Barriers to foreign direct investment under political instability.
Azzimonti, Marina ; Sarte, Pierre-Daniel G.
Foreign direct investment (FDI), as pointed out by Kindleberger
(1969), arises when the host country has an investment opportunity that
it cannot exploit by itself because it lacks the means or technical
know-how, or because of market incompleteness (that is, access to
capital markets is restricted). A multinational corporation (MNC) may be
able to exploit such an opportunity because it has the necessary
capital, technology, and managerial skills to do so. Even though the
return to foreign direct investment is potentially large in many
developing countries (for example, the opening up of Eastern Europe provided advantages to multinational firms because of the low cost of
labor, low levels of capital in place, and the proximity to major
markets), the flow of direct investment is concentrated in just a few
countries. (1) Lucas (1990) attributes this lack of FDI in countries
with potentially large marginal returns to capital to the fact that many
developing countries face higher political risk than industrialized ones.
A distinctive characteristic of FDI is that once an investment has
been made, a foreign investor cannot prevent the government in the host
country from changing the environment in which the investment decision
was made. Despite attempts to establish international tribunals,
contracts between multinational corporations (MNCs) and sovereign
countries are almost impossible to enforce. The quality of institutions,
and in particular, the degree of protection of property rights, are key
in determining the expected return to foreign investors. Countries with
relatively poor legal protection of assets, and a high degree of
political instability, generally exhibit high rates of expropriation and
this makes investment less attractive. In practice, expropriation can
take different forms. A direct act of expropriation involves
nationalization of foreign-owned corporations, in which the government
simply takes control of the capital stock (Kobrin 1980, 1984). There are
also indirect forms of expropriation that multinational corporations
face. Examples include excessive taxation, capital controls,
manipulation of exchange rates, and bribes and permits demanded by
government officials.
In this article, we describe some stylized facts about
expropriation episodes and other lessons learned from the empirical
literature on FDI. We then summarize some of the main theories
attempting to explain the effects of expropriation on investment and
growth. Finally, we develop a theory that relates each type of
expropriation to political instability and concentration of power.
A simple two-period political economy model is presented in which
groups with access to an expropriation technology alternate in power
according to an exogenous probability. The group that controls the
government in the first period has the ability to obtain bribes from
foreign investors who are attempting to gain access to production in the
host country. This form of indirect expropriation is analogous to an
investment tax, in the sense that it distorts the optimal allocation of
international capital by imposing additional costs to potential
investors. After investment decisions have been made (in the second
period), the group in office decides how much capital should be seized
or nationalized, a direct form of expropriation.
Following the literature on FDI, we will assume that any capital
expropriated by the host country becomes unproductive. This stylized representation tries to characterize the empirical observation that MNCs
are usually more efficient in running production than the host country.
For example, Minor (1994) documents that about 35 percent of all
enterprises that were expropriated between 1960 and 1979 have been
privatized between 1980 and 1992, indicating public "disillusion with the typical result of expropriation, the state-owned
enterprise" (see Biais and Perotti 2002 for more on recent trends
on privatizations). Theoretically, the costs associated with
expropriation arise mainly because of two reasons. First, there is
usually a reduction in the technological spillovers embodied in foreign
capital. Second, because the capital installed by foreign investors may
be specific to the manager's skills, it may take time for domestic
workers to acquire the know-how needed to operate the foreign
technology. As a consequence, reductions in the capital stock installed
by MNCs imply productivity losses and depressed domestic wages.
At any point in time, the benefit associated with expropriation is
given by the amount of goods that can be transferred from MNCs to
domestic agents. The tradeoff faced by policymakers is, therefore, given
by the redistributive gains of expropriation versus the income loss
suffered by local workers.
A key assumption is that there are no institutional barriers to
discretionary redistribution, so any group can appropriate all
expropriated resources. Because the group in power is not forced to
transfer resources to other groups, a "tragedy of the commons"
arises: there is too much expropriation in equilibrium. A tragedy of
commons occurs when property rights of an asset cannot be enforced; a
typical example is fishing on a lake. Typically this gives rise to
over-consumption or under-investment (see Gordon 1954 or Lancaster
1973). In our model, it is precisely the fact that groups cannot ensure
ex ante that they will receive the benefits of expropriation in the
future that cause over-expropriation in the first period, making the
level of bribes inefficiently large. The degree of such inefficiency is
related to how likely it is that the current group in government retains
power in the second period. That is, the degree of such inefficiency is
related to the political instability.
While countries that have higher political instability are
predicted to exhibit higher levels of indirect expropriation, direct
expropriation levels are lower. The intuition is as follows: because
each group finds its chances of being in power in the second period very
unlikely, it becomes shortsighted and demands a large quantity of bribes
when in power (i.e., in the first period). This discourages investment,
and the reduction of capital decreases the marginal cost of direct
expropriation, encouraging more expropriation in the second period. The
marginal benefit is reduced as well because the tax base shrinks, which
reduces the incentives to expropriate. Under a Cobb-Douglas technology
assumption, the latter effect dominates and direct expropriation goes
down.
A second interesting result derived in this article is related to
the concentration of power. Following Tornell and Lane (1999), power is
concentrated when there are few groups competing for government. They
find that the relation between indirect expropriation and the number of
groups in power is non-monotonic. When there is high concentration of
power initially, a dilution of concentration results in more indirect
expropriation, but this relationship reverts when concentration is small
(i.e., there is a large number of groups to begin with). Direct
expropriation, on the contrary, always increases with the number of
groups. We provide some details on the intuition behind this result at
the end of Section 4.
The organization of the paper is as follows. We define the
different types of expropriation in Section 1 and summarize the main
empirical findings in the literature in Section 2. We then proceed to
describe some of the most influential theoretical articles on
expropriation in Section 3. In Section 4, our model is described and the
main results are derived. Section 5 concludes.
1. DEFINING EXPROPRIATION
Expropriation refers, in general, to policies that adversely affect
the private value of the stock and/or returns of foreign investment. As
mentioned in the previous section, we can distinguish between
"direct" and "indirect" expropriation.
OECD (2004) provides an extensive analysis of the concept of
expropriation, where jurisprudence, state practice, and literature on
international investment law are considered. According to the survey,
direct expropriation is "... an act where there is a compulsory
transfer of property rights by the host state.... An investment is
nationalised or otherwise directly expropriated through formal transfer
of title or outright physical seizure. In addition to the term
expropriation, terms such as 'dispossession,'
'taking,' 'deprivation,' or privation' are also
used." Kobrin (1980, 1984) and Minor (1994) define direct
expropriation as the "forced divestment of equity ownership of a
foreign direct investor." The principal characteristic is that such
divestment is involuntary, against the will of the owners and/or
managers of the enterprise, and must entail managerial control through
equity ownership across national borders.
Indirect expropriation stands for other forms of change in the
institutional environment that reduce the value of an investment, but in
which property is not necessarily seized. Schlemmer-Schulte (1999)
characterizes indirect expropriation "... as excessive and
repetitive tax or regulatory measures that have a de facto confiscatory effect in that their combined results deprive the investor in fact of
his ownership, control or interests in the investment ..." This may
be accomplished, in addition to the raising of taxes, through
manipulation of exchange rates (i.e., devaluations), fees or bribes
charged to the enterprise, the return of the firm to public ownership at
unfair terms, the stiffening of regulation, or the institution of
non-tariff barriers, such as restrictions in the repatriation of profits
or other capital transactions (referred to as "transfer risk"
by insurance companies). This form of indirect expropriation is also
referred to as "disguised" or "creeping
expropriation." In contrast to the case of direct expropriation,
there is no generally accepted definition of indirect expropriation in
international law. Moreover, the distinction between this form of
expropriation and non-compensable regulation (i.e., antitrust laws,
environmental protection, etc.) is not clear. (2)
2. LESSONS FROM THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE
In this section, we will analyze alternative forms of expropriation
and describe their changes over the past 30 years. Afterward, we
summarize some of the empirical articles documenting the relationship
between expropriation (and other measures of the quality of
institutions) and FDI.
Direct Expropriation
According to Minor (1994), there were 575 expropriation acts
between 1960 and 1992, committed by 79 developing host countries against
foreign multinationals. Africa was the region with the highest
concentration of expropriation events in the 1960s and 1970s, but Latin
America and Asia became more active during the 1980s. The manufacturing
and petroleum sectors were the most affected by direct expropriation:
they account for about 40 percent of all expropriation events between
1960 and 1964, and this percentage rises to almost 50 percent in the
period 1976-1979. Jensen (2005) points out that another industry
recently affected by major political events was privately financed
infrastructure, in which some projects have been directly expropriated
(for example, the government of Thailand's seizure of a private
expressway in 1993). Li (2004) documents that out of 520 expropriation
acts committed between 1960 and 1990, autocratic governments committed
423 acts while democratic governments committed only 97 acts. This
finding relates to the fact that democratic governments have stronger
institutions protecting property rights.
Minor shows a decline in the number of expropriation events after
the 1970s. This is explained by the fact that international conditions
in the late 1970s increased the benefits of FDI inflows and the freedom
of action over some multinational corporations was limited. For example,
in 1990 a paragraph in the Chinese-Foreign Joint Venture Law added a
"no nationalization" clause (Robertson and Chen 1990).
Tanzania adopted the National Investment Protection Policy Act that
offers legal protection against nationalization (Corkran 1991). Of
course, whether host countries respect such agreements ex post is not
obvious. A more important factor that reduced the incentives to
nationalize multinational corporations was the failure of state-owned
enterprises. As mentioned earlier, more than 35 percent of the
enterprises that were expropriated prior to 1980 were subsequently
privatized. This indicates that multinational corporations have an
advantage over domestic governments in running production (because
investments are specific to the skills of their foreign managers, for
example), an assumption that will be made in the theoretical section of
the article.
According to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD), "Disputes on direct expropriation--mainly
related to nationalization that marked the 1970s and 1980s--have been
replaced by disputes related to foreign investment regulation and
'indirect expropriation'" (OECD 2004, 2). The following
section describes the particular form that this type of expropriation
has taken in recent years.
Indirect Expropriation
Indirect expropriation acts are more difficult to document in a
consistent manner because of the lack of a formal or legal definition.
In this subsection, we will restrict attention to a set of examples to
highlight the nature of these expropriation acts.
Argentina's financial crisis of 2001-2002, when the
"corralito" was imposed, provides a good example of indirect
expropriation: the government restricted capital transactions and
"pesified" contracts and financial assets. Foreign firms'
funds were converted into pesos, and many contracts, especially in
infrastructure, were rewritten or canceled. At the same time, capital
was not allowed to leave the country (hence the name,
"corralito," which means "little fence").
Janeba (2002) provides some other examples of indirect
expropriation. In 1995, China announced the dissolution of various
benefits that foreign firms received in the form of exemptions from
custom duties or tax rebates when using local materials. Russia
frequently considered introducing a "super profits tax" for
foreign oil companies investing in Russia. Government renegotiation of
power, electricity, and water contracts after financial crises in
Argentina, Indonesia, Pakistan, and the Philippines constitute further
examples (see Moran 2003). More recent examples include foreign oil
companies being forced out of their joint venture contracts, for
example, such as the company, TNK-BP in Russia.
Shleifer and Vishny (1993) argue that indirect expropriation is
particularly distortive for countries with unstable governments in which
an entrepreneur may have to bribe several public officials and still
face the possibility that none of them really has the power to allow the
project to proceed.
Stylized Facts
Trends
Researchers at the World Bank's Multilateral Investment
Guarantee Agency (MIGA) found that U.S. investors in emerging markets
were subject to both direct and indirect acts of expropriations between
1970 and 2001. The researchers note that between 1971 and 1980, U.S.
investors were exposed to restrictions on transferring and repatriating
funds (transfer risk) and also subject to a number of direct
expropriations. During the period of 1981-1990, an even greater increase
in the number of transfer risks claims as well as major reductions in
the number of expropriations occurred. Chifor (2002) notes, "In the
past two decades, indirect expropriation has supplanted direct takings
as the dominant form of state interference with foreign investment, as
host countries have learned that more value can be extracted from
foreign enterprises through the more subtle instrument of regulatory
control rather than outright seizures." The period of 1996-2000 was
risky for multinational corporations, mainly because political violence
and civil war claims increased dramatically. For most firms, however,
direct expropriation was the most damaging. As Jensen (2005) notes,
"Of all the dollars paid out by OPIC from 1970-1978, 96% of these
claims were for expropriation. From 1991-2004, even after the major
financial crises that triggered a number of transfer claims, 84% of the
settlement amounts of OPIC claims were for expropriation." (3)
FDI, Expropriation, and Institutions
There are a large number of empirical articles that attempt to
assess the quantitative importance of expropriations and the quality of
institutions on FDI inflows. Most studies make no distinction between
the effects of direct and indirect forms of expropriation. An exception
to this are articles focusing on corruption, a form of creeping
expropriation. Mauro (1995) finds that corruption has a negative effect
on total and private investment, thus hindering growth. Wei (2000),
using data on OECD countries, shows that corruption indices are strongly
and negatively correlated with FDI inflows. For example, he estimates
that an increase in Singapore's level of corruption to that of
Mexico's would have the same negative effect on inward FDI as
raising the tax rate on multinational corporations by 50 percentage
points. Hines (1995) documents a reduction in U.S. FDI in the period
following the 1977 U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, which stipulated
penalties for U.S. multinational firms found to be bribing foreign
officials. Asiedu (2006), using a panel data for 22 countries over the
period 1984-2000, shows that a decline in Nigeria's level of
corruption to that of South Africa's has the same positive effect
on FDI as increasing the share of fuels and minerals in total exports by
about 35 percent. He concludes that countries that are small or lack
natural resources can attract FDI by improving their institutions and
policy environment.
Variables contained in the Political Risk Services/International
Country Risk Guide (PRS/ICRG) political risk dataset, such as corruption
in government, expropriation risk, bureaucratic quality, risk of
repudiation of contracts by the government, and law and order, are used
in other studies to explain differences in FDI inflows across countries.
These variables are collected in order to provide a comparable measure
across countries of how expected returns to capital investment are
reduced by direct and indirect forms of expropriation. While some
components such as expropriation risk, for example, only incorporate the
probability that capital is expropriated after investment, others such
as corruption in government, for example, refer to reductions in
profitability that will occur almost with certainty (i.e., bribes).
Daude and Stein (2001), using a simple average of the variables in
the PRS/ICRG dataset mentioned previously (for the year 1995), find that
a one standard deviation improvement in the quality of institutions
increases FDI by a factor of 2.2. When focusing on risk of repudiation
of contracts by the government, an improvement of one standard
deviation--for example, from the level of Egypt to that of
Finland--increases FDI by a factor of 1.4. They also find that variables
measuring economic policy predictability are positively correlated with
FDI inflows. Busse and Hefeker (forthcoming), using the same dataset for
the period 1984-2005, find that the quality of institutions is a
relevant factor for determining FDI inflows. The degree of ethnic
tensions, law and order, and government stability are all statistically
significant factors affecting net FDI inflows.
Hausmann and Fernandez-Arias (2000) analyze the effects of
institutional variables in the composition of capital inflows using
variables compiled by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (1999). They
find that lack of regulatory quality, government effectiveness and
shareholder rights are significant factors explaining reductions in the
share of inflows represented by FDI. Using the Institutional Investor Index as a measure of country risk, Raff and Srinivasan (1998) find that
in the manufacturing sector there is a -0.55 correlation between country
risk and inward FDI. Li and Resnick (2003) find that both property
rights protection and democracy-related property rights protection
encourage FDI inflows.
In summary, there is concrete evidence from the empirical
literature that (1) poor quality of institutions, (2) alternative forms
of expropriation, and (3) lack of commitment of policy all have negative
effects on FDI inflows. In the next section, we will describe how the
theoretical literature attempts to explain these correlations.
3. LESSONS FROM THE THEORETICAL LITERATURE
Most of the theoretical literature assumes that local
governments' incentives to expropriate depend on the difference
between the benefits of obtaining income from foreign capital (or the
ownership of capital) and the opportunity costs of expropriation.
Affiliate operation is frequently less successful when managed by the
host government rather than by the MNC. This applies specifically to
projects in which the hosts import not only physical capital but also
foreign entrepreneurship, either in the form of managerial skills or
technological know-how.
Under these assumptions, Eaton and Gersovitz (1984) present one of
the most influential articles on expropriation theory. They analyze a
static economy where competitive investors decide on the amount of
foreign investment to be placed in a small open economy. The host
country decides whether to expropriate the whole stock of physical
capital in order to maximize national income. The cost of such policy is
given by the loss in productivity suffered because managerial services
are no longer available after expropriation occurs. Foreseeing that
their capital might be expropriated ex post, foreign investors will
never increase their investment to the level where expropriation becomes
optimal. As a result, even though no expropriation occurs in
equilibrium, the international allocation of capital is distorted, and
FDI remains inefficiently low. Consequently, the ability of the
government to expropriate when it lacks the commitment to make binding
promises on policy may actually reduce the government's welfare.
Empirically, this explains why domestic factor prices may not reflect
social returns when the supply of investment is affected by the threat
of expropriation. This also supports the finding that commodity trade
fails to equate the returns to capital across countries.
Thomas and Worrall (1994) extend this idea to an infinite-horizon
economy and characterize the set of self-enforcing agreements between
the host government and an MNC (i.e., in a bilateral monopoly environment). The contract specifies the level of investment the MNC
should make each period and the amount of output that must be
transferred to the host country. The key is that the host government may
have a short-term gain by reneging on the contract and expropriating
output or capital at any point. In this case, the MNC retaliates by not
investing in the future which entails a long-run cost because the
domestic economy returns to "autarky." The sustainable
contract prescribes that investments should be inefficiently low in the
initial periods with no transfers to the host country. Investment rises
afterward to a stationary level, in which the host country starts
receiving transfers. Investment is pro-cyclical, and transfers are
positively serially correlated. Because the temptation to expropriate is
larger when output is high, the optimal contract offers more transfers
in the future. The back-loading result can be interpreted as a tax
holiday, in which the host country exempts investors from tax
obligations. It provides some direct transfers and allows for duty-free
imports.
Thomas and Worrall's article is closely related to Doyle and
van Wijnbergen (1994) who find tax holidays as the outcome of a
bargaining game between a foreign investor and a small country, but in
which the host country can commit to tax rates for one period. Schnitzer
(1999) obtains a similar result by assuming that the foreign investor
can switch to production facilities in other countries, rather than
assuming commitment to taxes. In contrast to the previous articles, the
self-enforcing contract may exhibit overinvestment.
While the previous studies were mostly concerned with explaining
the level of expropriation, Aguiar, Amador, and Gopinath (2006) focus on
its cyclical properties. The role of the government is to insure the
wages of domestic workers, who do not have access to financial markets
and are subject to output risk. The government can obtain resources from
taxing the MNC's profits (which the authors interpret as an
indirect form of expropriation) and redistributing them as lump sum transfers to workers. They show that the combination of lack of
commitment and incomplete markets results in policy that generates
amplification and prolongation of shocks to output. The
government's credibility not to expropriate is scarcest when the
economy is in a recession, which depresses investment and prolongs
downturns. If the government had the ability to commit to a policy
sequence, it would use countercyclical and undistortionary taxes. When
it lacks commitment, it distorts foreign investment in bad times and
cannot achieve full insurance.
The articles mentioned previously have a common characteristic:
governments are benevolent. Policymakers want to maximize welfare (or
national output), but they cannot achieve the first best because they
are tempted to expropriate too much ex post. The lack of commitment to
policy is the main friction in these studies. One aspect that they do
not address is that such policies cause redistribution within agents in
the host country. Interaction between powerful groups that compete to
gain control and appropriate national resources can lead to another
source of inefficiencies that distort investment decisions. The
political economy game in which a "tragedy of commons" arises,
resulting in suboptimal investment levels, is studied in a series of
articles by Tornell and co-authors. Tornell and Velasco (1992) explain
why, even though poor countries have a higher marginal productivity of
capital, they are subject to capital flights toward richer countries.
Their main idea is that in countries with weak institutions and poor
protection of property rights, some groups can appropriate the returns
of other groups by controlling fiscal policy. By investing some of their
assets in foreign markets, domestic agents can ensure private access and
avoid "overappropriation" (i.e., indirect expropriation) from
other groups. Tornell and Lane (1999) use a similar environment to
explain how this dynamic interaction between groups leads to a slowdown
in economic growth. They show that dilution in the concentration of
power ameliorates this problem, a result in contrast to the traditional
wisdom in models with a common pool problem. The explanation is based on
the fact that groups do not cooperate. So as the number of groups
increases, each group must reduce its appropriation rate to make sure
its rate of return is no lower than that of its outside option (i.e.,
investing in the more inefficient informal sector). These articles are
closer to ours, due to their emphasis on political factors such as
disagreement over redistributive policy across the population of the
host country.
Our article is also closely related to Amador (2003), who finds
that government borrowing is inefficiently high if there is some
probability of losing power in the future. It is also related to
Azzimonti (2005), who provides microfoundations in a probabilistic
voting model for the shortsightedness of parties in an environment in
which the government chooses public investment and the provision of a
consumable public good. The underlying force driving the inefficiency of
policy is common to all three articles; the difference being that in
Azzimonti's environment, investment is chosen by the party in power
and taxes are imposed on the domestic group. In the current article,
investment is made by foreign investors who have an outside option and
the proceeds of expropriating part of it are distributed to a specific
group. The article is also related to a body of literature
characterizing equilibria that rules out reputation. See, for example,
Azzimonti, Sarte, and Soares (2006); Quadrini (2005); or Klein, Krusell,
and Rios-Rull (2004), which characterize Markov-perfect equilibria (the
analogous to our equilibrium concept in an infinite-horizon economy).
Finally, it is related to a set of political economy models in which
redistributive uncertainty results in inefficiencies (see Lizzeri 1999,
Alesina and Tabellini 1990, or Battaglini and Coate forthcoming).
4. THE EXPROPRIATION GAME
In this section, we describe the environment and derive our main
results. We proceed by specifying the timing and then solving for the
subgame-perfect equilibrium through backward induction.
The Environment
The economy is populated by a government, domestic agents, and
foreign capitalists. Agents live for two periods. They are endowed with
both one unit of time each period and e units of the only consumption
good in the economy. We can interpret e as an agent's share of
local production (which is not explicitly modeled). Additional output
can be produced by identical firms interacting in competitive markets.
Shares of these firms are owned by foreign investors who supply capital
(denoted by K) but not labor. The opportunity cost of installing capital
is given by the world interest rate r* that could be obtained by
investing the funds in riskless bonds in international financial
markets. Following Eaton and Gersovitz (1984), we will assume that
"managerial services" are the intangible assets that foreign
investors bring to the production process: organizational skills,
technological knowledge, access to overseas markets, etc. The main
difference between managerial skills and physical capital is that the
former cannot be expropriated by the government. More importantly, if
expropriation occurs, the managerial services of the foreign capitalist
are no longer available for production. This implies that any capital
expropriated by the government becomes unproductive, because either the
domestic worker does not have the necessary skills to run production by
himself or because the capital installed by the foreign investor was
specific to the manager's skills. Therefore, it cannot be used to
produce using the foreign technology.
Production requires two inputs, domestic labor L and capital K and
uses the following technology:
Assumption 1 The production function satisfies
f(K, L) = A[K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.1-[alpha]].
Domestic agents (the workers) supply labor inelastically at the
competitive wage rate w, and have no international mobility. Each
belongs to one of n groups (we can also interpret a group as a
collection of individuals residing in one of n districts), with total
population normalized to one. Agents are identical, so for symmetry we
will assume that there is a measure 1/n of agents per group or district.
Their preferences over consumption satisfy standard assumptions, as
shown below.
Assumption 2 Instantaneous utility is logarithmic and additively
separable, and agents discount the future at rate [beta] [member of] (0,
1). Thus,
u([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2]) = log([c.sub.1]) + [beta] log([c.sub.2]).
As described in Section 2, expropriation can take two forms: (1)
direct expropriation, in which the government takes part or all of the
already installed capital, and (2) creeping expropriation, in which
transnational corporations are required to pay bribes or licenses that
allow them to produce in the host country. Notice that while the former
takes place after investment decisions have been made, the latter takes
place beforehand. This asymmetry will have important implications
regarding the effects of electoral uncertainty on expropriation rates.
We will model both forms of expropriation as proportional rates.
The government will demand a proportion [tau] out of total investment to
be paid by any firm that intends to produce in the country. Notice that
we refer to it as a bribe, but in terms of the modeling technique, it is
observationally equivalent to an investment tax. The rate at which
installed capital is expropriated ex post will be denoted by [theta].
Notice that activities are homogeneous in this model, so the host
country expropriates all activities at the same rate. (4)
The resources collected by either form of expropriation are used to
provide lump sum transfers that can be targeted toward different groups
in the population. We will denote the transfer that group i receives, as
a function of the expropriation rate, by [T.sup.i] ([theta]).
Assumption 3 A group's objective, when in power, is to
maximize the utility of its members.
The government expropriates FDI and distributes the proceeds
between agents residing in different districts in the country. Two
remarks are relevant at this point.
First, even though the expropriation rate by acting as an
investment tax distorts the optimal allocation of capital, it serves as
an instrument to transfer resources from foreign investors to local
workers. The government, who only cares about the well-being of domestic
agents, might be willing to compromise future production (that will be
reduced because inflows of K decrease) in order to collect part of the
dividends that would otherwise go to the hands of foreigners. This
tradeoff will determine the optimal level of creeping expropriation
chosen over time. Notice that the dynamic nature of the game implies
that, in general, it would not be optimal for the government to require
bribes at a level where investment in the country drops to zero (that
is, a [tau] that drives I = 0). Given the assumptions on technology, it
would also never be optimal to expropriate capital completely ex post.
An important assumption behind this result is the fact that domestic
agents cannot produce with the transnational corporation's
technology, as described previously.
This environment is a stylized version of an economy where output
can be produced with a domestic technology and a (possibly superior)
foreign technology. Because we want to focus on the problem of
expropriation, rather than on the dynamics of the labor market, we
assume that agents are simply endowed with e units of the good and
supply labor, inelastically, to foreign firms. It would be interesting
to analyze, as an extension, the case in which labor decisions are
endogenous and domestic firms compete with transnational corporations
for domestic labor. Reallocation of workers from one sector to another
after expropriation will cause some distortions--and probably benefit
some types of workers while hurting others--that are ignored in the
following analysis.
Secondly, since transfers can be targeted toward specific
districts, it is reasonable to expect each region to lobby in order to
obtain them. The disagreement over how the budget should be allocated
across districts can be resolved by some form of voting. One way to
model this would be by assuming that there are n parties, each one
representing a district that alternates in power according to a Markov
process. Amador (2003) presents a model with symmetric parties that want
to maximize the group's consumption and face some probability of
being in power at each point in time (election dates are uncertain).
Once in power, the elected party chooses policy so as to maximize the
utility of its constituency. Azzimonti (2005) provides microfoundations
for the probabilities in a model of endogenous voting (but in which
elections occur at regular intervals). An alternative approach,
presented in Battaglini and Coate (forthcoming), assumes that
legislators representing a district bargain in congress over
redistribution of the budget. These approaches share the property that
redistributive uncertainty--captured by the probability of being the
decisionmaker in the following period--plays a key role in the level of
distortions imposed by policy because of the shortsightedness it
introduces.
The sequence of events can be divided into four stages as described
below.
Timing
* Period 1:
1. Creeping Expropriation Stage: the group in power decides the
level of bribes they will demand from foreign investors, [tau].
2. Investment Stage: foreign firms decide how much to invest, I, in
the host country. Bribes are collected, targeted transfers
[T.sub.1.sup.i] are made, and consumption [c.sub.1] takes place.
* Period 2:
1. Expropriation Stage: one of the groups gains control of the
government and expropriates a proportion [theta] of already installed
capital.
2. Post-Expropriation Stage: the good is produced, wages are paid,
targeted transfers [T.sub.2.sup.i] are made, and consumption [c.sub.2]
takes place.
Notice that we are assuming that there is no transnational
corporation in Period 1, so consumption at that point will be the sum of
the endowment an agent possesses and the transfers it obtains from the
government (that collected resources in the form of creeping
expropriation). We made this assumption to simplify the exposition, but
the model can easily be extended to a case in which the government can
also expropriate capital installed in the first period of a firm that
invested in the country at some point in the past.
We will solve the problem by backward induction, starting from the
last stage in Period 2.
The Second Period
Post-Expropriation Stage
This subsection describes the optimization problem faced by the
manager of a representative firm. Considering a particular specification
for technology and preferences, it characterizes a competitive
equilibrium given the expropriation rate and transfers for this economy.
At this stage, the government has already expropriated [theta] K
out of the total capital stock, hence the firm produces with the
remaining amount of capital (1 - [theta])K [equivalent to] [~.K]. Firms
take prices (the wage rate for local workers w) as given, and demand
labor in the local market to maximize profits
max f([~.K], L) + (1 - [delta])[~.K] - wL,
where [delta] denotes the depreciation rate of capital.
The FOC is
[f.sub.L]([~.K], L) = w,
so labor is paid its marginal productivity. For our given
production function, this is equivalent to
(1 - [alpha]) A[~.K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.-[alpha]] = w.
Notice that since [~.K] [less than or equal to] K, the wage rate
goes down after an expropriation. This occurs because with a lower level
of capital installed, workers are less productive (this would hold for
any arbitrary function that satisfies [f.sub.LK] > 0).
Recall that agents do not have access to capital markets, so their
only income is wage income wl, where l = 1 is the individual labor
supply, plus any transfers [T.sub.2.sup.i] received from the government.
Their budget constraint can be written as
[c.sub.2.sup.i] = e + w + [T.sub.2.sup.i].
Proposition 1 A competitive equilibrium given policy {[theta],
{[T.sub.2.sup.i] ([theta])}[.sub.i=1.sup.n]}, is a set of prices {w} and
allocations {L, {[c.sub.2.sup.i]}[.sub.i=1.sup.n]} such that
1. consumption of agent i satisfies
[c.sub.2.sup.i] = e + w + [T.sub.2.sup.i]([theta]),
2. labor supply is L = 1,
3. wages are competitive
w = (1 - [alpha]) A[H.sup.[eta]][~.K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.-[alpha]],
and (1)
4. the government's budget constraint holds
[n.summation over (i=1)] [1/n][T.sub.2.sup.i]([theta]) = [theta]K.
Expropriation Stage
This is the stage in which after a group gains power, it chooses
the proportion [theta] of total capital to be expropriated. (5) A
group's objective is to maximize the utility of its supporters.
This implies that, while they do not put any weight on the welfare of
other regions or groups, policymakers are "benevolent
planners" for their own region. (6)
It is assumed that there is no commitment technology: once in
power, the group will choose what is best for its constituency from that
point on, taking the capital stock as given. This implies that promises
made before the political uncertainty is resolved are not credible. In
particular, groups cannot credibly promise to transfer resources to
other regions in the future. As a result, it is in no group's
interest to provide transfers to regions different than its own once it
is in power. Mathematically, this implies that group i will optimally
set
[T.sub.2.sup.j] = 0 for j [not equal to] i.
This is the case because (1) groups do not derive utility from the
well-being of other regions, and (2) because they cannot sign binding
contracts with other groups over policy.
The government balances its budget, so the total amount
expropriated is divided among the members of the group controlling the
government. In other words,
[1/n][T.sub.2.sup.i] = [theta]K.
The maximization problem of the group in power at this point (where
we have omitted the i subscripts for clarity) is
[max.[theta]] u([c.sub.2]) s.t.,
[c.sub.2] = e + w + [T.sub.2],
[T.sub.2] = n[theta]K, and
[theta] [less than or equal to] 1,
where w satisfies equation (1). Replacing the constraints above, we
can simplify the objective function to u(e + w + n[theta]K). This
implies that at the second stage the government maximizes utility by
maximizing per capita consumption of the group it represents, so the
problem becomes simply
[max.[[theta][less than or equal to]1]]{e + w + n[theta]K}.
The first-order condition is
[[partial derivative]w/[partial derivative][theta]] + [[[partial
derivative][T.sub.2]]/[partial derivative][theta]] [less than or equal
to] 0 (= 0 if [theta] < 1).
The marginal benefit of increasing the expropriation rate is given
by the extra consumption that can be afforded by an increase in the
transfer,
MB [equivalent to] [[partial derivative][T.sub.2]]/[partial
derivative][theta] = nK > 0.
Notice that the marginal benefit is independent of the level of
[theta]. Graphically, it can be represented by a horizontal line (see
Figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The marginal cost is given by a decrease in the agent's labor
income due to a reduction in the domestic wage rate,
MC [equivalent to] -[[partial derivative]w/[partial
derivative][theta]] = -[[partial derivative]w/[partial
derivative][~.K]][[[partial derivative][~.K]]/[partial
derivative][theta]], and
= (1 - [alpha])[alpha]A (1 - [theta])[.sup.[alpha]-1]
[K.sup.[alpha]].
This function is increasing and convex in the rate of expropriation
as long as [alpha] < 1, as typically assumed with a Cobb-Douglas
production technology. Moreover, because the MC becomes infinitely large
as [theta] [right arrow] 1, the intersection between the two curves will
occur at an interior point (again, refer to Figure 1).
The optimal level of expropriation is found by equating the
marginal costs and benefits of increasing [theta].
(1 - [alpha]) [alpha]A (1 - [theta])[.sup.[alpha]-1]
[K.sup.[alpha]] = nK.
Proposition 2 The optimal expropriation rate is given by
[[theta].sup.E] = 1 - [1/K] [[1/n] (1 -
[alpha])[alpha]A][.sup.1/[1-[alpha]]].
Thus, it is not optimal for any group in power to fully expropriate
foreign investment. That is, [[theta].sup.E] < 1.
Since all other groups are identical, the amount of expropriation
in this economy is independent of the identity of the group in power. An
interesting extension would be to analyze the case in which sectors were
heterogeneous, either in their capital intensity or in the ability of
the government to expropriate them. In this case, workers would also be
heterogeneous and disagree on the rate of expropriation (and not only on
where to target the transfers).
The First Period
Recall that there are two relevant stages in this period:
investment and creeping expropriation stages. We discuss them in the
following section.
Investment Stage
We now move to the decision problem of a foreign firm considering
whether the project is worth pursuing in the host country. Expropriation
affects this decision on two margins. On the one hand, the cost of
investment is increased by the proportion of bribes that will need to be
paid to the group in power. On the other hand, the future returns of
such investment will be reduced by the fact that some proportion of
capital will be expropriated in the second period.
Firms discount the future at the rate 1/[1+r*], as r* represents
their outside option. The maximization problem faced by an investor at
this stage is
[max.I] - I(1 + [tau]) + [1/[1 + r*]] [pi](I) s.t.,
[pi](I) = f([~.I], L) + (1 - [delta])[~.I] - wL, and
[~.I] = (1 - [theta])I.
The cost of the investment is incurred today, while the benefits
[pi](I) are received next period, which is why they are discounted. The
investor knows that for each unit of investment, he will need to pay a
proportion [tau] today in bribes or permits. He also knows that for each
unit of capital installed, only a fraction (1 - [theta]) will be
productive: the rest is expropriated by the host country.
The assumption of atomistic competitive investors implies that the
action of one of them does not affect the level of expropriation. In
other words, each takes [theta] and [tau] as given (for the case where
the transnational corporation has monopoly, and hence bargaining power,
see Doyle and van Wijnbergen 1984 or Thomas and Worrall 1994). The
first-order condition for an investor is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Therefore, the transnational corporation equates the marginal cost
of investment to the discounted value of the marginal benefit received
from its investment opportunity. A marginal increase in installed
capital causes an increase in benefits of
[partial derivative][pi](I)/[partial derivative]I = (1 - [theta])
[[f.sub.I]([~.I], L) + (1 - [delta])].
The right-hand side is the marginal increase in production, plus
the marginal increase in undepreciated capital, all multiplied by the
proportion (1 - [theta]) that can be utilized. We can interpret [theta]
[[f.sub.I]([~.I], L) + (1 - [delta])] as the opportunity cost of
expropriation: it represents the amount of potential benefits that the
foreign investor could have obtained if it was not expropriated.
Notice that this value introduces a wedge-distorting investment
decision: it produces inefficiencies. This can be seen more clearly from
the following equation in which we have replaced the marginal benefit
and rearranged the optimality condition:
[f.sub.I]([~.I], L) + (1 - [delta]) = (1 + r*) (1 + [tau])[1/(1 -
[theta])].
Under our functional forms and noting that in equilibrium I = K,
the optimality condition becomes
[alpha]((1 - [theta])K)[.sup.[alpha]-1] A + (1 - [delta]) = [(1 +
r*)(1 + [tau])]/(1 - [theta]).
Lemma 1 The optimal level of investment under expropriation is
[K.sup.E] = ([[alpha]A(1 - [theta])[.sup.[alpha]]]/[(1 + r*)(1 +
[tau]) - (1 - [delta])(1 - [theta])])[.sup.1/[1-[alpha]]].
If there was no expropriation, a foreign firm would invest
[K.sup.NE] (where NE stands for "no expropriation").
[K.sup.NE] = ([alpha]A/[(1 + r*) (1 + [tau]) - (1 -
[delta])])[.sup.1/[1-[alpha]]] > [K.sup.E].
As expected, expropriation discourages investment in the host
country. We can now replace [theta] by [[theta].sup.E] to find the value
of FDI in equilibrium,
[K.sup.E] = [phi](n)/[1 + [tau]],
where
[phi](n) = [1/[1 + r*]](A[alpha][(1 -
[alpha])/n])[.sup.1/[1-[alpha]]] [1 - [delta] + [n/[1-[alpha]]]]. (2)
Creeping Expropriation Stage
At this stage, it is the group in power in Period 1 that decides
the level of bribes [tau], which it will demand from potential
investors. There are two main differences between the tradeoffs faced by
policymakers at this point, relative to those faced in the second
period, when choosing (ex post) direct expropriation. First, because
capital has not yet been installed, FDI is more "elastic."
Given the outside opportunities faced by investors, this imposes a
constraint on the level of bribes, which in principle, should decrease
the temptation to extract too many resources from multinational
corporations. Because of this, we would expect creeping expropriation to
be less harmful than direct expropriation. On the other hand, the group
decides on the level of [tau] without knowing whether it will be in
power next period. This introduces uncertainty over who will have
control of the expropriation technology in the second period. More
importantly, it introduces uncertainty on the identity of the group
receiving the benefits of such expropriation. With probability 1 - p,
another group gains control and distributes resources only toward its
own region. This second difference with respect to direct expropriation,
given by the existence of redistributional uncertainty, induces greater
expropriation in the present through bribes by any group in power in
Period 1. Therefore, it is not clear which type of expropriation is more
distortive at the end.
Before solving for the optimal level of [tau], we need to specify
the process by which groups gain control of the government. In this
article, we will assume that groups alternate in power according to a
stochastic Markov process: the probability of being the decisionmaker
next period, given that the group in power today is denoted by p. Notice
that this reduced-form specification is silent on whether groups gain
control via a democratic process in which parties compete for elections,
or the turnover follows from revolutions and coups following a
nondemocratic (and possibly violent) process.
Consider the problem faced by a representative group in power in
Period 1. It needs to choose the creeping expropriation rate [tau] on
FDI inflows, taking as given the behavior of the domestic sector and
foreign firms, as well as competitive prices and aggregates. In
particular, it needs to take into account the effects of the bribes and
other forms of creeping expropriation chosen based on the following:
1. The consumption of its constituency when the group is in power,
because it is maximizing its utility
[c.sub.1] = e + [T.sub.1], and
[c.sub.2] = e + w + [T.sub.2].
2. The consumption of its constituency when the group is out of
power, because there is a probability that next period a different group
is in power,
[~.c.sub.2] = e + w.
3. FDI inflows, I = [K.sup.E] (in equilibrium), because foreign
investors decide after knowing the level of [tau]
[K.sup.E] = [phi](n)/[1 + [tau]],
where [phi](n) is defined in equation (2).
4. Transfers to the region it represents, via the government budget
constraint
[T.sub.1] = [tau]n[K.sup.E] and
[T.sub.2] = [[theta].sup.E]n[K.sup.E].
5. Second period's expropriation rate [[theta].sup.E],
[[theta].sup.E] = 1 - 1/[K.sup.E] [[1/n](1 -
[alpha])[alpha]A][.sup.1/[1-[alpha]]].
6. Equilibrium prices, because they affect their
constituency's consumption
w = (1 - [alpha])A[(1 - [[theta].sup.E])[K.sup.E]][.sup.[alpha]].
The group solves
[max.[tau]]u([c.sub.1]) + [beta]{pu([c.sub.2]) + (1 -
p)u([~.c.sub.2])},
subject to the conditions listed above.
The first-order condition reads as
[u.sub.c]([c.sub.1])[[d[c.sub.1]]/d[tau]] +
[beta]{p[u.sub.c]([c.sub.2])[[d[c.sub.2]]/d[tau]] + (1 -
p)[u.sub.c]([~.c.sub.2])[d[~.c.sub.2]]/d[tau]} = 0.
When the rate of creeping expropriation increases today, there is a
direct effect in agents' consumption--captured in the first term of
the expression--since those favored by the group in control receive an
increase in the transfer of
[d[T.sub.1]]/d[tau] = [n[K.sup.E]]/[1 + [tau]].
Firms react to a larger [tau] by cutting FDI,
dI/d[tau] = -[[K.sup.E]/[1 + [tau]]].
This reduces the amount of capital available for production next
period (recall that dI/d[tau] = [d[K.sup.E]]/d[tau]), which modifies
tomorrow's consumption because the next policymaker will face a
lower tax base, and thus be forced to reduce the level of transfers
[T.sub.2]. Moreover, from condition 5 this triggers a reduction in
direct expropriation ([[theta].sup.E]) as well. The total effect in
transfers is given by
[d[T.sub.2]]/d[tau] = n[[K.sup.E][[d[[theta].sup.E]]/d[tau]] +
[[theta].sup.E][[K.sup.E]/d[tau]]] and
= -[[n[K.sup.E]]/[1 + [tau]]].
Notice that since (1 - [[theta].sup.E])[K.sup.E] is independent of
[tau] (see condition 5 above), then from condition 6 so is w. Because
second period wages are unaffected by creeping expropriation, the level
of consumption when a group is out of power is independent of [tau]. In
other words, [d[~.c.sub.2]]/d[tau] = 0, so the last term in the
first-order condition cancels out. The fact that [bar.c.sub.2] is
independent of the level of bribes is a result of the particular
assumption on preferences, because under logarithmic utility income and
substitution effects cancel out. This results in optimal direct
expropriation rates being inversely proportional to the stock of
capital, so (1 - [theta])K is constant and independent of [tau].
Replacing u by a logarithmic utility, we obtain the following lemma:
Lemma 2 Under assumption 2, redistributional uncertainty introduces
a wedge in the efficient growth rate of consumption since, in the
political equilibrium
[c.sub.2] = [beta]p[c.sub.1].
Absent the redistributional uncertainty (i.e., where groups act in
a coordinated fashion) the government would choose policy so that
[c.sub.2] = [beta][c.sub.1]. Because p < 1, the equation above shows
that the ratio of consumption between the two periods is suboptimally
low. In other words, the political uncertainty makes policymakers too
impatient.
Proposition 3 Under assumptions 1 and 2, the optimal rate of
creeping expropriation is given by
[tau] = [[gamma](n) - e[beta]p]/[(1 + [beta]p)n[phi](n) -
[gamma](n) + e[beta]p],
where
[gamma](n) = n[phi](n) [1 + [[(1+r*)(1 - [alpha])]/[[alpha][1 -
[delta] + n/[1-[alpha]]]]]] + e.
Expropriation and Political Instability
Political instability refers to the frequency by which groups
alternate in power. Countries facing high turnover rates are those where
p is relatively small. Why is this the case? Because the probability
that any given group remains in control of the government in the second
period is low.
In this section, we analyze the implications of political
instability on the level of expropriation predicted by the model and
contrast it to what the empirical literature has found.
Proposition 4 characterizes how each rate of expropriation changes
with p.
Proposition 4 Under assumptions 1 and 2, we can show that
1. creeping expropriation is larger in countries with greater
political instability (i.e., low p)
d[tau]/dp < 0, and
2. direct expropriation is lower in countries with greater
political instability
d[theta]/dp > 0.
We can understand the intuition behind the negative relationship
between the amount of bribes and permits demanded by foreign investors
[tau], and the probability of keeping control of the government p, by
looking at the expression in Lemma 2. When the group in power faces
relatively low political instability, the chances of being able to
appropriate transfers next period are large. In this case, policymakers
want to increase relative consumption (i.e., the ratio
[c.sub.2]/[c.sub.1]). The change in p is equivalent to an increase in
the degree of patience of the group in power. Consumption in the second
period becomes relatively cheaper, creating a substitution effect toward
less consumption today and more consumption tomorrow. Due to market
incompleteness, the only way to achieve this transfer of resources is
via a reduction in the degree of creeping expropriation today, by
lowering [T.sub.1] and, thus, [c.sub.1]. Because transnational
corporations bring human capital and technology, they are more efficient
in production than the local country. It is then optimal for any group
to wait and expropriate after investments have been made when p
increases, because the proportion of investment that will not be
expropriated ex post will be productive: [K.sup.E] increases with lower
[tau] rates. If the country had access to borrowing and lending, this
effect would be reduced, but nonetheless, present. Therefore, we should
expect that countries with low turnover impose relatively low barriers
to FDI inflows--that is, require lower bribes and make construction and
production permits cheaper to foreign investors.
The effect of p on direct expropriation is more subtle and has to
do with inter-group manipulation. Because [theta] is chosen after the
political uncertainty has been resolved, it is, in principle, unaffected
by p. There is no direct effect of turnover on expropriation ex post.
Indirectly, however, increases in p reduce creeping expropriation in the
first period and attract more FDI. In other words, [K.sup.E] increases.
Because there is a larger tax base, the MB of expropriating in Period 2
increases. The marginal cost also increases but in a lower proportion
(this is due to the Cobb-Douglas technology assumption). As a result,
[theta] goes up. Another way to understand the intuition behind this
second result is to consider the costs and benefits of the group
deciding today. If p is relatively low, another group will gain control
in Period 2 with high probability. If the current group happens to be
out of power tomorrow (a likely event), direct expropriation imposes
large costs in terms of reduced production and no benefits, because no
transfers are received. There are incentives, therefore, to manipulate
future decisions by affecting the stock of capital inherited by
tomorrow's policymaker and make direct expropriation less
attractive. From the expression in condition 5, Section 4, this can be
achieved by decreasing [K.sup.E]. How can the group controlling the
government in Period 1 reduce future capital? This can be accomplished
by making FDI less attractive--increasing the barriers to its entrance.
We should, therefore, expect a negative correlation between political
instability and direct expropriation rates.
Notice that this analysis is partial in the sense that we are only
considering a once-and-for-all investment decision. There is no action
that a government in the second period can take to undo the manipulation
of the first period policymaker. In an economy with a longer horizon, in
which investment decisions were made every period, the group in power in
Period 2 could also demand bribes and permits, and thus break the link
between first period bribes and the allocation of foreign capital in the
country. That possibility would give groups controlling the government
in Period 2 an extra degree of freedom. It would then be interesting to
extend the analysis to a case with an infinite-horizon economy.
Expropriation and Concentration of Power
The previous section assumed that differences in political
instability only correspond to political factors and were independent of
other fundamentals of the economy. In a model where such probability was
endogenized, we would expect p to be related to the number of groups in
the economy, n. If there were many groups fighting for power, given the
same aggregate size of the population, the probability of keeping
control of the government would probably be low, and we already know the
effects this reduction has on expropriation. On the other hand, a larger
value of n implies that if a given group happened to gain control, then
the benefits of expropriation per member in the group would increase
because per capita transfers would be larger. This implies that, in
principle, the relation between concentration of power and expropriation
could be non-monotonic.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
We have calculated how creeping expropriation changes as we reduce
the concentration of power for a numerical example (the parameter values
were not calibrated but rather chosen to illustrate our point). The
probability of staying in power faced by any group is assumed to satisfy
p = [1/n] + [xi],
where [xi] represents an "incumbency advantage" term,
reflecting the fact that the group in power has greater chances to gain
control next period than any other group in the opposition. The
political economy literature has documented the existence of such an
advantage in democratic elections. In more authoritarian systems, we
often see groups or families in control of the government for long
periods of time because they have access to military force and other
means of repression. Increases in [xi] can be interpreted as changes in
political instability not related to the concentration of power, which
were studied in the previous section, whereas the effects of
concentration can be analyzed separately by looking at the effects of
changes in n.
Inspection of Figure 2 tells us that when there is relatively large
concentration of power (i.e., n close to 2), increases in the number of
groups result in more expropriation of both types. This happens because
larger values of n reduce p and, from the intuition in the previous
section, this encourages creeping expropriation activities, that is,
rises in [tau]. On the other hand, when there is little concentration of
power, increases in the number of groups in a given economy result in
lower levels of [tau]. While the probability of remaining in power
decreases with n, transfers per capita increase, but in a larger
proportion and, therefore, dominate. Even though each group is less
likely to stay in power, the benefits of expropriating in Period 1 more
than compensate the costs driven by an increase in the risk of losing
control of the government in Period 2. This result is different from the
one found in the previous section, and it gives a direct testable
implication of the model. If countries have greater political
instability because there is low incumbency advantage, more creeping
expropriation is to be expected. If, on the other hand, it is due to the
composition of competing groups, and there is a relatively large number
of them, then we should expect less creeping expropriation as political
instability increases.
5. CONCLUSIONS
We reviewed the empirical evidence on the effects of expropriation
on FDI inflows, mainly focusing on developing countries. We then
discussed theoretical models explaining how the quality of institutions
affects FDI and growth. In particular, we described how the different
frictions present in the political process result in policies that
discourage FDI inflows. Finally, we presented a simple model that sheds
some light on the effects of expropriation on FDI under: (1) lack of
commitment to policy from the government, (2) redistributional
uncertainty resulting from stochastic alternation of groups in power,
and (3) the interaction between alternative forms of expropriation. The
main contribution of this work is twofold: the analysis of a model in
which both direct and indirect forms of expropriation are present and
the study of how the two types of expropriation relate to political
instability. We also discussed the effects of the concentration of power
on the incentives to use each type of expropriation and their resulting
effects on investment.
REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, Manuel Amador, and Gita Gopinath. 2006.
"Efficient Expropriation: Sustainable Fiscal Policy in a Small Open
Economy." Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper 06-9.
Alesina, Alberto, and Guido Tabellini. 1990. "A Positive
Theory of Fiscal Deficits and Government Debt." Review of Economic
Studies 57 (3): 403-14.
Amador, Manuel. 2003. "A Political Economy Model of Sovereign
Debt Repayment." Mimeo, Stanford Graduate School of Business.
Asiedu, Elizabeth. 2006. "Foreign Direct Investment in Africa:
The Role of Natural Resources, Market Size, Government Policy,
Institutions and Political Instability." World Economy 29 (1):
63-77.
Azzimonti, Marina. 2005. "On the Dynamic Inefficiency of
Governments." Mimeo, University of Iowa.
Azzimonti, Marina, Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte, and Jorge Soares. 2006.
"Distortionary Taxes and Public Investment When Government Promises
Are Not Enforceable." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Battaglini, Marco, and Steve Coate. Forthcoming. "A Dynamic
Model of Legislative Bargaining." The American Economic Review.
Biais, Bruno, and Enrico Perotti. 2002. "Machiavellian
Privatization." The American Economic Review 92 (1): 240-58.
Busse, Matthias, and Carsten Hefeker. Forthcoming. "Political
Risk, Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment." European Journal
of Political Economy.
Chifor, George. 2002. "Caveat Emptor: Developing International
Disciplines for Deterring Third Party Investment in Unlawfully
Expropriated Property." Law and Policy in International Business 33
(2).
Corkran, Douglas E. 1991. "Tanzania Opens its Doors to U.S.
Business." Business America 1 (July): 11.
Daude, Christian, and Ernesto Stein. 2001. "The Quality of
Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment." Paper presented at the
2001 Annual Meeting of the Inter-American Development Bank. Santiago,
Chile.
Doyle, Christopher, and Sweder van Wijnbergen. 1994. "Taxation
of Foreign Multinationals: A Sequential Bargaining Approach to Tax
Holidays." International Tax and Public Finance 1 (3): 211-25.
Eaton, Jonathan, and Mark Gersovitz. 1984. "A Theory of
Expropriation and Deviations from Perfect Capital Mobility."
Economic Journal 94 (373): 16-40.
Gordon, H. Scott. 1954. "The Economic Theory of a
Common-Property Resource: The Fishery." Journal of Political
Economy 62 (2): 124-42.
Hausmann, Ricardo, and Eduardo Fernandez-Arias. 2000. "Foreign
Direct Investment: Good Cholesterol?" Inter-American Development
Bank, Research Department Working Paper No. 417, Washington, DC.
Hines, James R. 1995. "Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and
American Business After 1977." NBER Working Paper No.W5266.
Janeba, Eckhard. 2002. "Attracting FDI in a Politically Risky
World." International Economic Review 43 (4): 1,127-55.
Jensen, Nathan. 2005. "Measuring Risk: Political Risk
Insurance Premiums and Domestic Political Institutions." Mimeo,
Washington University.
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton. 1999.
"Governance Matters." World Bank. Mimeo WPS2196.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1969. American Business Abroad: Six
Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Klein, Paul, Per Krusell, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull. 2004.
"Time-Consistent Public Expenditures." CEPR Discussion Paper
No. 4582.
Kobrin, Stephen J. 1980. "Foreign Enterprise and Forced
Divestment in LDCs." International Organization 34 (1): 65-88.
Kobrin, Stephen J. 1984. "Expropriation as an Attempt to
Control Foreign Firms in LDCs: Trends from 1960 to 1979."
International Studies Quarterly 28 (3): 329-48.
Lancaster, Kelvin. 1973. "The Dynamic Inefficiency of
Capitalism." Journal of Political Economy 81 (5): 1,092-109.
Li, Quan. 2004. "Democracy, Autocracy, and Tax Incentives to
Foreign Direct Investors: A Cross-National Analysis." Mimeo,
Pennsylvania State University.
Li, Quan, and Adam Resnick. 2003. "Reversal of Fortunes:
Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to
Developing Countries." International Organization 57 (1): 175-212.
Lizzeri, Alessandro. 1999. "Budget Deficits and Redistributive
Politics." Review of Economic Studies 66 (4): 909-28.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1990. "Why Doesn't Capital Flow
from Rich to Poor Countries?" The American Economic Review 80 (2):
92-6.
Mauro, Paolo. 1995. "Corruption and Growth." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 110 (3): 681-712.
Minor, Michael S. 1994. "The Demise of Expropriation as an
Instrument of LDC Policy, 1980-1992." Journal of International
Business Studies 25 (1): 177-88.
Moran, Theodore H., ed. 2004. International Political Risk
Management: The Brave New World. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 2004.
"Indirect Expropriation and the Right to Regulate in International
Investment Law." OECD Working Paper on International Investment No.
2004/4.
Quadrini, Vincenzo. 2005. "Policy Commitment and the Welfare
Gains from Capital Market Liberalization." European Economic Review
49 (8): 1,927-51.
Raff, Horst, and Krishna Srinivasan. 1998. "Tax Incentives for
Import-Substituting Foreign Investment: Does Signaling Play a
Role?" Journal of Public Economics 67 (2): 167-93.
Robertson, Dario, and Xiaokang Chen. 1990. "New Amendments to
China's Equity Joint Venture Law." East Asian Excecutive
Reports 15 (April): 9-13.
Schlemmer-Schulte, Sabine. 1999. "The World Bank Guidelines on
the Treatment of Foreign Direct Investment." In Legal Aspects of
Foreign Direct Investment, eds. Daniel D. Bradlow and Alfred D. Escher.
The Hague, The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International: 87, 99-100.
Schnitzer, Monika. 1999. "Expropriation and Control Rights: A
Dynamic Model of Foreign Direct Investment." International Journal
of Industrial Organization 17 (8): 1,113-37.
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1993.
"Corruption." Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 599-617.
Thomas, Jonathan, and Timothy Worrall. 1994. "Foreign Direct
Investment and the Risk of Expropriation." Review of Economic
Studies 61 (1): 81-108.
Tornell, Aaron, and Andres Velasco. 1992. "The Tragedy of the
Commons and Economic Growth: Why Does Capital Flow From Poor to Rich
Countries?" Journal of Political Economy 100 (6): 1,208-31.
Tornell, Aaron, and Philip R. Lane. 1999. "Voracity and
Growth." The American Economic Review 89 (1): 22-46.
United Nations. 1996. World Investment Report. New York and Geneva:
The United Nations.
Wei, Shang-Jin. 2000. "How Taxing is Corruption on
International Investors?" The Review of Economics and Statistics 82
(1): 1-11.
We would like to thank Andreas Hornstein, Leonardo Martinez, Borys
Grochulski, and Nashat Moin for their comments. Also, we would like to
thank Kevin Bryan for excellent research assistance. The views expressed
in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System. E-mails: marina-azzimonti@uiowa.edu and
pierre.sarte@rich.frb.org.
(1) The United Nations (1996) reports that 80 percent of the total
investment flowing to developing countries in 1995 was received by only
ten countries.
(2) See Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(2004) for an extensive discussion on the issue.
(3) The United States Overseas Private Investment Corporation
(OPIC) provides investment insurance for U.S. firms.
(4) We are abstracting from the fact that some sectors are more
vulnerable to expropriation than others.
(5) Because groups are homogeneous, we can focus on the problem of
a representative one.
(6) In the political economy literature, these policymakers are
referred to as partisan. An alternative approach, also studied in the
literature, assumes that the leaders' sole objective is to maximize
their probability of controlling the government because they either
obtain some ego-rents from being in power or they can redistribute resources to themselves (kleptocrats).