Currency quality and changes in the behavior of depository institutions.
Janicki, Hubert P. ; Moin, Nashat F. ; Waddle, Andrea L. 等
The Federal Reserve System distributes currency to and accepts
deposits from Depository Institutions (DIs). In addition, the Federal
Reserve maintains the quality level of currency in circulation by
inspecting all deposited notes. Notes that meet minimum quality
requirements (fit notes) are bundled to be reentered into circulation
while old and damaged notes are destroyed (shredded) and replaced by
newly printed notes.
Between July 2006 and July 2007, the Federal Reserve implemented a
Currency Recirculation Policy for $10 and $20 notes. Under the new
policy, Reserve Banks will generally charge DIs a fee on the value of
deposits that are subsequently withdrawn by DIs within the same week. In
addition, under certain conditions the policy allows DIs to treat
currency in their own vaults as reserves with the Fed. It is reasonable
to expect that the policy change will result in DIs depositing a smaller
fraction of notes with the Fed. While the policy is aimed at decreasing
the costs to society of currency provision, it may also lead to
deterioration of the quality of notes in circulation since notes that
are deposited less often are inspected less often.
This article analyzes the interaction between deposit behavior of
DIs and the shred decision of the Fed in determining the quality
distribution of currency. For a given decrease in the rate of DIs'
note deposits with the Fed, absent any change in the Fed's shred
decision, what effect would there be on the quality distribution of
currency in circulation? What kind of changes in the shred criteria
would restore the original quality distribution?
To answer these questions, we use the model developed by Lacker and
Wolman (1997). (1) In the model, the evolution of the currency quality
distribution over time is governed by (i) a quality transition matrix
that describes the probabilistic deterioration of notes from one period
to the next, (ii) DIs' deposit probabilities for notes at each
quality level, (iii) the Fed's shred decision for notes at each
quality level, (iv) the quality distribution of new notes, and (v) the
growth rate of currency.
We estimate three versions of the model for both $5 and $10 notes.
We have not estimated the model for $20 notes because they were
redesigned recently, and the new notes were introduced in October 2003.
The transition from old to new notes makes our estimation procedure
impractical; we discuss this further in the Conclusion. (2) Although the
policy affects $10 and $20 notes only, we also estimate the model for $5
notes because the policy change initially proposed in 2003 included $5
notes. (It is possible that at some point the recirculation policy might
be expanded to cover that denomination.) Also, it is likely that the
reduced deposits of $10 and $20 notes may induce DIs to change the
frequency of transporting notes to the Fed and, hence, affect the
deposit rate of other denominations. The model predicts roughly
comparable results for both denominations.
In each version of our model, we choose parameters so that the
model approximates the age and quality distributions of U.S. currency
deposited at the Fed. For each estimated model, we describe the
deterioration of currency quality following decreases in DI deposit
rates of 20 and 40 percent, and we provide examples of Fed policy
changes that would counteract that deterioration. As described in more
detail below, we view a 40 percent decrease in deposit rates as an upper
bound on the change induced by the recirculation policy.
According to the model(s), a 20 percent decrease in the DI deposit
rate would eventually result in an increase in the number of poor
quality (unfit) notes of between 0.8 and 2.5 percentage points. While
this range corresponds to different specifications of the model, not to
a statistical confidence interval, it should be interpreted as
indicating the range of uncertainty about our results. For $10 notes,
very small changes in shred policy succeed in preventing a significant
increase in the fraction of unfit notes. (3) Slightly larger changes in
shred policy are required to keep the fraction of unfit $5 notes from
increasing in response to a 20 percent lower deposit rate. Naturally, a
40 percent decrease in deposit rates would cause a larger increase in
the number of unfit notes, although the greatest increase we find is
still less than 6 percentage points. And even in that case there are
straightforward changes in shred policy that would be effective in
restoring the level of currency quality.
1. INSTITUTIONAL BACKGROUND
Federal Reserve Banks issue new and fit used notes to DIs and
destroy previously circulated notes of poor quality. In order to
maintain the quality level of currency in circulation, the Fed uses
machines to inspect currency notes deposited by DIs at Federal Reserve
currency processing offices. These machines inspect each note to confirm
its denomination and authenticity, and measure its quality level on many
dimensions. The dimensions that are measured include soil level, tears,
graffiti or marks, and length and width of the currency notes. Fit notes
are those that pass the threshold quality level on all dimensions. Once
sorted, the fit notes are bundled and then recirculated when DIs request
currency from the Reserve Banks. To replace destroyed notes and
accommodate growth in currency demand, the Federal Reserve orders new
notes from the Bureau of Engraving and Printing (B.E.P.) of the U.S.
Department of Treasury. The Fed purchases the notes from B.E.P. at the
cost of production. (4) In 2006, the Federal Reserve ordered 8.5 billion
new notes from the B.E.P., at a cost of $471.2 million (Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2006a)--approximately 5.5 cents
per note.
In 2006, the Federal Reserve took in deposits of 38 billion notes,
paid out 39 billion notes, and destroyed 7 billion notes (Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco 2006). Of the 19.9 million pounds of notes
destroyed every year, approximately 48 percent are $1 notes, which have
a life expectancy of about 21 months. The $5, $10, and $20 denominations
last roughly 16, 18, and 24 months, respectively (Bureau of Engraving
and Printing 2007). Each day of 2005, the Federal Reserve's largest
cash operation, in East Rutherford, New Jersey, destroyed approximately
5.2 million notes, worth $95 million (Federal Reserve Bank of New York 2006).
Costs and Benefits of Currency Processing and Currency Quality
The Federal Reserve's operating costs for currency processing
in 2006 were $319 million (Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 2006).
DIs benefit from the Fed's currency processing services in at least
two ways. First, the Federal Reserve ships out only fit currency,
whereas DIs accumulate a mixture of fit and unfit currency; to the
extent that DIs' customers--and their ATMs--demand fit currency,
DIs benefit from the Fed's sorting of currency. Second, while DIs
need to hold currency to meet their customers' withdrawals, they
also incur costs by holding inventories of currency in their vaults.
Currency inventories take up valuable space and require expenditures on
security systems; in addition, currency in the vault is
"idle," whereas currency deposited with the Fed is eligible to
be lent out in the federal funds market at a positive nominal interest
rate. Thus, the Fed's currency processing services amount to an
inventory management service for DIs. The benefits DIs accrue from
currency processing may not coincide exactly with the benefits to
society. On one hand, positive nominal interest rates make the
inventory-management benefit to DIs of currency processing exceed the
social benefit (Friedman 1969). On the other hand, the social benefits
of improved currency quality may exceed the quality benefits that accrue
to DIs: for example, maintaining high currency quality may deter
counterfeiting by making counterfeit notes easier to detect (Klein,
Gadbois, and Christie 2004). On net, it seems unlikely that the social
benefit of currency processing greatly (if at all) exceeds the private
benefit. This implies that it would be optimal for DIs to face some
positive price for currency processing. Lacker (1993) discusses in
detail the policy question of whether the Federal Reserve should
subsidize DIs' use of currency.
Historically, the Federal Reserve did not charge DIs for processing
currency deposits and withdrawals. (5) Policy did prohibit a DI's
office from cross-shipping currency; cross-shipping is defined as
depositing fit currency with the Fed and withdrawing currency from the
Fed within the same five-day period. However, as explained in the
Federal Reserve Board's request for comments that introduced the
proposed recirculation policy (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System 2003a), the restriction on cross-shipping was not practical to
enforce. Thus, overall the Federal Reserve cash services policy clearly
subsidized DIs' use of currency.
Policy Revision
By 2003, the Federal Reserve had come to view existing policy as
leading DIs to overuse the Fed's currency processing services
(Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2003b). Factors
contributing to this situation included an increase in the number of ATM
machines and a decrease in the magnitude of required reserves. The
former likely increased the value of the Fed's sorting services,
and the latter meant that for a given flow of currency deposits and
withdrawals by the DIs' customers, there would be greater demand by
DIs to transform vault cash into reserves with the Fed--which requires
utilizing the Fed's processing services. In October 2003, the
Federal Reserve proposed and requested comments on changes to its cash
services policy, aimed at reducing DIs' overuse of the Fed's
processing services (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
2003a). In March of 2006, a modified version of the proposal was adopted
as the Currency Recirculation Policy (Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System 2006b).
The Recirculation Policy has two components, both of which cover
only $10 and $20 denominations. The first component is a custodial
inventory program. This program enables qualified DIs to hold currency
at the DI's secured facility while transferring it to the Reserve
Bank's ledger--thus making the funds available for lending to other
institutions but avoiding both the transportation cost and the
Fed's processing cost. DIs must apply to be in the custodial
inventory program. One criterion for qualifying is that a DI must
demonstrate that it can recirculate a minimum of 200 bundles (of 1,000
notes each) of $10 and $20 notes per week in the Reserve Bank zone. The
policy's second component is a fee of approximately $5 per bundle
of cross-shipped currency. While this new policy is aimed at reducing
the social costs incurred because of cross-shipping currency, absent
changes in shred policy it is likely to lower the quality of currency in
circulation through reduced deposits and thus reduced shredding of unfit
currency. (6) The primary concerns of our study are the effect on
currency quality of the anticipated decrease in deposit rates, and the
measures the Fed can take to offset that decrease in quality. To address
these issues we construct a model of currency quality. We assume that
shredding policy is aimed at restoring or maintaining the original
quality distribution. If the cost of maintaining quality at current
levels exceeds the social benefits of doing so, it would be optimal to
let the quality of currency deteriorate somewhat.
2. THE MODEL
The model applies to one denomination of currency. (7) Time is
discrete, and a time period should be thought of as a month. For the
purposes of this study, there are three major dimensions to currency
quality: soil level front (we will use the shorthand "soil
level" or SLF), ink wear worst front ("ink wear" or
IWWF), and graffiti worst front ("graffiti" or GWF). There are
also at least 18 minor dimensions to currency: soil level back, graffiti
total front, etc. For a given denomination, we have separate models for
each major dimension. (8) Those models describe, for example, how the
distribution over soil level evolves over time. For each of those
models, however, we use data on the other dimensions to more accurately
describe the probability that a note of a particular major-dimension
quality level will be shredded. (9)
The basic structure of the model is as follows. At the beginning of
each period, banks deposit currency with the Fed; their deposit decision
may be a function of quality in the major dimension (that is, banks may
sort for fitness). The Fed processes deposited notes, shredding those
deemed unfit and recirculating the rest at the end of the period. The
shred decision is based on quality level in whatever major dimension the
model is specified. However, notes that are fit according to their
quality level in the major dimension are nonetheless shredded with
positive probability; this is to account for the fact that they may be
unfit along one of the other (major or minor) dimensions in which the
model is not specified. The stock of currency is assumed to grow at a
constant rate. Banks make withdrawals from the Fed at the end of the
period but these are not specified explicitly; instead, withdrawals can
be thought of as a residual that more than offsets deposits in order to
make the quantity of currency grow at the specified rate. In order to
accommodate growth in currency and replace shredded notes, the Fed must
introduce newly printed notes. Meanwhile, the notes that were not
deposited with the Fed deteriorate in quality stochastically. The
quality of notes in circulation at the end of a period, and thus at the
beginning of the next period, is determined by the quality of notes that
have remained in circulation and the quality of notes withdrawn from the
Fed.
Formal Specification of the Model
Time is indexed by a subscript t = 0, 1, 2,.... Soil level can take
on values 0, 1, 2,..., [n.sub.s] - 1; ink wear can take on values 0, 1,
2,..., [n.sub.u] - 1; and graffiti can take on values 0, 1, 2,...,
[n.sub.g] - 1; in general, larger numbers denote poorer quality. (10) We
will use q to denote a particular (arbitrary) quality level.
For the DIs' deposit decision, the vector p contains in its
qth element the probability that a DI will deposit a note conditional on
that note being of quality level q. The vector [rho] has length Q, where
Q = [n.sub.s] or [n.sub.i] or [n.sub.g], depending on the particular
model in question. For the Fed's fitness criteria, the Q x 1
vector[alpha] contains in its qth element the probability that a
deposited note of quality q is put back into circulation. If the model
were specified in terms of every quality characteristic--so that Q were
a huge number describing every possible combination of "soil level
front," "soil level back," etc.--then the elements of
[alpha] would each be zero or one and they would be known parameters,
taken from the machine settings. Because the model is specified in terms
of only one characteristic, the elements of [alpha] that would be one
according to q are adjusted downward to account for the fact that some
quality-q notes are unfit according to other dimensions of quality. The
values of [alpha] must then be estimated, and we describe in Section 4
how they are estimated.
The net growth rate of the quantity of currency is [gamma]; that
is, if the quantity of currency is M in period t, then it is (1 +
[gamma]) M in period (t + 1). The Q x 1 vector g describes the
distribution of new notes; its qth element is the probability that a
newly printed note is of quality q. (11) The deterioration of
non-deposited notes is described by the Q x Q matrix [pi]; the row-r
column-c element of [pi] is the probability that a non-deposited note
will become quality r next period, conditional on it being quality-c
this period. (12) Note that each column of [pi] sums to one, because any
column q contains the probabilities of all possible transitions from
quality level q.
The model's endogenous variables are the numbers of notes of
different quality levels, i.e., the quality distribution of currency. At
the beginning of period t, the Q x 1 vector [m.sub.t] contains in its
qth element the number of notes in circulation of quality q. The total
number of notes in circulation is [M.sub.t] =
[[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q] [m.sub.q,t] where [m.sub.q,t] denotes the
qth element of the vector [m.sub.t].
Combining these ingredients, the number of notes at each quality
level evolves as follows:
[m.sub.t+1.[Q x 1]] = [[pi].[Q x Q]] x ([(1 - [rho]).[Q x 1]]
[circle] [m.sub.t.[Q x 1]]) + [[alpha].[Q x 1]] [circle] [[rho].[Q x 1]]
[circle] [m.sub.t.[Q x 1]] + [([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q](1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][m.sub.q,t]).[1 x 1]][g.[Q x 1]] +
[([gamma][M.sub.t]).[1 x 1]][g.[Q x 1]]. (1)
The symbol [circle] denotes element-by-element multiplication of
vectors or matrices. (13)
Equation (1) is the model, although we will rewrite it in terms of
fractions of notes instead of numbers of notes. On the left-hand side,
[m.sub.t+1] contains the number of notes at each quality level at the
beginning of period t + 1. The right-hand side describes how [m.sub.t+1]
is determined from the interaction of [m.sub.t] (the number of notes at
each quality level at the beginning of period t) with the model's
parameters. The first term on the right-hand side is
[[pi].[Q x Q]] x ([(1 - [rho]).[Q x 1]] [circle] [m.sub.t.[Q x
1]]). (2)
This term accounts for the fractions (1 - [rho]) of notes at each
quality level that are not deposited. These notes deteriorate according
to the matrix [pi], and thus the first term is a Qx1 vector containing
in its qth element the number of circulating notes that were not
deposited in period t and that begin period t + 1 with quality q. If
banks were to sort for fitness, then the notes that remain in
circulation and deteriorate during the period would be relatively high
quality notes, otherwise they would be a random sample of notes. The
matrix [pi] has [Q.sup.2] elements; assigning numbers to those elements
will be the key difficulty we face in choosing parameters for the model.
The second term is
[[alpha].[Q x 1]] [circle] [[rho].[Q x 1]] [circle] [m.sub.t.[Q x
1]]. (3)
This term accounts for the fractions [alpha] [circle] [rho] of
notes at each quality level that are deposited and not shredded--that
is, [alpha] [circle] [rho] [circle] [m.sub.t] comprises the deposited
notes at each quality level that are fit and will be put back into
circulation at the end of period t. If banks were to sort for fitness in
a manner consistent with the Fed's fitness definitions, and if
banks possessed enough unfit notes to meet their deposit needs, then
this term would disappear--all deposited notes would be shredded.
The third term, ([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q] (1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][m.sub.q,t]) [g.[Q x 1]], represents
replacement of shredded notes. The object in parentheses is the number
of unfit notes that are processed (and shredded) each period.
Multiplying by the distribution of new notes g gives the vector of new
notes at each quality level that are added to circulation at the end of
period t to replace shredded notes.
The fourth term, [([gamma][M.sub.t]).[1 x 1]][g.[Q x 1]],
represents growth in the quantity of currency. The number of new notes
added to circulation to accommodate growth (as opposed to shredding) is
[gamma] [M.sub.t], and the distribution of new notes is g, so this term
is a vector containing the numbers of new notes at each quality level
added to circulation at the end of period t to accommodate growth.
We noted above that withdrawals are not treated explicitly in the
model. The quantity of withdrawals can, however, be calculated. The
number of notes withdrawn in period t must be equal to the sum of
deposits and currency growth. That is, withdrawals equal
([Q.summation over (q=1)] [[rho].sub.q][m.sub.q,t]) +
[gamma][M.sub.t]. (4)
Note that the model does not incorporate currency inventories at
the Fed. New notes materialize as needed, and fit notes deposited at the
Fed are recirculated at the end of the period.
The evolution of currency quality over time is determined entirely
by equation (1). Given a vector [m.sub.t] describing the distribution of
currency quality at the beginning of any period t, equation (1)
determines the vector [m.sub.t+1] describing the distribution of
currency quality at the beginning of period t + 1. The law of motion is
determined by the parameters [pi], [rho], g, [gamma], and [alpha]. (14)
The Model in Terms of Fractions of Notes
The model has been expressed in terms of the numbers of notes at
each quality level. To express the model in terms of fractions of notes
at each quality level, we first define [f.sub.t] to be the vector of
fractions, that is the Qx 1 vector of numbers of notes at each quality
level divided by the total number of notes:
[f.sub.t] [equivalent to] (1/[M.sub.t]) x [m.sub.t]. (5)
Likewise, the fraction of notes at a particular quality level is
[f.sub.q,t] [equivalent to] (1/[M.sub.t]) x [m.sub.q,t]. (6)
Note that the elements of [f.sub.t] sum to one, because [M.sub.t] =
[[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q] [m.sub.q,t]. Using these definitions, we can
rewrite the model (1) by dividing both sides by [M.sub.t] and recalling
that [M.sub.t+1] = (1 + [gamma]) [M.sub.t]:
(1 + [gamma]) [f.sub.t+1] = [pi] x ((1 - [rho]) [circle] [f.sub.t])
+ [alpha] [circle] [rho] [circle] [f.sub.t] +
([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q](1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][f.sub.q,t]) g + [gamma]g. (7)
With this formulation it will be straightforward to study the
model's steady state with currency growth.
The Steady-State Distribution of Notes
Under certain conditions, the distribution of currency quality
converges to a steady state with the distribution [f.sub.t], which is
constant over time (see, for example, Stokely, Lucas, with Prescott,
chap. 11). Assuming that a unique steady-state distribution exists, we
will denote it by f*. In the steady state, the law of motion (7) becomes
(1 + [gamma]) f* = [pi] x ((1 - [rho]) [circle] f*) + [alpha]
[circle] [rho] [circle] f* + ([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q](1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][f*.sub.q])g + [gamma]g. (8)
Our method of choosing the model's parameters will require us
to compute the steady-state distribution--we will assume that our data
are generated in a steady-state situation. One way to compute the steady
state is to simply iterate on (7) from some arbitrary initial
distribution [f.sub.0] and hope that the iterations converge. If they
converge, we have found the steady state. Alternatively, we can use
matrix algebra to solve directly for the steady state from (8).
Ultimately, we want to rewrite (8) in the form
[GAMMA] x f* = [gamma]g, (9)
where [GAMMA] is a Q x Q matrix. If we can rewrite (8) in this way,
then the steady-state distribution is f* = [[GAMMA].sup.-1] x
([gamma]g). The first step is to note that for any Q x 1 vector
[upsilon], we have [upsilon] [circle] f* = diag([upsilon]) x f*, where
diag([upsilon]) denotes the Q x Q matrix with the vector [upsilon] on
the diagonal and zeros, elsewhere. Using this fact, we can rewrite (8)
as
(1 + [gamma]) f* = [pi] x diag(1 - [rho]) x f* + diag ([alpha]
[circle] [rho]) x f* + ([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q](1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][f*.sub.q]) g + [gamma]g. (10)
Next, note that the scalar ([[summation].sub.q=1.sup.Q](1 -
[[alpha].sub.q])[[rho].sub.q][f*.sub.q]) can be rewritten as ((1 -
[alpha]) [circle] [rho])' f*, where "'" denotes
transpose. Using this fact, we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (11)
Now we can express (8) in the same form as (9), [GAMMA] x f* =
[gamma]g, where
[GAMMA] [equivalent to] [(1 + [gamma]) I - [pi] x diag(1 - [rho]) -
diag ([alpha] [circle] [rho]) - g ((1 - [alpha]) [circle]
[rho])'][.sup.-1]. (12)
Thus, the steady state can be computed directly as
f* = [[GAMMA].sup.-1] x ([gamma]g).
The steady-state distribution f* contains in its qth element the
fraction of notes with quality q, corresponding to a particular
measurement of soil level, graffiti or ink wear. Thus, f* can be thought
of as the marginal distribution over soil level, graffiti or ink wear.
When comparing the model to data, we will use the marginal distributions
for each major quality dimension and the distribution of notes by age.
We use the age distribution because the quality distribution alone puts
few restrictions on the matrix [pi]: we can match a given quality
distribution with many [pi] matrices, each implying a different age
distribution.
The Appendix contains a detailed description of how to calculate
the steady-state age distribution of notes. For now, we simply state the
notation: [h.sub.q,k] denotes the fraction of notes that are quality q
and age k, and [h.sub.k] denotes the Q by 1 vector of age k notes, the
qth element of which is [h.sub.q,k].
3. THE DATA
The model's predictions will depend on the numerical values we
assign to the matrix [pi] describing deterioration of notes, the vector
[rho] of deposit probabilities, the vector [alpha] of shred
probabilities, the quality distribution of new notes g, and the currency
growth rate [gamma]. This section describes the basic data whose
features we attempt to match in choosing the model's parameters.
The ideal data set for our purposes would be one with a time series
of observations on a large number of currency notes, with observations
each month on the quality of every note. Data of this sort would allow
for nearly direct measurement of the matrix [pi]. Of course such data
does not exist, and probably the only way it could exist would be if
individual notes had built-in sensors and transmitters. Without such
data, we need to estimate the parameters of [pi]. We use two data sets
for this purpose. One data set describes the marginal quality
distributions only and has extremely broad coverage. The other data set
is at the level of individual notes, and contains age of notes as well
as quality. It has more limited coverage.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Large Data Set Describing Marginal Distributions
The large data set comprises fitness data for the entire Federal
Reserve System for the months of January 2004 and May 2004, provided by
the Currency Technology Office (CTO) at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond. This data characterizes the marginal quality distributions for
more than two-and-a-half billion notes. The data are at the level of
office location, date, shift, supervisor, and denomination. For a
particular denomination, we assume that summing these data over all
dates, supervisors, and shifts generates a precise estimate of the
steady-state marginal distribution over each quality level. Figures 1
and 2 plot the marginal distributions over soil level, ink wear and
graffiti for the combined January and May 2004 data, for $5 and $10
notes (solid lines). (15)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The raw data have 26 quality levels for each category. However, for
many quality levels there are very few notes, and for speed of
computation it is advantageous to decrease the number of quality levels.
For each denomination and each category (e.g., SLF) we have, therefore,
combined multiple quality levels into one. For example, our new soil
level zero for the $10 notes includes all notes with soil levels zero
through 2 in the data. Table 1 contains comprehensive information about
how we combine quality levels. Boxes around multiple quality levels
indicate that we have combined them, and the columns labeled
"q" contain the quality level numbers corresponding to our
smaller set of quality levels. After combining in this way, we are left
with between 7 and 13 quality levels for each denomination and category.
For each denomination and each dimension, there are three unfit quality
levels. For example, for the $5 notes SLF, quality levels 9, 10, and 11
are unfit.
Per-Note Data
In addition to the comprehensive data set describing marginal
distributions, we use per-note data sets covering approximately 45,000
notes each of $5 notes and $10 notes. These data were gathered at nine
Federal Reserve offices in February and March 2006. For each note, there
is information on the date of issue, as well as quality level in at
least 21 categories, including SLF, GWF, and IWWF. The dotted lines in
Figures 1 and 2 are the marginal quality distributions for SLF, IWWF,
and GWF from the per-note data for the $5 and $10 notes. There are minor
differences relative to the marginal distributions from the large data
set, but the broad patterns are the same. This gives us some confidence
that the per-note data are representative samples.
Because the note data contain date of issue for each note, we are
able to get an estimate of the age distribution of notes. In Figure 3,
the jagged dotted line is a smoothed version of the age distribution of
unfit notes from the note data. The smoothing method involves taking a
three-month moving average. Without smoothing, the age distributions
would be extremely choppy. Note that in Figure 3, we plot the age
distribution of unfit notes. It is the unfit notes with which we are
most concerned for this study, and whose age distribution we care most
about matching with the model. Unfit notes are those notes whose quality
is worse than the shred threshold in any dimension--major or minor.
4. CHOOSING THE MODEL'S PARAMETERS
There are [Q.sup.2] + 3Q + 1 parameters in each model; they
comprise the [Q.sup.2] elements of [pi], the 3Q elements of [alpha],
[rho], and g, and the single parameter [gamma]. (16) Since Q is between
7 and 13, the number of parameters is between 71 and 209. We select the
model's parameters in several stages. (17)
First, we make some a priori assumptions on the transition matrix
[pi] that decrease the number of free parameters. Next, we pin down g,
[alpha], [gamma], and [rho] based on information from the Federal
Reserve System's Currency Technology Office, the Federal Reserve
Board, and preliminary analysis of the data. We select the remaining
parameters so that the model's steady-state distribution matches
the quality and age distributions in Figures 1-3.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
At this point, it may be useful to remind the reader where we are:
we have specified a model of the evolution of currency quality, and we
will now use data from the period before implementation of the currency
recirculation policy in order to choose parameters of the model. Once
the parameters have been chosen, we will simulate the model under
particular assumptions about how DI behavior will change in response to
the recirculation policy. The recirculation policy itself is
"outside the model"; the model does not address pricing of
currency processing by the Fed, and the model does not address
(intraweek) cross-shipping because it is specified at a monthly
frequency.
A Priori Restrictions on [pi]
We reduce the number of parameters determining [pi] by imposing the
restriction that notes never improve in quality, except that soil level
may "improve" to zero if a note is laundered (i.e., the note
has gone through a washing machine). This restriction means that almost
half the elements of [pi] are zeros. For the ink wear and graffiti
model, all elements above the main diagonal are zero. For the soil level
model, the elements above the main diagonal are zero except in the first
row, which may contain nonzero elements in every column to account for
the possibility of laundered notes; in the first column, the first row
contains a one and all other rows contain zeros, because a laundered
note always remains laundered. The numbers of nonzero elements in [pi]
are thus ([[[n.sub.s]([n.sub.s] + 1)]/2] + [n.sub.s] - 1),
[[n.sub.i]([n.sub.i] + 1)]/2 and [[n.sub.g]([n.sub.g] + 1)]/2 for the
three models. The last restriction we impose on [pi] is an inherent
feature of the model: the columns of [pi] must sum to one, and [pi] is a
stochastic matrix with each element weakly between zero and one. This
adds Q restrictions, subtracting an equal number of parameters.
Choosing [alpha], g, [rho], and [gamma]
The Federal Reserve chooses the definition of fit notes, so there
would be no difficulty determining [alpha] if the model were specified
in terms of all quality dimensions simultaneously; [[alpha].sub.q] would
be one for fit notes and zero for unfit notes. However, since we specify
the model in terms of only one dimension, we need to adjust the shred
parameter [alpha] to reflect the fact that notes may be unfit even
though they are fit according to the dimension in which the model is
specified. For example, if the model is specified in terms of soil
level, a note that is very clean may nonetheless be unfit because of its
level of ink wear. We adjust for this possibility as follows, using the
soil level example: for each fit degree of soil level q, calculate the
fraction of notes with soil level q that are unfit according to other
dimensions and subtract that fraction from [[alpha].sub.q]. That
calculation is necessarily based on the per-note data, as it requires
going beyond marginal distributions. The corrections we make to [alpha]
are shown in Table 2.
The vector g represents the quality distribution of newly printed
notes. Our estimates of g are from the Federal Reserve System's
Currency Technology Office (unpublished data), and these are presented
in Table 3. Sorting behavior by DIs is captured by the vector [rho].
We assume that DIs do not sort, which implies that all elements of
[rho] are identical and are equal to the fraction of notes that DIs
deposit each period. (18) We set each element of [rho] to 0.1165 for the
$5 notes and 0.1322 for the $10 notes. These numbers are based on data
from the Federal Reserve Board (S. Ferrari, pers. comm.). Finally,
[gamma] is the growth rate of the stock of currency. We have set the
annual growth rate at 1.78 percent for the $5 notes, and 0.38 percent
for the $10 notes, again based on data from the Federal Reserve Board
(S. Ferrari, pers. comm.).
Matching the Quality and Age Data
We select the remaining parameters of the matrix [pi]--for each
specification of the model--so that the model's steady-state
distribution matches as closely as possible two features of the data.
First, we want to match the marginal quality distribution from the 2004
comprehensive data (Figures 1 and 2, solid line). Second, we want to
match the age distribution of unfit notes from the 2006 per-note data
(Figure 3). Concretely, we select the parameters of [pi] to minimize a
weighted average of (i) the sum of squared deviations between the
marginal quality distribution and that predicted by the model, and (ii)
the sum of squared deviations between the unfit age distributions and
that predicted by the model. (19) Table 4 contains one example of the
[pi] matrix; it is for the GWF model of $5 notes.
With respect to the marginal quality distributions, we have no
trouble matching the data. In all of the model specifications, we match
the marginal quality distributions nearly perfectly. The age
distributions are a different matter, which perhaps is not surprising
given their choppiness in the data--the model wants to make the age
distribution of unfit notes smooth. Figure 3 plots the age distributions
implied by each specification of the model, along with the age
distributions from the data. (20) With the exception of the SLF model
for $5 notes, the age distributions implied by the model involve too
many unfit notes more than approximately four years old.
5. SIMULATING A CHANGE IN DI BEHAVIOR
Because the response of the quality distribution to a decrease in
deposit rates depends on the transition matrix [pi], the fact that we
have multiple models means that we generate a range of responses to a
decrease in deposit rates. Figures 4 and 5 plot the time series for the
fraction of unfit notes, in response to 20 and 40 percent decreases in
DIs' deposit rates, respectively. According to final Currency
Recirculation Policy (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
2006b), of the $10 and $20 notes processed by the Fed in 2004, 40.4
percent were cross-shipped. Thus, a 40 percent decrease in deposits
corresponds to DIs ceasing entirely to cross-ship. This seems unlikely,
so we view the 40 percent number as an upper bound on the effect of the
recirculation policy. In addition, cross-shipping is likely more
important for $20 notes than $10 notes, because of the necessity of
having crisp (fit) $20 notes in ATM machines. Since the DIs always
receive fit notes from the Federal Reserve System, a larger volume of
$20 notes are cross-shipped than any other denomination. (21) Thus, the
40.4 percent upper bound for $10 notes and $20 notes combined is higher
than the upper bound for the $10 notes or $5 notes.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Each line in Figures 4 and 5 represents the transition path for the
fraction of unfit notes for a different major dimension model (soil
level, ink wear, graffiti). In response to a 20 percent decrease in the
deposit rate, the models predict a long-run increase in the fraction of
unfit notes of between 0.017 and 0.025 for the $5 notes (i.e., around
two percentage points), and between 0.008 and 0.018 for the $10 notes.
In our large data sets, the total fractions of unfit notes are 0.173 for
the $5 notes and 0.150 for the $10 notes. Note that the model that
provides the best fit to the age distribution ($5 SLF) is also the model
that predicts the largest increase in the fraction of unfit notes,
0.025. Not surprisingly, a 40 percent decrease in deposit rates
generates a larger increase in the fraction of unfit notes--between
0.044 and 0.055 for the $5 notes and between 0.019 and 0.044 for the $10
notes.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figures 6, 7, 8, and 9 provide a different perspective on the
effects of a decrease in deposit rates. These figures plot on the same
panel the initial steady-state quality distribution (prior to the drop
in deposit rates) and the new steady-state quality distribution
corresponding to the lower deposit rate. For the 20 percent experiment
(Figures 6 and 7), the long-run effects on quality are generally small,
reinforcing the message of Figure 4. There are, however, certain quality
levels that are strongly affected. For example, the fraction of $10
notes at soil level 6 (in Figure 7) eventually rises from 0.13 to 0.1832
in response to the 20 percent drop in deposits. For the 40 percent
experiment, things look somewhat more dramatic: for example, the
fraction of $10 notes at soil level 6 increases from 0.13 to 0.27 (in
Figure 9). To put this change in perspective though, Table 2 tells us
that only 6.2 percent of the level 6 SLF $10 notes are unfit, so the big
increase in notes at that level (which is still fit according to SLF)
brings with it an increase of less than one percentage point in unfit
notes. Recall that the change in total fraction of unfit notes is shown
in Figures 4 and 5.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
If the Fed wished to offset the quality deterioration caused by a
decrease in deposit rates, a natural policy would be to shred notes of
higher quality. Table 5 displays scenarios for fraction of notes to
shred at each quality level in order to maintain the fraction of unfit
notes at its old steady-state level. For example, if deposit rates fall
20 percent, our SLF model for $5 notes implies that shredding all notes
in the worst-fit category and shredding 35 percent of notes in the
second worst-fit category would counteract the deposit decrease, leaving
the fraction of notes unchanged. The columns in this table should be
read independently, as they each apply to distinct models. In other
words, the column labeled $5 SLF provides a policy change for SLF that
is predicted to bring about a stable fraction of unfit notes; no changes
are made to shred thresholds for other dimensions. Note that we have
omitted GWF from the analysis in Table 1; we were not successful in
finding policies that counteracted the quality decline by changing the
shred policy for GWF. In order to counteract the effects of a 40 percent
decrease in deposits, Reserve Banks would have to shred currency at
significantly higher quality levels, depending on the particular model
specification. In the most extreme case, which is the IWWF model for $10
notes, the worst six levels of fit notes would have to be shredded
(quality levels four through nine), and 22 percent of notes at quality
level 3 would have to be shredded to prevent overall quality from
deteriorating. Recall, however, that the 40 percent decrease in deposit
rates represents an upper bound on how we expect DIs to change their
behavior in response to the recirculation policy.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
6. CONCLUSION
The quality of currency in circulation is an important policy
objective for the Federal Reserve. Changes in the behavior of depository
institutions, whether caused by Fed policy or by independent factors,
can have implications for the evolution of currency quality. Currently
the Fed is implementing a recirculation policy, which is expected to
cause changes in the behavior of DIs and, therefore, affect currency
quality. The mechanical model of currency quality in this article can be
used to study the effects of changes in DI behavior and changes in Fed
policy on the quality distribution of currency. In general, the model
predicts relatively modest responses of currency quality to decreases in
DI deposit rates that are anticipated to occur as a consequence of the
recirculation policy. For $5 and $10 notes, our model is able to match
the marginal quality distributions perfectly, and the age distributions
of unfit notes reasonably well. Thus, we have some confidence in the
range of predictions that the different model specifications make for
the effects on currency quality of a decrease in deposit rates. In what
follows, we discuss potential extensions to the current analysis.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Although our framework allows for sorting by DIs, the quantitative
analysis has assumed no sorting occurs. If DIs do sort, then the
researcher must take into account that the distribution of currency in
circulation is not the same as the distribution of currency that visits
the Fed. The derivations in this report do not differentiate between the
two distributions, but it is straightforward to do so. If DIs were to
sort using the same criteria as the Federal Reserve, then it is likely
that the results presented here would overstate the decline in currency
quality following implementation of the recirculation policy; by
depositing with the Fed only low-quality notes, DIs would offset the
deleterious effect of depositing fewer notes. The recirculation policy
clearly provides an incentive for at least some DIs to sort because it
imposes fees for cross-shipment of fit currency only.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Our analysis has not addressed $20 notes. Figure 10 illustrates the
difficulty they present: they are not in a steady state but are
transiting from the old to the new design. Of the old notes, more than
10 percent are unfit, whereas of the new notes, less than 3 percent are
unfit. All the old notes are more than two years old, whereas all the
new notes are less than three years old. Our model is not inherently
restricted to steady state situations. To apply it to the 20s, one would
want to use the form of the model in (7) and also allow for [gamma] (the
growth rate of currency) to be time-varying or at least allow [gamma] to
vary across designs. The non-steady-state form of the model (7) also
could be useful more generally, in providing a check on our estimates.
If there is good data on marginal quality distributions available
monthly, then that data can be used to generate forecast errors for the
model on a real-time basis.
One reason to question the steady-state assumption is the
possibility that the payments system is in the midst of a transition
away from the use of currency and toward electronic forms of payment.
Although it is difficult to distinguish a change in the trend from a
transitory shock, data on the stock of currency does give some credence
to this concern: from 2002 to 2007 the growth rate of currency has
declined steadily, and at 2 percent for the 12 months ending in June
2007 it is currently growing more slowly than most measures of nominal
spending. A decreasing currency growth rate means that there is a
decreasing rate of new notes introduced into circulation. This would
likely require stronger measures by the Federal Reserve to maintain
currency quality in response to a decrease in deposit rates.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
The version of the model estimated here is very small and easy to
estimate. Expanding the model so that it describes the joint
distribution of all three quality dimensions studied here leads to an
unmanageably large system. A middle ground that might be worth pursuing
would be to specify the model in terms of two dimensions, say graffiti
and soil level, and include information about unfitness in other
dimensions, as we have done here.
Finally, it would be useful to embed the currency quality model of
this article in an economic model of DIs and households. The DIs'
deposit rate and sorting policy (both summarized by [rho]) would then be
endogenously determined. Such a model could be used to predict the
effects of a change in the Federal Reserve's pricing policy on DI
behavior. It could also be used to conduct welfare analysis of different
pricing and shredding policies. The model in Lacker (1993) is a natural
starting point.
APPENDIX: DETAILS OF CALCULATING AGE DISTRIBUTION
It is straightforward to compute the age distribution of notes for
any quality level and the quality distribution at any age. Begin by
defining the fraction of notes at quality level q and age k to be
[h.sub.q,k]. These fractions satisfy
1 = [[infinity].summation over (k=0)][Q.summation over
(q=1)][h.sub.q,k]. (13)
For convenience, define [h.sub.k] to be the Q-vector containing in
element q, the fraction of notes that are k-periods old, and in quality
level q:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (14)
We also have that [h.sub.q,k] = ([e.sub.q.sup.Q])' [h.sub.k],
where [e.sub.q.sup.Q] is a Q x 1 selection vector with a 1 in the qth
element and zeros elsewhere.
The fraction of brand-new notes is
[Q.summation over (q=1)][h.sub.q,0] = [[gamma]/[1 + [gamma]]] +
[N.summation over (j=1)](1 - [[alpha].sub.j])[[rho].sub.j][f*.sub.j],
(15)
and since the quality distribution of new notes is g, the fractions
of notes that are new and in each quality level q are
[h.sub.0] = ([[gamma]/[1 + [gamma]]] + [N.summation over (j=1)](1 -
[[alpha].sub.j])[[rho].sub.j][f*.sub.j]) x g. (16)
For one-period old notes, the fractions are
[h.sub.1] = [[[pi] x diag (1 - [rho]) + diag ([alpha] [circle]
[rho])]/[1 + [gamma]]] x [h.sub.0]. (17)
Likewise, we have
[h.sub.k+1] = [[[pi] x diag (1 - [rho]) + diag ([alpha] [circle]
[rho])]/[1 + [gamma]]][.sup.k+1] x [h.sub.0], for k = 0, 1,..., (18)
with [h.sub.0] determined by (16). Thus, we can calculate the
fraction of notes at any age-quality combination as
[h.sub.q,k] = ([e.sub.q.sup.Q])' [[[pi] x diag (1 - [rho]) +
diag ([alpha] [cicle] [rho])]/[1 + [gamma]]][.sup.k] x [h.sub.0]. (19)
The age distribution of quality-q notes is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (20)
and the quality distribution of age-k notes is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (21)
REFERENCES
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2003a.
"Federal Reserve Bank Currency Recirculation Policy. Request for
Comment, notice." Docket No. OP-1164, October 7. Available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/Boarddocs/press/other/2003/20031008/attachment.pdf (accessed July 13, 2007).
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2003b. Press
release, October 8. Available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/press/other/2003/20031008/default.htm (accessed July 13, 2007).
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2006a.
"Appendix C. Currency Budget." Annual Report: Budget Review:
31.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2006b.
"Federal Reserve Currency Recirculation Policy. Final Policy."
Docket No. OP-1164, March 17. Available at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/other/other20060317al.pdf
(accessed July 13, 2007).
Bureau of Engraving and Printing. 2007. "Money Facts, Fun
Facts, Did You Know?" Available at:
http://www.bep.treas.gov/document.cfm/18/106 (accessed October 30,
2007).
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2006. "Currency Processing
and Destruction." Available at:
http://www.ny.frb.org/aboutthefed/fedpoint/fed11.html (accessed May 30,
2007).
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. 2006. "Cash
Counts." Annual Report: 6-17.
Federal Reserve System, Currency Quality Work Group. 2007.
"Federal Reserve Bank Currency Quality Monitoring Program."
Internal memo, June.
Ferrari, Shaun. 2005. "Division of Reserve Bank Operations and
Payment Systems." Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Governors. E-mail message to author, September 9, 2005.
Friedman, Milton. 1969. Optimum Quantity of Money: And Other
Essays. Chicago, IL: Aldine Publishing Company.
Klein, Raymond M., Simon Gadbois, and John J. Christie. 2004.
"Perception and Detection of Counterfeit Currency in Canada: Note
Quality, Training, and Security Features." In Optical Security and
Counterfeit Deterrence Techniques V, ed. Rudolf L. van Renesse, SPIE Conference Proceedings, vol. 5310.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. 1993. "Should We Subsidize the Use of
Currency?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 79
(1): 47-73.
Lacker, Jeffrey M., and Alexander L. Wolman. 1997. "A Simple
Model of Currency Quality." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
(November).
Stokely, Nancy L., Robert E. Lucas, Jr., with Edward C. Prescott.
1989. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
The authors are grateful to Barbara Bennett, Shaun Ferrari, Juan
Carlos Hatchondo, Chris Herrington, Jaclyn Hodges, Larry Hull, Andy
McAllister, David Vairo, John Walter, and John Weinberg for their input.
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the
Federal Reserve System. Correspondence should be directed to
alexander.wolman@rich.frb.org.
(1) The Appendix to Lacker (1993) contains a simpler model of
currency quality that shares some basic features with the model here.
(2) New $10 notes were introduced in March 2006 and new $5 notes
are expected to be introduced in 2008; our data were collected in 2004
and early 2006.
(3) We view "fit notes" as referring to any notes that
meet a fixed quality standard determined by the Federal Reserve. Prior
to a decrease in deposit rates, a fit note is synonymous with a note
that meets the Fed's quality threshold for not shredding. If the
Fed adjusts its shred policy in response to a decrease in deposit rates,
then it will shred some notes that were fit according to this fixed
standard.
(4) Thus, seigniorage for notes accrues initially to the Federal
Reserve. In contrast, the Fed purchases coins from the U.S. Mint (a part
of the Department of Treasury) at face value, so that seigniorage for
coins accrues directly to the Treasury.
(5) Note, however, that DIs do pay for transporting currency
between their own offices and Federal Reserve offices.
(6) Federal Reserve Banks have estimated that over 10 years, the
recirculation policy could reduce their currency processing costs by a
present value of $250 million. Taking into account increased DI costs,
the corresponding societal benefit is estimated at $140 million (Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2006b).
(7) By changing the parameters appropriately, it can be applied
separately to more than one denomination; indeed we will do just that.
(8) The models for the three major dimensions are truly separate,
in that they will yield different predictions.
(9) As mentioned earlier, the model was first developed in Lacker
and Wolman (1997). That article studied a different policy question,
namely expanding the dimensions of quality measurements to include
limpness.
(10) The exception is soil level zero, which is assumed to describe
currency that has been laundered (i.e., has been through a washing
machine) and is deemed unfit.
(11) We allow for new notes to have some variation in quality.
However, by choosing g appropriately we can impose the highest quality
level for all new notes.
(12) We assume that the number of notes is sufficiently large that
the probability that a quality c note makes a transition to quality r is
the same as the fraction of type c notes that make the transition to
type r. That is, the law of large numbers applies.
(13) For example, if a = [1, 2] and b = [3, 4]. then a [circle] b =
[3, 8].
(14) We have written the model as if all parameters are constant
over time. We maintain that assumption for the quantitative results
described in this report. The model remains valid if the parameters
change over time, although estimation becomes more challenging.
(15) The same data set covers $20 notes, but as described in the
Conclusion, our limited analysis of the 20s has not used this data.
(16) Recall that Q is either [n.sub.s], [n.sub.i], or [n.sub.g],
depending on the version of the model.
(17) Because our approach to selecting parameters is ad hoc. we
hesitate to talk about "estimating the model." However, in
effect that is what we are doing.
(18) A recent internal Federal Reserve study confirmed that DIs
have not been sorting to any appreciable extent, as the quality
distribution of currency that the Federal Reserve receives from DIs is
close to the quality distribution of currency in circulation (Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2007). However, the
recirculation policy--in particular, the fee for cross-shipping fit
currency--gives DIs an incentive to sort. We address this issue in the
Conclusion.
(19) We have also experimented with adding to our estimation
criterion the fraction of age k notes that are unfit, for k = 1, 2,...
For moderate weights on this component the results are not materially
affected.
(20) In Figure 3, the lines associated with the model stop at 56
months because we did not attempt to match the age distribution beyond
56 months.
(21) In 2005, the volume of $5, $10, and $20 notes that were
cross-shipped were 12.7 percent, 9.0 percent, and 78.3 percent,
respectively.
Table 1 Marginal Quality Distributions and Combined Quality Levels
$5 Notes
Quality Level SLF q IWWF q GWF q
0 0.000 0.059 0 0.000 0
1 0.000 0.342 1 0.333
2 0.000 0 0.121 2 0.454 1
3 0.004 0.086 3 0.138 2
4 0.039 0.067 4 0.036 3
5 0.094 1 0.054 5 0.015
6 0.116 2 0.044 6 0.008 4
7 0.128 3 0.037 0.005
8 0.140 4 0.031 0.003 5
9 0.139 5 0.027 7 0.002
10 0.122 6 0.023 0.002 6
11 0.093 7 0.019 0.001
12 0.056 8 0.017 0.001
13 0.027 0.014 8 0.001
14 0.013 9 0.011 0.001
15 0.007 0.009 0.000
16 0.005 0.007 9 0.000
17 0.004 10 0.005 0.000
18 0.003 0.004 0.000 7
19 0.002 0.004 10 0.000
20 0.002 0.003 0.000
21 0.002 0.002 0.000
22 0.001 11 0.002 0.000
23 0.001 0.002 11 0.000
24 0.001 0.001 0.000
25 0.000 0.008 0.000
$10 Notes
Quality Level SLF q IWWF q GWF q
0 0.000 0.040 0 0.001 0
1 0.000 0 0.300 1 0.602
2 0.001 0.106 2 0.257 1
3 0.014 1 0.084 3 0.078 2
4 0.068 0.075 4 0.030 3
5 0.122 2 0.069 5 0.012 4
6 0.143 3 0.063 6 0.006
7 0.157 4 0.056 0.004 5
8 0.153 5 0.049 7 0.003
9 0.130 6 0.041 0.002
10 0.096 7 0.033 0.001
11 0.058 8 0.026 8 0.001
12 0.027 0.019 0.001
13 0.012 9 0.013 9 0.001
14 0.006 0.009 0.000
15 0.004 0.006 0.000
16 0.003 10 0.003 10 0.000
17 0.002 0.002 0.000 6
18 0.002 0.001 0.000
19 0.001 0.001 11 0.000
20 0.001 0.000 0.000
21 0.000 11 0.000 0.000
22 0.000 0.000 0.000
23 0.000 0.000 12 0.000
24 0.000 0.000 0.000
25 0.000 0.001 0.000
Table 2 Corrections to [alpha] Vector
$5 Notes $10 Notes
q SLF q IWWF q GWF q SLF q IWWF q GWF
0 0 0 0.0850 0 0.0624 0 0 0 0.0255 0 0.0374
1 0.0375 1 0.1080 1 0.1215 1 0.0215 1 0.0545 1 0.1142
2 0.0640 2 0.1445 2 0.2795 2 0.0106 2 0.0654 2 0.2294
3 0.0867 3 0.1754 3 0.5783 3 0.0120 3 0.0868 3 0.3392
4 0.1150 4 0.1801 4 0 4 0.0272 4 0.0844 4 0
5 0.1417 5 0.2048 5 0 5 0.0389 5 0.0857 5 0
6 0.1852 6 0.2109 6 0 6 0.0622 6 0.0878 6 0
7 0.2546 7 0.2461 7 0 7 0.1132 7 0.1036
8 0.3658 8 0.2913 8 0.1890 8 0.1251
9 0 9 0 9 0 9 0.1496
10 0 10 0 10 0 10 0
11 0 11 0 11 0 11 0
12 0
Table 3 Quality Distribution of New Notes
$5 Notes $10 Notes
q SLF q IWWF q GWF q SLF q IWWF q GWF
0 0 0 1 0 0.935 0 0 0 1 0 1
1 0.010 1 0 1 0.065 1 0.965 1 0 1 0
2 0.695 2 0 2 0 2 0.035 2 0 2 0
3 0.295 3 0 3 0 3 0 3 0 3 0
4 0 4 0 4 0 4 0 4 0 4 0
5 0 5 0 5 0 5 0 5 0 5 0
6 0 6 0 6 0 6 0 6 0 6 0
7 0 7 0 7 0 7 0 7 0
8 0 8 0 8 0 8 0
9 0 9 0 9 0 9 0
10 0 10 0 10 0 10 0
11 0 11 0 11 0 11 0
12 0
Table 4 [pi] Matrix for $5 Notes According to GWF
q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
0 0.9469 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
1 0.0531 0.9755 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
2 0.0000 0.0224 0.9647 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0353 0.9945 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
4 0.0000 0.0022 0.0000 0.0000 0.8828 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
5 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0054 0.1148 0.8294 0.0000 0.0000
6 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0024 0.1706 0.9995 0.0000
7 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0005 1.0000
Notes: The row r, column c element of this matrix is the probability
that a note will become quality r next period, conditional on it being
of quality c in this period. For example, the probability that a note
will be of quality 4 in the next period, given that it is quality 1 in
this period is 0.0022, the element in row 4, column 1.
Table 5 Policy Response to Offset Effect of Deposit Rate Decrease
20 Percent Decrease in Deposits: Fraction of Notes to Shred
$5 Notes $10 Notes
q SLF q IWWF q SLF q IWWF
0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0
1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0
2 0 2 0 2 0 2 0
3 0 3 0 3 0 3 0
4 0 4 0 4 0 4 0
5 0 5 0 5 0 5 0
6 0 6 0 6 0 6 0
7 0.3512 7 0.0255 7 0 7 0
8 1 8 1 8 0.545 8 0
9 1 9 1 9 1 9 0.6845
10 1 10 1 10 1 10 1
11 1 11 1 11 1 11 1
12 1
40 Percent Decrease in Deposits: Fraction of Notes to Shred
$5 Notes $10 Notes
q SLF q IWWF q SLF q IWWF
0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0
1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0
2 0 2 0 2 0 2 0
3 0 3 0 3 0 3 0.22
4 0 4 0 4 0 4 1
5 0.198 5 0 5 0 5 1
6 1 6 0.48 6 0 6 1
7 1 7 1 7 0.125 7 1
8 1 8 1 8 1 8 1
9 1 9 1 9 1 9 1
10 1 10 1 10 1 10 1
11 1 11 1 11 1 11 1
12 1