Quantitative models of sovereign default and the threat of financial exclusion.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos ; Martinez, Leonardo ; Sapriza, Horacio 等
Business cycles in small emerging economies differ from those in
developed economies. Emerging economies feature interest rates that are
higher, more volatile, and countercyclical (interest rates are usually
acyclical in developed economies). These economies also feature higher
output volatility, higher volatility of consumption relative to income,
and more countercyclical net exports. (1) Recent research is trying to
develop a better understanding of these facts, as has been done for U.S.
business cycles.
Because of the high volatility and countercyclicality of the
interest rate, the (state-dependent) borrowing-interest rate menu is a
key ingredient in any model designed to explain the cyclical behavior of
quantities and prices in emerging economies. Some studies assume an
exogenous interest rate. (2) Others provide microfoundations for the
interest rate based on the risk of default. (3) This is the approach
taken by recent quantitative models of sovereign default, which are
based on the framework proposed by Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). (4) These
articles build on the assumption that lenders can punish defaulting
countries by excluding them from international financial markets. The
assumption is controversial on several grounds. First, it appears to be
at odds with the existence of competitive international capital markets
(which is assumed in these models). It is not obvious that competitive
creditors would be able to coordinate cutting off credit to a country
after a default episode. (5) Second, empirical studies suggest that once
other variables are used as controls, market access is not significantly
influenced by previous default decisions (see, for example, Gelos,
Sahay, and Sandleris 2004, Eichengreen and Portes 2000, and Meyersson
2006). (6)
1. SUMMARY OF RESULTS
This article studies the role of the exclusion assumption for
business cycle properties of emerging economies. It first describes the
business cycle properties of a sovereign default model with exclusion
and compares them with those of the same model without exclusion. The
article finds that the presence of exclusion punishment is responsible
for a high fraction of the sovereign debt that can be sustained in
equilibrium. It also finds that the business cycle statistics of the
model are not significantly affected by the exclusion punishment. The
model without exclusion generates annual debt-output ratios of less than
2 percent. Whereas, the model with exclusion generates debt-output
ratios between 4.8 and 6.3 percent. On the other hand, the cyclical
behavior of consumption, output, interest rate, and net exports are not
fundamentally different in the models with and without exclusion. An
additional limitation shared by both model environments is that the
volatility of the interest rate and (to a lesser extent) of the trade
balance are too low compared to the data. This suggests that the
exclusion assumption does not play an important role in these
dimensions, and therefore future studies that do not rely on the threat
of financial exclusion will not necessarily be handicapped in explaining
the business cycle in emerging economies.
The model studied in this article builds on the framework studied
in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), which in turn, quantifies the model
presented by Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). The most appealing feature
about this setup is that it reduces the default decision to a simple
tradeoff between current and future consumption without a major
departure from the workhorse model used for real business cycle analysis
in the last decades. Recent quantitative studies on sovereign default
have shown that this environment can potentially account for important
business cycle features in emerging economies and that it can be
extended to address other issues (such as the optimal maturity structure
of sovereign debt). (7) The framework studied in Aguiar and Gopinath
(2006) is the simplest among the ones presented in recent studies. This
has the advantage of making the discussion of the role of the exclusion
assumption more transparent. (8) On the other hand, this has the
disadvantage of hurting the performance of the model along several
dimensions. Where appropriate, the article explains how the simplifying
assumptions hurt the performance of the model.
This article studies a small open economy endowed with a single
tradable good. As in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), two endowment processes
are considered: a process with shocks to the endowment level and a
process with shocks to the endowment growth rate. The objective of the
government is to maximize the present value of future utility flows of
the representative agent. The government has only one financial
instrument available: it can save or borrow using one-period bonds.
These assets are priced in a competitive market inhabited by a large
number of identical, infinitely lived, risk neutral-lenders. Lenders
have perfect information regarding the economy's endowment. The
government makes two decisions in every period. First, it decides
whether to refuse to pay previously issued debt. Second, it decides how
much to borrow or save. The baseline model features two costs of
defaulting. First, the country may be excluded from capital markets.
Second, it faces an "output loss." The endowment is reduced in
a fixed percentage in the period following a default. The assumption
that countries experience an output loss after a default intends to
capture the disruptions in economic activity entailed by a default
decision. IMF (2002), Kumhof (2004), and Kumhof and Tanner (2005)
discuss how financial crises that lead to severe recessions are
triggered by sovereign default.
This article solves the model with and without the exclusion threat
and compares their behavior. Mechanically, in the model with shocks to
the endowment level, the default decision becomes relatively more
sensitive to the endowment shock once the exclusion threat is eliminated
and, therefore, less sensitive to the debt level. In turn, bond prices
become less sensitive to the borrowing level. On the other hand, in the
model with shocks to the growth rate the default decision becomes
relatively less sensitive to the endowment shock, which increases the
sensitivity of the bond price to the borrowing level. Given that in this
class of models the high sensitivity of the default probability to the
borrowing level limits their quantitative performance, the previous
effects slightly improve the performance of the model with shocks to the
endowment level and deteriorate the performance of the model with shocks
to the growth rate. In spite of this, both models still do not replicate the default rates, the volatility of the trade balance, nor the
volatility of the spread observed in the data.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows. Section 2 introduces
the model. Section 3 presents the parameterization. Section 4 discusses
the case in which the economy can be excluded from capital markets.
Section 5 studies how the implications of the model change when the
economy cannot be threatened with financial exclusion. Section 6
concludes the article.
2. THE MODEL
The environment studied in this article builds on the framework
presented by Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), who study the quantitative
performance of a model of sovereign default based on Eaton and Gersovitz
(1981). Relative to Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), the only difference is
that it is assumed here that there is a single period of output loss
after default--in contrast with the stochastic number of periods of
output loss assumed in their article. The Appendix shows that the
results are not sensitive to this assumption.
The economy receives a stochastic endowment stream of a single
tradable good. The endowment process has two components: a transitory
shock and a trend shock, namely,
[y.sub.t] = [e.sup.zt][[GAMMA].sub.t], (1)
where [y.sub.t] denotes the endowment realization in period t,
[z.sub.t] denotes the transitory shock, and [[GAMMA].sub.t] denotes the
trend component.
The transitory shock [z.sub.t] follows an AR(1) process with
long-run mean [[mu].sub.z], and autocorrelation coefficient |[[rho].sub.z]| < 1, that is,
[z.sub.t] = (1 - [[rho].sub.z])[[mu].sub.z] +
[[rho].sub.z][z.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t.sup.z], (2)
where [[epsilon].sub.t.sup.z] ~ N (0, [[sigma].sub.z.sup.2]).
The trend component evolves according to
[[GAMMA].sub.t] = [g.sub.t][[GAMMA].sub.t-1], (3)
where
ln ([g.sub.t]) = (1 - [[rho].sub.g]) (ln ([[mu].sub.g]) - m) +
[[rho].sub.g]ln ([g.sub.t-1]) + [[epsilon].sub.t], (4)
|[[rho].sub.g]| < 1, [[epsilon].sub.t] ~ N (0,
[[sigma].sub.g.sup.2]), and [[mu].sub.g] =
[1/2][[[sigma].sub.g.sup.2]/[1-[[rho].sub.g.sup.2]]]. (9)
The objective of the government is to maximize the present value of
future utility flows of the representative agent. The representative
agent has preferences that display a constant coefficient of relative
risk aversion:
u (c) = [[c.sup.(1 - [sigma])] - 1]/[1 - [sigma]],
where [sigma] denotes the coefficient of relative risk aversion.
Let [beta] denote the discount factor. To ensure a well-defined problem
it is assumed that
E {[lim.t[right arrow][infinity]][[beta].sup.t] ([y.sub.t])[.sup.(1
- [sigma])]} = 0.
The government makes two decisions in each period. First, it
decides whether to refuse to pay previously issued debt. Second, it
decides how much to borrow or save. As in previous quantitative studies,
it is assumed that the government faces two penalties if it decides to
default. One penalty is that it may be excluded from capital markets.
The second penalty is that it faces an exogenous "output loss"
of [lambda] percent in the period following a default.
The exclusion state evolves as follows. In the default period, the
economy is excluded from capital markets with probability 1 -
[[phi].sub.1], with [[phi].sub.1] [member of] [0, 1]. In every period
that follows a period of exclusion, the economy regains access to
capital markets with probability [phi] [member of] [0, 1] or remains
excluded for one more period with probability 1 - [phi]. (10) This
implies that the expected length of exclusion is given by
[1-[[phi].sub.1]]/[phi]. If the economy was not excluded from financial
markets at the end of the previous period, it is not excluded at the
beginning of the current period.
The government can choose to save or borrow using one-period bonds.
There is a continuum of risk-neutral lenders with "deep
pockets." Each lender can borrow or lend at the risk-free rate r.
Lenders have perfect information regarding the economy's endowment.
The bond price is determined as follows. First, the government announces
how many bonds it wants to issue. Then, lenders offer a price for these
bonds. Finally, the government sells the bonds to one of the lenders who
offered the highest price.
Let b denote the current position in bonds. A negative value of b
denotes that the government was an issuer of bonds in the previous
period. Each bond delivers one unit of good next period for a price of
[q.sub.d] (b', z, [GAMMA], g) this period. The price depends on the
current default decision, d. This is due to the fact that a current
default decreases future output and affects future default decisions.
The government compares two continuation values in order to decide
whether to default or pay back the previously issued debt. The present
discounted utility after a default is represented by [V.sub.1] (z,
[GAMMA], g, h). The variable h denotes the credit history of the
government. It takes a value of 1 when the government defaulted in the
previous period, and it takes a value of 0 when the government did not
default in the previous period. The present discounted utility when all
previously issued debt is paid back is represented by [V.sub.0] (b, z,
[GAMMA], g, h). The government defaults if the continuation value
[V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h) is larger than [V.sub.0] (b, z, [GAMMA], g,
h) and does not default otherwise.
Let x denote the exclusion state. The variable x takes a value of 1
when the economy is excluded, and takes a value of 0 otherwise. Let V(b,
z, [GAMMA], g, h, x) denote the government's value function at the
beginning of a period.
In the period it defaults, the economy can or cannot be excluded
from financial markets. Let [~.V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h, 0) denote the
continuation value when the economy defaulted and is not excluded. Let
[~.V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h, 1) denote the continuation value when it
is excluded. Thus,
[V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h) = [[phi].sub.1][~.V.sub.1] (z,
[GAMMA], g, h, 0) + (1 - [[phi].sub.1]) [~.V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h,
1). (5)
The timing of the decisions within a period is summarized in Figure
1. At the beginning of the period the endowment shocks are realized. The
realization in period t of a state variable x is denoted by [x.sub.t].
After observing the endowment realization, the government decides
whether to pay back previously issued debt. If it decides to pay the
debt back, the government issues an amount [b.sub.t+1.sup.N D] of bonds
and faces a continuation value of [V.sub.0] ([b.sub.t+1.sup.N D],
[z.sub.t], [[GAMMA].sub.t], [g.sub.t], 0). If the government defaults,
it may or may not be excluded from capital markets today. If it is not
excluded, it faces a continuation value of [~.V.sub.1] ([z.sub.t],
[[GAMMA].sub.t], [g.sub.t], 1, 0,). If it is excluded, it faces a
continuation value of [~.V.sub.1] ([z.sub.t], [[GAMMA].sub.t],
[g.sub.t], 1, 1,). If the government defaults and is not excluded today
from capital markets, it issues an amount [b.sub.t+1.sup.D] of bonds.
After a default, the government faces an output loss of [lambda] percent
in period t + 1 regardless of whether it was excluded from capital
markets in period t.
The value function of a defaulting economy that is excluded in the
default period is computed as follows:
[~.V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h, 1) = u (y (1 - h[lambda])) + [beta]E
[V(0, z', g'[GAMMA], g', 1, e)], (6)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
where
E [V(0,z',g'[GAMMA],g',1,e)] = [integral] [integral]
[[phi]V (0,z',g'[GAMMA],g', 1,0)+(1 - [phi]) V (0,
z', g'[GAMMA], g', 1, 1)] [F.sub.z] (dz' | z)
[F.sub.g] (dg' | g).
If the government has decided to default and is excluded in the
period of default, it consumes the aggregate endowment (there are no
financial transfers from or to the rest of the world) and carries zero
debt to the next period. At the beginning of the following period,
exclusion finishes with probability [phi]. The expected continuation
value of this scenario is V(0, z, g[GAMMA], g, 1, 0). If the exclusion
time is extended, the expected continuation value is V(0, z, g[GAMMA],
g, 1, 1).
The dynamic programming problem for a defaulting economy that is
not excluded in the default period is
[~.V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h, 0) = [max.b'] {u (y (1 -
h[lambda]) - [q.sub.1] (b', z, [GAMMA], g)b') + [beta]E [V
(b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 1, 0)]} (7)
where
E [V (b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 1, 0)] =
[integral][integral] V (b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 1,
0)[F.sub.z] (dz' | z) [F.sub.g] (dg' | g).
In this case, the government must choose how much debt it will
issue.
The value function of the government when it has decided to pay
back its debt is obtained from the following Bellman equation:
[V.sub.0] (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h) = [max.b'] {u (y (1 -
h[lambda]) + b - [q.sub.0] (b', z, [GAMMA], g) b') + [beta]E
[V (b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0, 0)]}, (8)
where
E [V (b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0, 0)] =
[integral][integral] V (b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0,
0)[F.sub.z] (dz' | z) [F.sub.g] (dg' | g).
The function V (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h, x) is computed as follows:
V (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h, 0) = max{[V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h),
[V.sub.0](b, z, [GAMMA], g, h)}, (9)
and
V (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h, 1) = u (y (1 - h[lambda])) + [beta]E [[phi]
V (0, z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0, e)],
where
E [V (0, z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0, e)] =
[integral][integral] [[phi] V (0, z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0,
0) + (1 - [phi]) V(0, z', g'[GAMMA], g', 0, 1)] [F.sub.z]
(dz' | z) [F.sub.g] (dg' | g).
Let
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
denote the equilibrium default decision.
The price of a bond if a default decision d was made in the current
period satisfies the lenders' zero profit condition. It is given by
[q.sub.d] (b', z, [GAMMA], g) = [1/[1 + r]] [1 - E [d' |
b', z, [GAMMA], g, d]], (11)
where
E [d'| b', z, [GAMMA], g, d] = [integral][integral] d
(b', z', g'[GAMMA], g', d) [F.sub.z] (dz' | z)
[F.sub.g] (dg' | g)
denotes the probability that the government decides to default if
it purchases b' bonds, and the current default decision is d.
Equilibrium Concept
Definition 1 A recursive competitive equilibrium is characterized by
1. a set of value functions V (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h, x), [V.sub.1]
(z, [GAMMA], g, h), and [V.sub.0] (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h);
2. a set of policies for asset holdings [b'.sub.0] (b, z,
[GAMMA], g, h) and [b'.sub.1] (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h), and a default
decision d (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h); and
3. a bond price function [q.sub.d] (b', z, [GAMMA], g),
such that
(a) V (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h, x), [V.sub.1] (z, [GAMMA], g, h), and
[V.sub.0] (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h) satisfy the system of functional
equations (5)-(9);
(b) the default policy d (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h) and the policies for
asset holdings [b'.sub.0] (b, z, [GAMMA], g, h) and [b'.sub.1]
(b, z, [GAMMA], g, h) solve the dynamic programming problem specified by
equations (5)-(9); and
(c) the bond price function [q.sub.d] (b', z, [GAMMA], g, h)
is given by equation (11).
Discussion of the Environment
The model analyzed in this article relies on several simplifying
assumptions. This has the advantage that the model remains tractable and
that the main mechanisms can be presented in a more transparent way. The
disadvantage of using such a stylized framework is that the model is
ill-suited to account for the quantitative behavior of some key
variables. (11) The rest of this section discusses several
simplifications embedded in the environment presented in the previous
section and extensions that have been studied in the literature.
Focusing on an endowment economy simplifies the analysis. A more
comprehensive study of the business cycle would require incorporating
capital and labor into the model. Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) also
consider an extension of the basic model with labor as the only input in
the production function. The results do not change significantly. More
recently, Bai and Zhang (2006) study a production economy with capital.
The model assumes that the government issues one-period bonds.
Allowing the government to issue long-term bonds would introduce
nontrivial complications to the analysis. For instance, if the
government can issue two-period bonds, it is necessary to keep track of
how much debt was issued two periods ago (which is due today) and how
much debt was issued one period ago (which will be due tomorrow).
Alternatively, if the government only issues annuities there would only
be one state: how many annuities have been issued since the last
default. However, the pricing of the annuities issued today would be
more complex than the price of a one-period bond. Lenders would not only
need to compute the probability of a default in the following period,
but also the probability of a default two-periods ahead, conditional on
not observing a default tomorrow; the probability of observing a default
three-periods ahead; conditional on not observing a default in the next
two periods; and so on. Arellano and Ramanarayanan (2006) allow the
government to issue short and long bonds.
It was assumed that the government cannot issue bonds contingent on the future realization of its endowment. Even if creditors have perfect
information regarding the economy's endowment, this would not imply
that contracts contingent on the endowment realization could be written
(the endowment may not be verifiable). In reality, one limitation for
writing contracts contingent on real variables is that the government
could manipulate the measurement of these variables (see Borensztein and
Mauro 2004). Determining to what extent bonds can be state contingent in
reality and studying some degree of state contingency in quantitative
models of sovereign default are interesting avenues for future research.
The assumption that countries experience an exogenous output loss
after defaulting intends to capture the disruptions in economic activity
entailed by a default decision. In general, default episodes are not
observed in economic booms but in recessions. This means that a fraction
of the low economic activity that is observed after a default episode
can be explained by weak fundamentals pre-existing the default decision.
Thus, not all of the decrease in economic activity observed after a
default is related to the default decision and cannot be considered as a
cost of defaulting. On the other hand, default decisions are likely to
introduce disruptions in economic activity of the defaulting economy.
IMF (2002), Kumhof (2004), and Kumhof and Tanner (2005) discuss how
financial crises that lead to severe recessions are triggered by
sovereign default. This is due to the fact that government debt is not
only held by foreigners but also by locals, and in particular by local
banks--something that is not explicitly considered in the stylized model
studied in this article. Thus, government default may hurt financial
intermediation significantly (see IMF 2002 for a discussion of recent
episodes). (12)
In the model, the output loss triggered by the default decision is
independent of the size of the default. If the output loss represents
the damage made by the default decision through the local financial
system, it could be argued that the loss should depend (positively) on
the amount that is not repaid by the government (in particular, it
should depend on the amount held by the locals; see, for example, IMF
2002). Considering this would introduce additional complications to the
analysis though it is an interesting avenue to be pursued in future
work. If the output loss depends on the amount not paid by the
government, it can be argued that the government should also be allowed
to choose the size of the default. (13) Arellano (forthcoming) argues
that the output loss depends on the state of the economy and, thus,
introduces this into the model.
Previous quantitative studies assume that after default, the
economy suffers the output loss for a stochastic number of periods (the
periods in which the economy is excluded from capital markets). For
simplicity, this assumption is modified in this article. Assuming that
the output loss lasts for a stochastic number of periods in a context in
which there is no financial exclusion raises the possibility of
scenarios in which the government defaults before the duration of output
losses triggered by the previous default has ended. This would require
keeping track of the number of output losses the economy is suffering
and would increase the dimensionality of the state space. The Appendix
shows that the results are not sensitive to the modification of the
output loss process utilized in this article.
The assumption that countries are excluded from capital markets
after a default episode is motivated by evidence of a drainage in
capital flows into countries that defaulted (see, for example, Gelos,
Sahay, and Sandleris 2004). However, it very well may be that the
difficulties in market access observed after a default episode respond
to the same factors that triggered the default decision itself. (14) In
support of this, Gelos, Sahay, and Sandleris (2004) document that once
other variables are used as controls, market access is not significantly
influenced by previous defaults (see also Eichengreen and Portes 2000
and Meyersson 2006). Moreover, it is not obvious that after a default
episode competitive creditors would be able to coordinate cutting off
credit to defaulting countries. Thus, the study of an environment in
which a defaulting economy cannot be excluded from capital markets is
the first building block of any work that attempts to explain the
exclusion outcome as an endogenous outcome of the model.
3. PARAMETERIZATION
The model is solved numerically using value function iteration and
interpolation as in Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (2006a). (15)
Whenever possible, this article considers the same parameter values as
in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), which facilitates the comparison of the
results. To solve the model numerically, Bellman equations are first
recast in detrended form. All variables are normalized by
[[mu].sub.g][[GAMMA].sub.t-1] as in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006). This
normalization implies that the mean of the detrended endowment is one.
Even though Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) argue that the best
representation of the output process for emerging economies is
characterized by equations (1) through (4), this specification requires
keeping track of z and g as state variables. The computational method
used in previous articles in the literature does not allow solving for
this specification without incurring sizable approximation errors.
Instead, they consider two alternative endowment processes. In Model I,
the economy is hit only with transitory shocks (z shocks). In Model II,
the economy is hit with shocks to the trend only (g shocks). Table 1
reports the parameter values specific to each of the two model
alternatives.
Parameters values that are common across models are presented in
Table 2. Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) assume an output loss of 2 percent
during the exclusion period. This is based on empirical estimates of the
output loss triggered by a default decision (see Chuhan and Sturzenegger
2005). As explained above, for simplicity this article assumes that all
output loss occurs only in one period, the period that follows the
decision. The value of [lambda] is calibrated to make the output-loss
cost of defaulting in this article equivalent to the one in Aguiar and
Gopinath (2006). In particular, the value of [lambda] is chosen to be
such that for Model I, the mean debt level in the simulations is the
same as the one in the original formulation of Aguiar and Gopinath
(2006). We show that this value (of [lambda]) enables Model II to
generate a similar level of debt as in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006).
Except for the value of [lambda], the remaining parameters take the
same values as in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006). The coefficient of
relative risk aversion of 2 is within the range of accepted values. The
probability of redemption implies an average autarky duration of 2.5
years (in the model, a period refers to a quarter), similar to the value
estimated by Gelos, Sahay, and Sandleris (2004)--Section 5 presents the
results when creditors cannot exclude a defaulting economy. The process
of output is calibrated to match the process for Argentina from 1983 to
2000. The subjective discount factor is set to 0.8. This departs from
standard macro models. As in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), in the stylized
framework discussed in this article, a low discount factor is needed to
induce the economy to accumulate debt and be willing to accept a higher
spread over the risk-free interest rate (the international interest
rate). The limitations faced by the stylized framework to generate
default with more reasonable discount factors may be a consequence of
its simplifying assumptions. (16) As was mentioned previously, recent
articles study different extensions of this framework that improve its
quantitative performance (assuming that lenders can use financial
exclusion as a punishment).
4. RESULTS WITH EXCLUSION
This section presents the results obtained when the parameters that
determine the exclusion process are chosen as in Aguiar and Gopinath
(2006), that is, [[phi].sub.1] = 0 and [phi] = 0.1. This means that the
government cannot issue bonds in the period it defaults, and after that
it faces a constant probability [phi] of regaining access to capital
markets.
Equilibrium Default Region and Bond Prices with Exclusion
The shaded areas in Figure 2 display the default regions (i.e., the
combinations of endowment shocks and debt levels for which the economy
would choose to default) of the model with transitory and trend shocks.
(17) Both graphs show that the higher the endowment shock, the higher
the minimum debt level at which it is optimal to declare a default. From
another perspective, for a given initial debt level, the government
finds it optimal to default only if the endowment shock is sufficiently
low.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The benefit of defaulting is that resources that would have been
allocated to pay back previously issued bonds are, instead, allocated to
current consumption. There are two costs entailed by a default decision:
a loss in output and the inability of the government to use
international capital markets to smooth out domestic endowment shocks.
It should be noticed that the "costs" of defaulting do not
depend on the debt level at the time of default. Thus, a higher initial
debt level increases the benefits of a default without increasing the
costs. For sufficiently large debt levels, the benefits of defaulting
offset the "fixed" costs. This explains why in Figure 2 it is
optimal for the government to default on relatively large values of debt
(low b).
A low endowment shock implies that there are less resources
available in the current and subsequent periods. (18) Given that the
output loss that follows a default decision is a constant fraction of
the underlying potential output, it is more costly to default for high
endowment realizations than for low endowment realizations. In the model
with transitory shocks, this is the main force behind the negative
relationship between the shock to the endowment and the debt threshold
at which the government is indifferent between defaulting and not
defaulting. (19) However, in the model with trend shocks, a high shock
today signals higher growth rates in the future. This increases the
desire to borrow as it allows bringing future resources to the current
period. The fact that the ability to borrow is more valuable in good
than in bad times helps explain why the government defaults only on
larger debt volumes in good times.
Figure 3 shows the equilibrium bond prices faced by the government
as a function of the current issuance level (-b) and the endowment
shock. The curves have a waterfall shape. For relatively low issuance
levels there is no risk of default. In this case, competitive investors
demand the risk-free rate in compensation for purchasing the
government's bonds. For issuance volumes for which there is a
positive probability of default tomorrow, the rate of return demanded
for holding bonds is higher than the risk-free rate, i.e., the price
offered is lower than 1/[1 + r]. Finally, for sufficiently high issuance
volumes, it is common knowledge that the government would default in the
following period for almost any endowment realization. In this case,
investors offer a zero price for each bond issued today.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
It should be noted that price q is nondecreasing in the current
endowment realization. In other words, the higher the endowment, the
higher the issuance level at which the price starts to fall. This is due
to the persistence in the endowment process and the shape of the default
regions. A higher endowment today implies that it is more likely to
observe high endowments in the following period, and therefore it makes
the default probability lower.
Business Cycle Properties With the Exclusion Punishment
The model is simulated for 750,000 periods (500 samples of 1,500
observations each). In order to compute business cycle statistics, 400
samples of the last 72 periods before a default episode are used. The
samples selected are such that the last exclusion period was observed at
least two periods before the first period in the sample. The number of
periods in each sample is equal to the number of periods in the data
compared with the simulations (Argentina 1983-2000). Restricting to
samples at least two periods away from the last exclusion period helps
avoid extreme observations that may distort the results. (20) The
moments reported below correspond to the average across the 400 samples.
The behavior of four series is analyzed: the logarithm of income (y),
the logarithm of consumption (c), the ratio of the trade balance to
output (tb), and the annualized spread ([R.sub.s]). All series are
filtered using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of
1600. Standard deviations are denoted by [sigma] and are reported in
percentage terms; correlations are denoted by [rho].
Table 3 reports business cycle moments observed in the data
(Argentina 1983-2000) and in Models I and II. With the exception of the
debt-to-output ratio, the business cycle moments for Argentina are taken
from Aguiar and Gopinath (2006). The moments are chosen so as to
evaluate the ability of the models to replicate the distinctive business
cycle properties of emerging economies that were described in the
beginning of the article. It must be said that the sample moments for
Argentina display the same qualitative features observed in other
emerging markets. (21)
The moments in the simulated samples generated by Models I and II
are different from the moments reported in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006).
The main reason is that they use a different computational method from
the one used in this article. While, Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) use a
discrete state space method, we use interpolation methods and a
nonlinear optimization routine to find the optimal issuance levels.
Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (2006a) demonstrate that the numerical
errors incurred by the discrete state space technique may lead to
misleading conclusions in some dimensions. The most important one is
that the spread volatility becomes negligible once the model is solved
using a more accurate method. Other statistics about the behavior of the
spread over the business cycle are also susceptible to numerical errors
when the model is solved using a discrete state space technique. (22)
The table shows that both models fail to generate the volatilities
of the trade balance and spread observed in the data. In particular, the
standard deviations of the spread are two orders of magnitude lower than
the value observed in the data. This is an important limitation of both
models. Moreover, Models I and II generate 6.6 and 24 defaults in 10,000
periods, respectively. These values are below the ratio of 75 defaults
in 10,000 periods computed by Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano (2003)
using a sample of emerging markets from 1824 to 1999, though it is not
clear that this is the frequency that the model should replicate. (23)
An alternative procedure is to compare the default rate generated by the
model with the default rate implicit in the average spread observed over
the sample period (under the assumption of risk-neutral lenders). The
value of the latter is 243 defaults for every 10,000 periods, which is
even further away from the model predictions.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
On the other hand, the models are able to generate a high
volatility of consumption relative to income and the sign of the
co-movements between the trade balance, spread, and output that are
observed in the data. (24)
Discussion of the Results With the Exclusion Punishment
This section describes the tradeoffs the government faces when it
decides how much debt to issue. This helps in understanding the logic
behind the results presented in Table 3. The section focuses on the
model with transitory shocks (z), though the same logic applies to the
model with trend shocks.
Given the monotonicity of the default decisions (see Figure 2), the
bond price function faced by the government when it decides how much to
borrow can be written as
q (b', z) = [1 - F (z* (b') | z)]/[1 + r], (12)
where z* (b') denotes the next period endowment shock that
makes the government indifferent between defaulting and not defaulting
on a debt level b', and F denotes the cumulative distribution
function for the next period shock. If the endowment shock in the
following period is lower than z*, the government will default on
b'. If it is higher than z*, the government will pay back b'.
In the top panel of Figure 2, z* (b') represents the frontier of
the shaded area. Equation (12) shows that the shape of price q mirrors
the shape of the probability of observing a default the next period,
namely, F (z* (b') | z).
The solid line of Figure 4 displays the bond price menu faced by
the government in a period in which the endowment realization is equal
to the unconditional mean of the endowment process ([[mu].sub.z]) and
the economy is not excluded from capital markets. The sensitivity of the
bond price to the issuance volume (b') is given by
[q (b', z)]/[partial derivative]b' = [[-f (z* (b') |
z)]/[1 + r]] [[[partial derivative]z* (b')]/[partial
derivative]b'], (13)
where f denotes the density function of future shocks. This
equation shows that the shape of the bond price depends on two factors:
the probability distribution f and the sensitivity of z* to changes in
b' (the shape of the default region). The assumption that future
endowment shocks are drawn from a Gaussian distribution accounts for the
flat portion of the price curve. The thin tails of f explain why the
price is almost invariant to b' at issuance volumes such that the
threshold z* takes extreme values.
The bond price plays a central role in understanding the shape of
the objective function of the government represented in Figure 4.
Formally, the objective function is given by the right-hand side of the
Bellman equation:
RHS (b') = u (y(1 - [lambda]) + b - [q.sub.0] (b', z)
b') + [beta] [integral] V(b', z', 0, 0)[F.sub.z]
(dz' | z).
For the range of values of b' such that there is no default
risk, the present discounted welfare increases with the issuance level,
i.e., the burden of starting tomorrow with higher liabilities does not
compensate for the extra resources collected for current consumption.
(25) As the price per bond starts to fall, there is an extra factor that
appears in the tradeoff between current and future consumption: an extra
dollar of borrowing implies a lower bond price. In particular, an extra
dollar of borrowing implies a decrease in price q received for all the
bonds issued in the current period.
If the price function is steep, borrowing an extra dollar is quite
costly due to the decrease in bond price received for all bonds issued
in the current period. In the stylized model presented in this article,
the price function becomes very steep at borrowing levels at which the
government pays an interest rate close to the risk-free rate.
Consequently, the borrowing levels observed in equilibrium are such that
the economy pays low spreads. This explains the low default frequency
reported in Table 3.
The top panel of Figure 3 shows that a higher endowment realization
enables the government to borrow more without paying a higher spread,
but the price function becomes steep at borrowing levels for which the
spread is low independently of whether the endowment shock is
"low" or "high." This feature contributes to the
explanation of why in equilibrium the government chooses to pay low
spreads at all endowment realizations, and thus the volatility of the
spread is low.
The inability of the model to generate a higher default rate and
spread volatility may be a consequence of its simplifying assumptions.
Consider, for instance, the assumption that the government can only
issue one-period bonds. Recall that as illustrated in Figure 4, the
interest rate increases with the borrowing level (the bond price
decreases). The assumption of one-period bonds implies that in every
period the economy has to roll over its entire stock of debt. Thus, the
increase in the interest rate that is due to an extra dollar of
borrowing affects the entire stock of bonds and not only the last unit
issued. More precisely, consider the decision of whether to borrow x + 1
dollars or x dollars. When the government is renewing its entire stock
of debt, the higher interest implied by borrowing x + 1 instead of x
applies to the x + 1 units issued. This is trivially larger than the
cost induced by an increase in the interest rate paid for the last bond
issued. This argument illustrates how restricting the government to
issue one-period bonds increases the marginal issuance cost, and thus
accounts for a fraction of the low spreads generated by the model.
Even though the government is risk averse and lenders are risk
neutral, the volatility of consumption is higher than the volatility of
output in both models. As discussed in the beginning of Section 4, price
q is nondecreasing in the current endowment realization. That is, a
higher endowment enables the government to issue more bonds without
necessarily paying a higher spread. Given the low value of the discount
factor, the economy will seize the opportunity to borrow more whenever
it appears, explaining why the economy borrows more in good times. This
explains why the model is able to generate a higher volatility of
consumption relative to income. Formally, current consumption is
determined by current income and net borrowing, namely,
c = y - (qb' - b).
Therefore,
[[sigma].sup.2] (c) = [[sigma].sup.2] (y) + 2[sigma][y - (qb'
- b)] + [[sigma].sup.2] (qb' - b).
The positive covariance between net borrowing (b - qb') and
income increases the volatility of consumption relative to income.
Table 3 shows that both models are able to replicate the sign of
the co-movements between trade balance, spread, and output observed in
the data. The fact that the government borrows more in good times leads
to a negative correlation between trade balance and output (as observed
in the data). (26) The mechanics that determine the sign of the
correlation between the spread and output are more complex. On the one
hand, if the bond price function faced by the government is kept
constant, a higher income realization today reduces the need to borrow,
and therefore it reduces the spread that the government is willing to
pay for its debt. This generates a negative correlation between income
and spread. But the bond price function also changes with the income
realization. If the price of the bond becomes less sensitive to the
borrowing level at higher income levels, the government would be willing
to pay a higher spread at higher income levels. The latter may change
the sign of the correlation between the spread and income. For example,
the next section shows that once the exclusion punishment is eliminated,
the spread becomes pro-cyclical in Model II.
5. RESULTS WITHOUT EXCLUSION
This section studies the implications of removing the threat of
financial exclusion. Formally, this implies setting the value of
[[phi].sub.1] equal to 1. The section describes how the default and
saving decisions change when the government cannot be threatened with
financial exclusion. This helps to understand how the business cycle
statistics change when the exclusion assumption is abandoned, which is
discussed later in the section entitled "Business Cycle
Properties."
Equilibrium Choices Without the Exclusion Punishment
The common feature across Models I and II is that they are able to
sustain a lower debt level when the government does not face the threat
of financial exclusion. In other dimensions, the model with transitory
shocks without exclusion features higher equilibrium spreads (lower
equilibrium issuance prices) and spreads that are more responsive to the
endowment shock compared to the model with transitory shocks and
exclusion. On the other hand, the model with trend shocks features lower
equilibrium spreads and spreads that are less responsive to trend shocks
compared to the model with exclusion.
Figure 5 illustrates how the default decisions change when
exclusion cannot be used as a punishment in Models I and II. The graphs
illustrate that the government defaults at lower debt levels when the
threat of financial exclusion is eliminated. The result is not
surprising though. The possibility of being excluded from capital
markets imposes a cost to every default decision (regardless of the size
of the default). Once the threat of financial exclusion is eliminated,
it becomes less costly to default, and thus the government finds it
optimal to default at lower debt levels.
The top panel of Figure 5 shows that in Model I the default
decision becomes relatively more sensitive to the endowment shock (and
less sensitive to the debt level) when the threat of exclusion is
eliminated. This is due to the fact that the possibility of going into
financial autarky is more painful at lower endowment realizations than
at higher endowment realizations. When the current shock to the
endowment level is higher, the need to smooth out consumption by
borrowing is weaker, and therefore the value assigned to retaining
access to capital markets is lower. In other words, the government would
suffer less from being excluded from capital markets if its endowment
level is higher. When the threat of financial exclusion is eliminated,
the overall cost of defaulting decreases more at lower endowment
realizations than at higher endowment realizations. This accounts for
the flatter default region in the top panel of Figure 5.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The picture looks different in the model with trend shocks. The
bottom panel of Figure 5 shows that the default region becomes steeper
without exclusion. In this case, the mechanism described in the previous
paragraph is also present, but there is an additional effect. A higher
growth rate in the current period not only means that there are more
resources available for current consumption but also that future growth
rates are likely to be high--recall that there is persistence in growth
rates. Consequently, unlike a higher transitory shock, a higher growth
shock introduces an incentive to borrow more on account of the future
increases in the endowment. This means that the value assigned to
retaining access to capital markets is larger when the current growth
rate is higher. When the threat of financial exclusion is eliminated,
the overall cost of defaulting decreases more at higher endowment
realizations than at lower endowment realizations. This explains the
change in the slope of the default regions in the model with trend
shocks.
The change in the shape of the default region plays an important
role in understanding the change in the shape of the price function. The
formal link between the two is described in equation 13. For example,
the steeper the default region (the higher the expression |[[partial
derivative]z*(b')]/[partial derivative]b'|), the steeper the
price function.
Figure 6 shows the price functions faced by the economy in Model I
with and without exclusion. (27) The charts in Figure 6 show that when
the threat of exclusion is eliminated, the bond price starts to decrease
at a lower issuance level. This mirrors the shift of the default region
due to a lower cost of default. The graphs show that the moderate change
in the slope of the default regions observed in the top panel of Figure
5 translate into a moderate change in the slope of the price functions.
Figure 7 shows the price function faced by the economy in Model II
with and without exclusion. (28) The charts show that the steeper
default regions that are observed when the threat of financial exclusion
is eliminated translate into steeper price functions.
Figure 8 displays the equilibrium issuance price in Model I as a
function of the endowment shock realization in the specifications with
and without exclusion. The graphs show that the price at which the
government issues debt is lower and more sensitive to the endowment
shock in the setup without exclusion.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Figure 9 shows the bond prices paid in equilibrium in the model
with shocks to the trend with and without exclusion. The graphs show
that the prices at which the government issues debt are higher in the
setup without exclusion. The correlation with the endowment shock also
changes. When the government can be threatened with financial exclusion
the spread decreases with respect to the shock to the trend. But when
the government cannot be threatened with financial exclusion, the spread
increases with respect to the shock to the trend. (29)
The Mechanics of the Equilibrium Behavior of the Spread
This section discusses the differential behavior of the spread in
Models I and II once the exclusion assumption is abandoned. Consider
first the Euler equation that determines the optimal borrowing level
u' (c) [q.sub.0](b', z, [GAMMA], g) = {[beta] [integral]
[integral] [[[partial derivative]V(b', z', [GAMMA]',
g', h)]/[partial derivative]b'] F(dz' | z)F(dg' | g)
- u' (c)b' [[[partial derivative][q.sub.0](b', z,
[GAMMA]', g)]/[partial derivative]b'].} (14)
The left-hand side of the equation captures the marginal benefit of
issuing one more bond today, i.e., the increase in current consumption.
The right-hand side captures the marginal costs. The first term
represents the "future marginal cost." Issuing one more unit
of debt today makes the economy poorer in the future--the government
will either have to pay back its debt or face the cost of defaulting.
The second term on the right-hand side represents the "present
marginal cost." This is the cost derived from decreasing the price
of all the bonds issued today. The role of the latter was discussed more
extensively in the end of Section 4.
In both models the optimal issuance volume is lower when the
government does not face the threat of default. An immediate consequence
is that it depresses the present marginal cost (the second term in the
right-hand side of equation (14) is the product of the borrowing level
times the sensitivity of the price to the borrowing level). The decrease
in the marginal cost induced by a lower borrowing level may be
compensated, in part, by accepting a lower price for each bond issued,
which reduces the marginal benefit of borrowing. This can explain the
lower equilibrium bond prices (higher spread) that are observed in Model
I when the threat of exclusion is eliminated (see Figure 8).
A similar effect is present in Model II. But in this case the bond
price becomes steeper in the setup without exclusion. This effect alone
tends to increase the present marginal cost of borrowing, and therefore
unlike Model I, a lower bond price is not necessary to satisfy equation
(14). This can explain why the levels of the equilibrium bond prices in
Model II do not change significantly when the threat of exclusion is
eliminated (see Figure 9).
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The forces behind the changes in the slope of the spread with
respect to the endowment shock are more difficult to tease out. As
explained in the end of Section 4, the equilibrium relationship between
the spread and the endowment shock depends on various effects, and the
sign of the relationship does not necessarily need to be negative. In
fact, Figure 9 shows that in the model with trend shocks and no
exclusion, the spread increases with the growth shock.
Business Cycle Properties Under No Exclusion
The business cycle statistics reported in Table 3 are recalculated
for an economy without the exclusion punishment and presented in Table 4
(the statistics in Table 3 are reproduced in order to facilitate
comparison).
The implications of removing the exclusion punishment reported in
Table 4 are consistent with the discussion of equilibrium choices in the
beginning of Section 5. Table 4 shows that the assumption of exogenous
exclusion is responsible for a high fraction of the debt level supported
in the model with exclusion. Recall that in this model the government
chooses borrowing levels that allow the government to pay very low
spreads. These levels are lower when the default cost raised by the
threat of financial exclusion is removed.
Table 4 shows that both models quantitatively fail along important
dimensions with or without the assumption of financial exclusion: the
default rate, the volatility of the spread, and the volatility of the
trade balance are too low compared with the data. Even though the
overall performance is poor, the behavior of the model with transitory
shocks shows a moderate improvement, while the behavior of the model
with trend shocks deteriorates when the exclusion assumption is
eliminated. The model with endowment shocks and no exclusion displays a
higher default rate and spread volatility compared to the model with
exclusion (but still far below the data), while the remaining business
cycle statistics are not substantially different. On the other hand, the
sign of the correlation between output and the spread, and between the
spread and the trade balance are reversed and become counterfactual in
the model with trend shocks and no exclusion.
The higher default rate generated by Model I when the threat of
financial exclusion is eliminated is consistent with the higher
equilibrium spread described in Figure 8. The higher spread volatility
observed in the setup without exclusion is also consistent with Figure
8, which shows a higher sensitivity of the spread with respect to output
in the model without exclusion. The lower default rate and similar
spread volatility generated by Model II when the threat of financial
exclusion is eliminated are consistent with the adjustments illustrated
in Figure 9.
6. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This article discusses the quantitative performance of sovereign
default models and explains how the performance is affected by the
assumption that countries can be exogenously excluded from capital
markets after a default. The article compares the performance of a
stylized model with and without the threat of exclusion. It is shown
that the exclusion assumption explains a high fraction of the sovereign
debt that can be sustained in equilibrium but does not significantly
alter the remaining business cycle statistics of the model. In effect,
the model without exclusion generates annual debt-output ratios of less
than 2 percent. The model with exclusion generates annual debt-output
ratios of 4.8 percent when the shocks hit the growth rate and of 6.3
percent when the shocks hit the endowment level. The article shows that
in the model with shocks to the endowment level, the default decision
becomes slightly more sensitive to the endowment shock and, therefore,
less sensitive to the debt level. This helps reduce the sensitivity of
the bond price to the borrowing level. On the other hand, in the model
with shocks to the trend the default decision becomes relatively less
sensitive to the endowment shock, which increases the sensitivity of the
bond price to the borrowing level. Given that in this class of models
the excessive sensitivity of the default probability to the borrowing
level limits the models' quantitative performance, the previous
effects may help explain why the performance of the model with shocks to
the endowment level shows moderate improvement and why the performance
of the model with shocks to the trend deteriorates. In spite of this,
both models still fail along important dimensions. The default rate, the
volatilities of the trade balance and of the spread, and the debt levels
are too low compared to the data. These shortcomings suggest that the
exclusion assumption does not play an important role, and therefore
future studies that do not rely on the threat of financial exclusion
will not necessarily be handicapped in explaining the business cycle in
emerging economies. These shortcomings also suggest that other
assumptions of the model must be modified in order to bring the model
closer to the data.
APPENDIX: THE MODEL WITH STOCHASTIC DURATION OF OUTPUT LOSS
As mentioned before, the model introduced in Section 2 does not
exactly coincide with the model presented in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006).
They assume that following a default episode, the duration of lower
output lasts as long as the time of exclusion. Table 5 shows that the
business cycle statistics presented in Table 3 are not greatly affected
by the choice of the process of output loss-statistics computed with a
stochastic duration of output loss are taken from Hatchondo, Martinez,
and Sapriza (2006a) who solve the model in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006)
with the computational method used in this article.
REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath. 2006. "Defaultable Debt,
Interest Rates and the Current Account." Journal of International
Economics 69 (1): 64-83.
Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath. 2007. "Emerging Markets
Business Cycles: The Cycle is the Trend." Journal of Political
Economy 115 (1): 69-102.
Arellano, Cristina. Forthcoming. "Default Risk and Income
Fluctuations in Emerging Economies." American Economic Review.
Arellano, Cristina, and Ananth Ramanarayanan. 2006. "Default
and the Term Structure in Sovereign Bonds." Working Paper,
University of Minnesota.
Athreya, Kartik B., and Hubert P. Janicki. 2006. "Credit
Exclusion in Quantitative Models of Bankruptcy: Does It Matter?"
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 92 (1): 17-50.
Bai, Yan, and Jing Zhang. 2006. "Financial Integration and
International Risk Sharing." Working Paper, University of Michigan.
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Paolo Mauro. 2004. "The Case for
GDP-Indexed Bonds." Economic Policy 19 (38): 165-216.
Chuhan, Punam, and Federico Sturzenegger. 2005. "Defaults
Episodes in the 1980s and 1990s: What Have We Learned?" In Managing
Economic Volatility and Crises, eds. Joshua Aizenman and Brian Pinto,
New York, NY: Cambridge University Press: 471-519.
Cole, Harold L., James Dow, and William B. English. 1995.
"Default, Settlement, and Signalling: Lending Resumption in a
Reputational Model of Sovereign Debt." International Economic
Review 36 (2): 365-85.
Cuadra, Gabriel, and Horacio Sapriza. 2006a. "Sovereign
Default, Interest Rates and Political Uncertainty in Emerging
Markets." Banco de Mexico, Working Paper 2006-02.
Cuadra, Gabriel, and Horacio Sapriza. 2006b. "Sovereign
Default, Terms of Trade, and Interest Rates in Emerging Markets."
Banco de Mexico, Working Paper 2006-01.
Eaton, Jonathan, and Mark Gersovitz. 1981. "Debt With
Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis." Review
of Economic Studies 48 (2): 289-309.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Richard Portes. 2000. "Debt
Restructuring With and Without the IMF." Manuscript, University of
California, Berkeley.
Gelos, Gaston, Ratna Sahay, and Guido Sandleris. 2004.
"Sovereign Borrowing by Developing Countries: What Determines
Market Access?" IMF Working Paper 04/221.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2006a. "Computing Business Cycles in Emerging Economy Models."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Working Paper No. 06-11.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2006b. "A Quantitative Study of Sovereign Default with
Heterogeneous Borrowers." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Working
Paper No. 05-12.
IMF. 2002. "Sovereign Debt Restructurings and the Domestic
Economy Experience in Four Recent Cases." Policy Development and
Review Department, February 21.
Kumhof, Michael. 2004. "Fiscal Crisis Resolution: Taxation
Versus Inflation." Manuscript, Stanford University.
Kumhof, Michael, and Evan Tanner. 2005. "Government Debt: A
Key Role in Financial Intermediation." IMF Working Paper 05/57.
Lizarazo, Sandra. 2005a. "Sovereign Risk and Risk Averse
International Investors." ITAM, Working Paper.
Lizarazo, Sandra. 2005b. "Contagion of Financial Crises in
Sovereign Debt Markets." ITAM, Working Paper.
Meyersson, Erik. 2006. "Debt Intolerance and Institutions, an
Empirical Investigation into the Institutional Effect of Sovereign
Debt." Mimeo, Institute for International Economic Studies,
Stockholm University.
Neumeyer, Pablo A., and Fabrizio Perri. 2005. "Business Cycles
in Emerging Economies: The Role of Interest Rates." Journal of
Monetary Economics 52 (2): 345-80.
Reinhart, Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano.
2003. "Debt Intolerance." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1: 1-62.
Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe. 2003. "Closing
Small Open Economy Models." Journal of International Economics 61
(1): 163-85.
Sturzenegger, Federico, and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2005. "Has
the Legal Threat to Sovereign Debt Restructuring Become Real?"
Working Paper, Harvard University.
Uribe, Martin, and Vivian Yue. 2006. "Country Spreads and
Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom?" Journal of International
Economics 69 (1): 6-36.
Yue, Vivian. 2005. "Sovereign Default and Debt
Renegotiation." Working Paper, New York University.
The authors would like to thank Kartik Athreya, Kevin Bryan,
Huberto Ennis, and Ned Prescott for helpful comments. E-mails:
JuanCarlos.Hatchondo@rich.frb.org; Leonardo.Martinez@rich.frb.org; and
hsapriza@andromeda.rutgers.edu. The views expressed in this article do
not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or
the Federal Reserve System.
(1) See Aguiar and Gopinath (2007), Neumeyer and Perri (2005), and
Uribe and Yue (2006).
(2) See, for example, Aguiar and Gopinath (2007), Neumeyer and
Perri (2005), Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2003), and Uribe and Yue (2006).
(3) Default episodes are not exceptional. Many nations have
experienced episodes of sovereign default, some of the latest being
Russia in 1998, Ecuador in 1999, and Argentina in 2001.
(4) See Aguiar and Gopinath (2006); Arellano (forthcoming);
Arellano and Ramanarayanan (2006); Bai and Zhang (2006); Cuadra and
Sapriza (2006a, b); Lizarazo (2005a,b); and Yue (2005).
(5) This point is also raised by Cole, Dow, and English (1995) and
Athreya and Janicki (2006).
(6) Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2005) discuss how holders of
defaulted bonds succeeded in interfering with cross-border payments to
other creditors who had previously agreed to a debt restructuring. From
this, they infer that holders of defaulted bonds may have been able to
exclude defaulting economies from international capital markets. On the
other hand, they conclude that "legal tactics are updated all the
time, and new ways are discovered both to extract payment from a
defaulting sovereign as well as to avoid attachments." In
particular, they expect that "the threat of exclusion may be less
relevant for some countries or to all countries in the future." For
example, they explain that after Argentina defaulted in 2001,
"attempts to actually attach assets have so far turned out to be
fruitless." In any case, other forms of financing are always
available to defaulting economies (issuing bonds at home, aid, official
credit, multilateral or bilateral financing, etc.). The discussion in
Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2005) suggests, therefore, that defaulting
economies might face at most a higher borrowing cost, though it is not
clear how important this cost differential may be.
(7) Arellano (forthcoming); Arellano and Ramanarayanan (2006); Bai
and Zhang (2006); Cuadra and Sapriza (2006a,b); Lizarazo (2005a,b); and
Yue (2005) extend the framework in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) but
maintain the basic assumptions (including the exclusion assumption).
(8) The only difference between the model presented in this article
and the model in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) is that here it is assumed
that there is a unique period of output loss after default--in contrast
with the stochastic number of periods of output loss assumed by Aguiar
and Gopinath (2006). This allows us to eliminate the threat of exclusion
without increasing the dimensionality of the state space. The Appendix
shows that this departure does not have sizable effects on the results.
(9) The endowment process is motivated by the work of Aguiar and
Gopinath (2007). They find that shocks to trend growth (rather than
transitory fluctuations around a stable trend) are the primary source of
fluctuations in emerging markets.
(10) Previous quantitative studies of sovereign default assume that
the government cannot borrow in the period it defaults ([[phi].sub.1] =
0), and it regains access to capital markets with a constant probability
([phi]) after that. In order to accommodate this possibility, it is
assumed that [[phi].sub.1] can be different from [phi].
(11) Other authors have studied different extensions of this
framework, which have improved its quantitative performance. See, for
example, Arellano (forthcoming); Arellano and Ramanarayanan (2006); Bai
and Zhang (2006); Cuadra and Sapriza (2006a, b); Lizarazo (2005a, b);
and Yue (2005).
(12) In the stylized model discussed in this article, the output
loss of [lambda] percent in the period after a default intends to
capture the cost of defaulting implied by the disruptions in economic
activity triggered by the declaration of default. The calibration of the
parameter [lambda] should capture these disruptions and does not intend
to match the overall decrease in output observed after a default. In
contrast to the exclusion from capital markets, the output loss does not
intend to capture a punishment imposed by creditors. Eaton and Gersovitz
(1981) discuss output loss as the result of punishments.
(13) In this article, the government must decide whether it honors
all the debt issued in the previous period or whether it defaults on all
of it. But this is not a restrictive assumption given that the costs of
defaulting are orthogonal to the amount of debt that is repudiated. In
this case, the government would never find it optimal to default on less
than a 100 percent of the outstanding debt. This would not be the case
if the cost of defaulting depends on the amount repudiated. Yue (2005)
studies partial default in an environment in which the defaulted amount
is decided in a bargaining process between the government and the
lenders.
(14) For example, Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (2006b) analyze
a model in which both default and the difficulties in market access
after default may be triggered by a change in the policymaker in power.
(15) The value functions [V.sub.0] and [V.sub.1] are approximated
using Chebychev polynomials. Fifteen polynomials on the asset space and
ten on the endowment shock are used. Results are robust to using more
polynomials.
(16) For example, the end of Section 4 describes how the assumption
that the government can only issue one-period bonds increases the
marginal issuance cost. If it were not for the low discount factor, the
issuance volume and spreads observed in equilibrium would be even lower
than what is observed in the data.
(17) The detrended output process has a mean of 1. This implies
that the debt levels b in Figure 2 correspond to the ratio of
debt-to-mean output.
(18) Both the trend shocks and the transitory shocks display
positive autocorrelation.
(19) If the endowment is low, the marginal utility of consumption
is high, and therefore the gain from defaulting is high. However, if the
model with transitory shocks is solved assuming that the output loss is
a fixed amount instead of a percentage of output, the default region
becomes almost vertical but with a positive slope. This is due to the
fact that with a high endowment shock the economy displays a less
intense desire to issue debt, and therefore it assigns a lower value to
retaining access to capital markets.
(20) In the periods that follow an exclusion period, the government
inherits little or no debt from previous periods. The consequence is
that in these periods the government borrows a relatively low amount,
and thus it pays relatively low spreads compared to what is observed in
the remaining observations. In the simulations, these outliers may
appear up to two periods after the end of an exclusion period. It is
judged that it is more appropriate to present results computed without
considering these outliers. Simulation results are contrasted against
data from Argentina during a period in which the economy was not
excluded from capital markets. Moreover, these outliers can alter the
calculations of business cycle statistics (see Hatchondo, Martinez, and
Sapriza 2006a).
(21) As previously mentioned, emerging economies feature interest
rates that are high, volatile, and countercyclical; high volatility of
consumption relative to income (typically, higher than one); and
countercyclical net exports (see, for example, Aguiar and Gopinath 2007;
Neumeyer and Perri 2005; and Uribe and Yue 2006).
(22) A second reason behind the discrepancy between the moments in
Table 3 and in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) is that the setups are not
exactly the same. In their model, the output loss lasts as long as the
exclusion punishment. In the present setup, the output loss lasts for
only one period. The Appendix shows that this difference accounts for
only a small fraction of the discrepancy in the performance of the two
models.
(23) The model is calibrated to match the macroeconomic behavior of
Argentina between 1983 and 2000, while the default rate computed in
Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano (2003) is based on a different time
period and a sample of various countries.
(24) The table does not report statistics about the current
account. Given that both models generate a relatively stable debt level
and a low volatility of the interest rate, interest payments also
display low volatility. Therefore, the balance of the current account is
almost perfectly correlated with the trade balance and inherits the
statistical properties of the latter.
(25) It should be stressed that this result is not general and
critically depends on the parameter values chosen, especially the value
of the subjective discount factor.
(26) The trade balance is defined as
tb = y - c = qb' - b.
Thus, the positive correlation between net borrowing and income
translates into a negative correlation between trade balance and income.
(27) Notice that the top panel of Figure 6 represents the same
functions as the top panel of Figure 3 but with different scales. The
graph is reproduced again in order to facilitate the comparison of the
shape of the price functions in the models with and without exclusion.
(28) The top panel of Figure 6 represents the same functions as the
bottom panel of Figure 3 but with different scales.
(29) The beginning of Section 5 provides some intuition for the
differential behavior of the spread displayed by Models I and II once
the exclusion assumption is abandoned.
Table 1 Parameter Values Specific to Models I and II
Model I Model II
[[rho].sub.g] - 0.17
[[sigma].sub.g] 0% 3%
[[rho].sub.z] 0.90 -
[[sigma].sub.z] 3.4% 0%
Notes: A period in the model corresponds to a quarter.
Table 2 Parameter Values Common to Models I and II
Risk Aversion [sigma] 2
International Interest r 1%
Rate
Probability of [[phi].sub.1] 0%
Redemption in the
Same Period of
Default
Probability of [phi] 10%
Redemption
Mean Growth Rate [[mu].sub.g] 1.006
Mean (log) Transitory [[mu].sub.z] -0.5[[sigma].sub.z.sup.2]
Productivity
Discount Factor [beta] 0.8
Loss of Output [lambda] 8.3%
Notes: A period in the model corresponds to a quarter.
Table 3 Business Cycle Statistics
Model I Model II
Data Transitory Shocks Trend Shocks
[sigma](y) 4.08 4.14 4.15
[sigma](c) 4.85 4.23 4.38
[sigma](tb) 1.36 0.20 0.63
[sigma]([R.sub.s]) 3.17 0.006 0.013
[rho](c, y) 0.96 0.99 0.99
[rho](tb, y) -0.89 -0.43 -0.29
[rho]([R.sub.s], y) -0.59 -0.80 -0.06
[rho]([R.sub.s], tb) 0.68 0.85 0.89
Mean Debt Output Ratio (%) 51 6.3 4.8
Rate of Default 75 6.6 24
Notes: The moments correspond to the average across 400 samples. The
debt output ratio is measured as the stock of debt divided by the annual
output level.
Table 4 Business Cycle Statistics Computed With and Without Exclusion
Punishment
Transitory Shocks Trend Shocks
With Without With Without
Data Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion
[sigma] (y) 4.08 4.14 4.10 4.15 4.16
[sigma] (c) 4.85 4.23 4.19 4.38 4.23
[sigma] (TB/Y) 1.36 0.20 0.21 0.63 0.23
[sigma] ([R.sub.s]) 3.17 0.006 0.05 0.013 0.015
[rho] (c, y) 0.96 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99
[rho] (TB/Y, y) -0.89 -0.43 -0.43 -0.29 -0.29
[rho] ([R.sub.s], y) -0.59 -0.81 -0.95 -0.06 0.40
[rho] ([R.sub.s], 0.68 0.85 0.69 0.89 -0.96
TB/Y)
Mean Debt
Output Ratio (%) 51 6.3 1.7 4.8 1.8
Rate of Default 75 6.6 25 24 20
Notes: The debt output ratio is measured as the stock of debt divided by
the annual output level.
Table 5 Business Cycles Under Different Specifications of the Output
Loss
Transitory Shocks Trend Shocks
Stochastic Stochastic
One-Period Duration of One-Period Duration of
Output Loss Output Loss Output Loss Output Loss
[sigma] (y) 4.14 4.13 4.16 4.16
[sigma] (c) 4.23 4.25 4.38 4.39
[sigma] (TB/Y) 0.20 0.24 0.63 0.65
[sigma] ([R.sub.s]) 0.006 0.007 0.013 0.015
[rho] (c, y) 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99
[rho] (TB/Y, y) -0.43 -0.43 -0.29 -0.29
[rho] ([R.sub.s], y) -0.81 -0.74 -0.06 -0.09
[rho] ([R.sub.s], 0.85 0.89 0.89 0.91
TB/Y)
Mean Debt
Output Ratio (%) 6.8 6.8 4.7 4.8
Rate of Default 6.6 7.8 24 22
Notes: Business cycle statistics from models with output loss in one
period and models with a stochastic duration of the output loss. The
debt output ratio is measured as the stock of debt divided by the annual
output level.