. Hence, it
is quite common in this literature to estimate the policy rules using
the CBO estimates of the output (or unemployment) gap.
(5) We lose observations at the beginning and end of the sample
period due to leads and lags of inflation in the policy rule. The
effective sample period is 1988:1 to 2004:4.
(6) In Boivin (2006), the main objective is to investigate whether
policy coefficients have changed over time. For expected inflation, the
Greenbook forecasts of GNP and GDP deflator are employed. The level of
economic activity is proxied using the difference between the natural
unemployment rate and the Greenbook forecast of the unemployment rate.
The article, however, also uses the real-time output gap measure
constructed by Orphanides (2001). For the period 1985 to 1995, the point
estimates of the long-run inflation response coefficients are well above
unity and those for the long-run output gap response coefficient are
well below unity.
(7) In particular, the four-quarter-average inflation forecast is
defined as [bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] = ([[pi].sub.t,1.sup.c] +
[[pi].sub.t,2.sup.c] + [[pi].sub.t,3.sup.c] + [[pi].sub.t,4.sup.c])/4.
We have also dropped the subscript 0 in the output gap term (ln
[y.sub.t,0] - ln [y*.sub.t,0]).
(8) Reifschneider, Stockton, and Wilcox (1997) provide some
information about the conditioning assumptions of the Greenbook
forecasts over the last ten years. The first feature is that these
forecasts are made under the typical assumption that the federal funds
rate will remain unchanged during the next six to eight quarters. This
neutral assumption about the path of monetary policy may reflect the
desire of the Board staff to avoid being construed as making policy
recommendations, suggesting that for most of that period, the forecasts
were not conditioned on the policy surprise. The second feature of these
forecasts is a large "judgmental" component, making it hard
for these forecasts to be mechanically reproduced by any particular
forecasting model, thereby lessening the probability of a
contemporaneous correlation between forecasts and the policy surprise.
(9) Potential output is defined as trend in the productive capacity
of the economy and is estimated by the level of GDP attainable when the
economy is operating at a high rate of resource use. The CBO estimates
potential output for the economy, using a production function approach
applied to each of five major sectors (nonfarm business, government,
farm, household and nonprofit institutions, and residential housing) and
then aggregating sectoral estimates of potential output. For example,
for the nonfarm business sector CBO uses a neoclassical production
function that relates output produced in that sector to labor (hours
worked), capital, and total factor productivity. Potential output in
nonfarm business sector is an estimate of output attainable when labor,
capital, and total factor productivity variables in the production
function are set at their cyclically adjusted levels (Congressional
Budget Office 2001).
(10) In January of each year from 1991 to 2006, the Congressional
Budget Office has released the historical data on actual and potential
output. For the period 1987 to 1990, the output gap is constructed using
the series on actual and potential output given in the 1991 vintage data
file. For 1991, we have used the pertinent series on actual and
potential output from the 1992 vintage data file and for each year
thereafter. So, the potential output estimate for 2005 is constructed
using the data file released in January 2006.
(11) As illustrated in Rudebusch (2006), the typical estimate of
the partial adjustment coefficient [rho] for this sample period is .8,
suggesting that if in response to changed economic conditions the
Federal Reserve wanted to raise the funds rate by one percentage point,
it would raise it by about 20 basis points in the first three months and
by about 60 basis points after one year. Focusing on the Taylor rule,
which is estimated using Greebook forecasts and real-time data on the
output gap, the mid-point of the estimated range of the partial
adjustment coefficient is .6, suggesting the adjustment of the actual
funds rate to its desired level will be complete well before a year. See
also English, Nelson, and Sack (2002), in which the use of real-time
data in a forward-looking policy rule yields an estimate of the partial
adjustment coefficient that is also quite low.
(12) Blinder and Reis (2005) report a similar finding. For the
period from 1987:3 to 2000:1, they estimate a Taylor rule that relates
the funds rate target to current inflation and the unemployment gap. The
inflation response coefficient estimated during that time is .57,
leading them to conclude that the Greenspan Fed did not respond strongly
to inflation.
(13) The results do not change if the general specification is
estimated including current values of inflation and the output gap,
instead of lagged values of inflation. That is, the estimated
coefficient on expected inflation remains significant and that on
current inflation is not.
(14) We did not consider the consumption expenditure deflator (PCE)
in this comparison, because the Federal Reserve only recently started
focusing on core PCE. In fact, the Greenbook started producing forecasts
of core PCE beginning in 2000, suggesting the Greenspan Fed was focused
on core CPI for most of the period covered.
(15) The predictions begin in 1987:4. For generating the prediction
for 1987:4, we use the preceding quarter's actual funds rate. For
later periods, the predicted values are generated using the preceding
period's predicted value and the current period estimates of
expected inflation and the output gap.
(16) If the Taylor rules based on the Greenbook forecasts of three
alternative measures of inflation--core CPI, CPI, and GDP--are estimated
with instrumental variables, then the root mean squared errors generated
by the dynamic prediction exercise are .46, .59, and .49 percentage
points, respectively.
(17) It will be interesting to derive an estimate of the Greenspan
Fed's inflation target under the additional assumption that the
Fed's estimate of the short-term real rate can be approximated by
the sample mean of the ex post real yield on three-month Treasury bills
over a longer sample period, the latter defined as the nominal yield minus the lagged value of the four-quarter-average GDP inflation rate.
By this metric, the short-term real rate is 1.9 percent if we use the
sample period 1961:1-2005:4, and 2.1 percent if we use only the
Greenspan period 1987:1-2005:4. These calculations suggest it is
reasonable to assume that the Greenspan Fed's estimate of the
short-real rate is approximately 2.0 percent. Given rr* = 2.0 percent
and given an estimate of the constant term from the estimated Taylor
rule based on the Greenbook forecasts of core CPI inflation, the
Greenspan Fed's inflation target calculated using the relationship
[^.[alpha].sub.0] = rr* + (1 - [^.[alpha].sub.[pi]])[pi]* [right arrow]
.12 = 2.0 + (1 - 1.7)[pi]* is 2.7 percent. The result above--the
Greenspan Fed's inflation target is 2.7 percent--may at first
appear at odds with the 2.0 percent value assumed in the original Taylor
rule, where inflation is measured by the behavior of GDP inflation.
During the Greenspan era, GDP inflation has exhibited a somewhat
different trend behavior than the core CPI inflation measure. Using the
metric of comparing means, the sample mean of GDP inflation rates over
1987:1-2005:4 is 2.4 percent, which is lower compared with the value 3.0
percent computed using core CPI inflation over the same period. If we
were to adjust the inflation targets for the presence of different
means, then the Greenspan Fed having an inflation target of 2.7 percent
based on the behavior of the core CPI inflation measure is equivalent to
its having, instead, an inflation target of 2.1 percent based on the GDP
inflation measure. The latter value is close to 2.0 percent assumed in
the original Taylor rule.
(18) Another factor that explains the greater-than-policy
tightening in 1995 and in 1996-1997, as in some previous work that uses
actual future inflation and the current vintage output gap measure, is
the remarkable increase in productivity and potential output. At the
time, most economists did not recognize these changes and, hence, may
have overestimated the degree of utilization in product and labor
markets, which likely reflected in tighter policy. However, a visual
check of Figures 1 and 2 suggests that productivity acceleration may not
be relevant in explaining the greater-than-policy tightening in 1995. As
shown in Figure 1, real-time estimates of the output gap indicate far
less slack in the economy than what is suggested by its
2006-vintage-only data in the subperiod following the year 1995.
Similarly, the Greenbook forecasts become significantly pessimistic only
in the years 1996-1997. Thus, these considerations suggest that while
productivity acceleration may be relevant in explaining the post-1995
greater-than-policy tightenings documented in some previous work, its
role in explaining the 1995 policy episode is in doubt.
Table 1 Estimated Taylor Rules: Core CPI Inflation
Row Period Gap Inflation Estimation [[alpha].sub.[pi]]
1 2005:4 Revised (Actual, FW) IV 1.5
(3.7)
2 2005:4 Real-time (Actual, FW) IV 2.2
(8.2)
3 2000:4 Real-time (GB, FW) OLS 1.7
(8.8)
4 2000:4 Real-time (Actual, BW) OLS 1.0
(1.8)
5 2005:4 Real-time (Actual, BW) OLS 0.71
(0.8)
Row [[alpha].sub.y] [rho] s [bar.R.sup.2] SER
1 .78 .73 .59 .98 .326
(3.2) (6.7) (4.3)
2 .68 .66 .49 .98 .315
(5.5) (6.4) (3.6)
3 .64 .70 .35 .98 .257
(6.4) (13.1) (2.5)
4 .73 .75 .59 .97 .329
(2.6) (5.9) (3.5)
.51 0.66 .84 .98 .345
5 (1.5) (2.8) (3.9)
Notes: Rows 1 and 2 contain nonlinear instrumental variables (IV)
estimates of policy coefficients from the forward-looking (FW) policy
rule given below in (a) and use revised or real-time data on the
output gap.
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y]
(ln [y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} + [v.sub.t]. (a)
Row 3 contains nonlinear ordinary least squares estimates (OLS) of
policy coefficients from the forward-looking (FW) policy rule given
below in (b) and use the Greenbook (GB) inflation forecasts of core CPI
inflation and real-time CBO estimates of the output gap.
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]] GB[bar.[pi].sub.t,4.sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y]
(ln [y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} + [v.sub.t]. (b)
Row 4 contains nonlinear ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of
policy coefficients from the backward-looking (BW) policy rule given
below in (c).
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t-1.sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y] (ln
[y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} + [v.sub.t]. (c)
The instruments used are three lagged values of the inflation rate, the
funds rate, the output gap (final or real-time), the growth gap, and the
spread between nominal yields on ten-year Treasury bonds and the federal
funds rate. Parentheses contain t-values. SER is the standard error of
estimate. Estimation was done allowing for the presence of first-order
serial correlation in [v.sub.t], and s is the estimated first-order
serial correlation coefficient. The sample periods begin in 1988:1 and
end in the year shown in the column labeled "period."
Table 2 Estimates of Policy Response Coefficients From a General Policy
Rule: Core CPI Inflation
Row GB Forecasts [[alpha].sub.[pi]] [[alpha].sub.y] [rho]
1 1-q average 1.49 .91 .75
(1.9) (1.9) (8.4)
2 2-q average 1.85 0.86 0.75
(2.0) (1.9) (8.5)
3 4-q average 1.99 0.71 0.72
(2.5) (2.0) (8.3)
Row GB Forecasts [[alpha].sub.[pi]2] [[alpha].sub.y2] SER
1 1-q average .29 -.1 .284
(.3) (.2)
2 2-q average .16 -.1 .275
(.1) (.3)
3 4-q average 0.33 -.1 .262
(.3) (.3)
Row GB Forecasts [bar.R.sub.2] p-value
1 1-q average .97 .89
2 2-q average .97 .94
3 4-q average .97 .93
Notes: The coefficients reported are nonlinear least squares estimates
of the policy rule given below in (a) and use the Greenbook forecasts
(GB) and real-time data on the output gap.
[FR*.sub.t] = a + [[alpha].sub.[pi]]
GB[bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] + [[alpha].sub.y] (ln [y.sub.t] - ln
[y*.sub.t]) + [[alpha].sub.[pi]2][bar.[pi].sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.y2](ln [y.sub.t-1] - ln [y*.sub.t-1]), (a.1)
[FR.sub.t] = [rho] [FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]) [FR*.sub.t] +
[v.sub.t], (a.2)
where all variables are defined as in Table 1. Parentheses below
coefficients contain t-values. The p-value reported is for the test of
the null hypothesis that [[alpha].sub.[pi]2] and [[alpha].sub.y2] are
zero. The sample period is from 1988:1 to 2000:4. We do not report the
estimated serial correlation coefficient, though the equations are
estimated assuming the presence of serial correlation.
Table 3 Estimated Taylor Rules
Panel A: Greenbook Forecasts/Ordinary Least Squares
Sample Period Inflation [[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.[pi]]
1988:1-2000:4 Core CPI 0.12 1.7
(0.20) (8.8)
1988:1-2000:4 CPI -0.80 2.1
(0.70) (6.4)
1988:1-2000:4 GDP 0.70 1.9
(1.20) (8.5)
Panel B: Greenbook Forecasts/Instrumental Variables
1988:1-2000:4 Core CPI -0.20 1.8
(0.30) (9.3)
1988:1-2000:4 CPI -1.50 2.3
(1.20) (6.0)
1988:1-2000:4 GDP 0.29 2.1
(0.40) (9.0)
Panel C: Actual Future Inflation/Instrumental Variables
1988:1-2000:4 Core CPI 2.70 1.0
(1.30) (1.5)
1988:1-2000:4 CPI 1.80 1.3
(1.00) (2.2)
1988:1-2000:4 GDP 1.30 1.9
(0.80) (2.9)
Panel A: Greenbook Forecasts/Ordinary Least Squares
Sample Period [[alpha].sub.y] [rho] s [bar.R.sup.2] SER
1988:1-2000:4 .64 .69 .35 .98 .257
(6.4) (13.1) (2.5)
1988:1-2000:4 .81 .74 .46 .98 .253
(5.5) (14.4) (3.3)
1988:1-2000:4 .66 .66 .45 .98 .252
(6.5) (10.9) (3.3)
Panel B: Greenbook Forecasts/Instrumental Variables
1988:1-2000:4 .62 .60 .45 .98 .270
(6.6) (6.9) (3.2)
1988:1-2000:4 .78 0.64 .60 .98 .273
(5.5) (7.8) (4.3)
1988:1-2000:4 .64 .51 .55 .97 .278
(7.2) (4.5) (4.1)
Panel C: Actual Future Inflation/Instrumental Variables
1988:1-2000:4 .85 .80 .60 .97 .314
(1.9) (5.6) (3.2)
1988:1-2000:4 .80 .78 .61 .98 .324
(2.0) (7.3) (3.4)
1988:1-2000:4 .67 .72 .63 .96 .332
(1.8) (4.3) (2.7)
Notes: Panels A, B, and C contain nonlinear estimates of policy
coefficients from the policy rule given below in (a). Panels A and B use
the Greenbook inflation forecasts and the CBO real-time estimates of the
output gap. Panel C uses actual future inflation and the final revised
data on the output gap.
[FR.sub.t] = [rho][FR.sub.t-1] + (1 - [rho]){[[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.[pi]][bar.[pi].sub.t,[bar.4].sup.c] +
[[alpha].sub.y](ln [y.sub.t] - ln [y*.sub.t])} + [v.sub.t]. (a)
The instruments used are three lagged values of the pertinent inflation
variable: the federal funds rate, the output gap (real-time or final),
the growth gap, and the spread between nominal yields on ten-year
Treasury bonds and the federal funds rate. See notes in Table 1.