The problem of small change in early Argentina.
Ennis, Huberto M.
Many economies, during the early stages of monetary development,
experienced what appear to be sporadic relative shortfalls of small
denomination means of payment. These episodes have been broadly
documented in the literature under the label of "shortages of small
change." Sargent and Velde (2002), for example, review in great
detail the evidence for Europe. Hanson (1979) provides an interesting
survey of the evidence for the British colonies in North America. The
purpose of this paper is to present evidence of similar events occurring
in the early monetary history of Argentina.
The provision of small change in modern economies has become almost
a nonissue. (1) In fiat money systems, the monetary authority controls
the aggregate supply of monetary balances (of all denominations) and
stands ready to exchange at par any denomination for an equivalent
amount of any other denomination. It is, then, demand that determines
the relative amounts of the different denominations that circulate in
the economy. There are, of course, costs of providing the demanded
amounts. Low-denomination coins tend to be relatively more costly to
produce (at least, per unit of value). Yet, in general, governments in
modern societies have considered these costs worthwhile.
Under a commodity money system it is also possible, in principle,
to solve the problem of the relative supply of denominations. Basically,
it requires issuing token coins that can be readily exchanged at par
with the monetary authority for full-bodied coins. (2) This monetary
arrangement is commonly known as the "standard formula" (see
Sargent and Velde 2002, 5). For some time, the production of token coins
represented a significant technological challenge. Since token coins are
worth more than their intrinsic value, counterfeiting is a very
profitable activity under the "standard formula" system. To
avoid counterfeiting, the coins need to be fairly sophisticated, which
increases their production cost. In the history of monetary systems,
before the technology for production of coins was well developed, token
coins were at best a very imperfect solution to the problem of small
change.
When all coins are full-bodied coins, as was the case in Spanish
America, the potential for mismatches on the demand and supply of
denominations becomes more likely. The minting cost per value is
normally lower for high-denomination coins. To the extent that coins
circulate at par value (i.e., without discounts), there are incentives
to mint only high-denomination coins. The historical record on the
shortages of small change is the story of monetary authorities that
struggled to sustain the proper mix of (full-bodied) high- and
low-denomination coins.
Imperfect private solutions to the shortage problem are possible.
For example, coins could be cut in portions to circumvent the
indivisibility barrier. Also, small change can be offered at a premium.
However, all these partial solutions bring forth the problems that arise
when high- and low-denomination coins do not exchange in convenient and
fixed ratios. These issues are most relevant in cases where the need for
small change originates in domestic transactions. Systematic negotiation
over discounts and measurement of effective coin weight, in this case,
involve very low-value amounts, most likely not worth the trouble.
In Search of a Formal Definition
Providing a precise theoretical definition of a shortage of small
change is no simple matter. Sargent and Velde (1999; 2002) consider a
model where low-denomination money can be used for "small" and
"large" transactions but high-denomination money can only be
used for "large" transactions. They then define a
"shortage" as a situation where the agents in the economy have
to adjust their consumption pattern to their holdings of
low-denomination money while, at the same time, holding an
"excess" stock of the high-denomination money. In other words,
at the time of consumption decisions, the agent's holdings of
low-denomination money act as a binding constraint (see Rolnick and
Weber [2003] for a good summary).
Such a definition provides an interesting prediction that can
potentially be confronted with the data. Basically, shortages of
low-denomination money (as defined by Sargent and Velde) coincide with
the persistent depreciation of low-denomination money relative to
high-denomination money. The economic intuition for this result is
simple. During shortages, low-denomination money is effectively more
useful in transactions than high-denomination money. However, both
monies are being voluntarily held by agents. For this situation to be an
equilibrium, the low-denomination money has to be losing value with
respect to the high-denomination money. In other words, while
low-denomination money is more useful in transactions, its value is
depreciating with time. The two effects offset each other in equilibrium
and leave agents indifferent (at the margin) between holding low- and
high-denomination money. (3)
Wallace (2003) strongly criticizes Sargent and Velde's
definition. Wallace points out that the historical "shortages are
reports by contemporaries concerning the difficulty of carrying out
trade in the face of a sudden disappearance of some kinds of
coins." However, in Sargent and Velde's model, agents are
"freely choosing quantities while taking prices as given," and
"nothing in the model looks like a shortage or a disruption of
trade."
Wallace goes on to discuss what is, in his view, at the heart of
the problem of small change. He starts by specifying the four desirable
properties of a medium of exchange: portability, divisibility,
durability, and recognizability; and he describes the history of coinage
as "mainly about the technological difficulties of achieving a
full-bodied coinage system that comes close to having those
attributes." Formal economic analyses that explicitly model all
four attributes of a medium of exchange and study the denomination
structure of money are not readily available. Wallace (2003) provides an
introduction to the formal treatment of these matters within the
framework provided by the random matching models of money pioneered by
Kiyotaki and Wright (1989). (4) He discusses how the indivisibility of
coins, for example, could limit the set of transactions that agents
undertake and how such limitations would clearly be perceived as
shortages of small change by the agents in the model. These are
interesting theoretical avenues that should eventually improve our
understanding of the historical records.
The objective of this article is not to answer the theoretical
questions that surround the issue of the appropriate provision of small
change. Those are difficult questions that involve theoretical concepts
that are not yet well understood in the literature and require much
further study. Here, instead, we will limit ourselves to reviewing the
historical evidence that indicates that the availability of small change
was a problem around the turn of the 18th century in the region that is
today Argentina. As noted above, similar evidence is available for other
parts of the world. However, in view of the intricate nature of the
problem involved, it seems important to collect and analyze as much
evidence as possible on this matter.
A Caveat
Before turning to the main subject of the article, a general
clarification is in order. When reading the historical records, one has
to be especially careful in differentiating the scarcity of means of
payment from the general scarcity of resources prevailing in the area.
The confusion between those two different phenomena was common at the
time (for example, official resolutions would sometimes associate the
general scarcity of resources with the inability to issue coins). (5)
The territory of Argentina was relatively poor at the end of the 18th
and the beginning of the 19th centuries and it relied on imports from
Europe for many essential needs. Furthermore, the recurrent military
conflicts at the beginning of the 1800s only contributed to further
reducing the availability of economic resources. But the general
stringency of resources is not the subject of this article. Instead, I
intend to report evidence that suggests that the relative scarcity of
certain means of payment, and in particular fractional money,
constituted a problem in itself.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows. In the next
section, I discuss the evidence from 1776 to the 1810 Revolution, that
is, the latter part of the colonial period. Classic manifestations of
the scarcity of small change appear in this period: attempts by the
government to ban the export of fractional money; extreme difficulties
in persuading the population to remint low-quality, low-denomination
coins; and the development of imperfect substitutes for use in payment
of small transactions are among the main ones being reviewed. In Section
2, I present evidence that suggests that the shortage of small change
continued to be a problem during the 15 years after the revolution. I
explain how the government struggled with the decision to issue copper
coins for 10 years, and how it finally injected the coins in 1823 with
great initial success. Also, in 1822 the first bank in the region was
created and allowed to issue notes of moderate denominations after some
initial reluctance. I discuss the genesis of that decision in some
detail. To conclude, in Section 3, I provide some further discussion of
the economic issues highlighted by the evidence discussed.
1. EVIDENCE FROM THE PERIOD OF THE VICEROYALTY OF THE RIO DE LA
PLATA
Spanish settlers were in the area that is today Argentina since the
mid-1500s. For the early colonial period, the available evidence
indicates that there was no widespread monetary exchange occurring in
the region and that instead barter was the predominant way of exchange
(Prebisch 1921, 193; Elia 1942a, 416). Since the beginning of
colonization, Spain implemented a system of international trade
restrictions in the colonies. The port of Buenos Aires could only trade
with Spain and such trade was subject to heavy taxation. These
restrictions significantly slowed down economic development for more
than two hundred years. Only in 1776, with the creation of the
Viceroyalty of the Rio de la Plata, the representative of the king,
Viceroy Ceballos, declared free trade in the port of Buenos Aires. (6)
As a result, a significant increase in the level of internal and
external trade took place in Buenos Aires and its area of influence.
During most of the early colonial period, Buenos Aires maintained a
trade deficit with Spain. This deficit resulted in a constant outflow of
gold and silver (in the form of coins, bars, and silverware). (7) Coins
came to Buenos Aires from the regions of Upper Peru (the area occupied
today by Bolivia and Peru). The Royal Villa of Potosi was the major
center of economic activity in Upper Peru, with its adjacent silver
mines and the regional mint house. Smuggling of European linen and
relatively inexpensive Brazilian products was common in the port of
Buenos Aires. Most of these products were sent to Upper Peru to be sold
in exchange for gold and silver coins. The proceeds, especially
high-quality coins, were then exported to Europe via Buenos Aires.
The constant outflow of coins from the port of Buenos Aires was
perceived as creating significant liquidity problems in the area of the
Rio de la Plata (Elia 1942a, 420-21). For example, as a result of
numerous local complaints, in October 1618 the King of Spain passed a
resolution allowing these colonies to use "products of the
land" (instead of gold and silver coins) to pay the "Indies
taxes" (Elia 1942a, 418). (8) Interestingly, there is very similar
evidence of perceived shortages of specie in colonial Canada at the end
of the 18th century. Redish (1984) argues that these common complaints
about a general scarcity of specie in Canada should really be
interpreted as reflecting the discomfort of merchants with what was
actually a scarcity of high-quality coins. Redish provides evidence
indicating that most of the coins in circulation in late 1700s Canada
were old coins whose weight had been reduced by intentional clipping or
sweating (and the normal wear and tear of very old coins), i.e.,
low-quality coins. The idea behind Redish's interpretation is that,
in accordance with modern versions of Gresham's Law, low-quality
coins tended to drive high-quality coins out of circulation. (9)
In principle, it seems that Redish's hypothesis could be
applicable for interpreting the complaints about general scarcity of
specie during the early colonial period of Argentina. However, more
research is needed in this area before reaching a more definite
conclusion. Here, though, the focus will be on trying to identify
situations where the shortage could be associated exclusively to
low-denomination media of exchange, and I will restrict my study to only
the latter part of the colonial period (that is, since the creation of
the Viceroyalty of the Rio de la Plata in 1776).
The Monetary System
The foundations of the monetary system in the Viceroyalty of the
Rio de la Plata resembled those of the system in place in Spain at the
time. Basically, there were in circulation gold and silver coins minted
in Spain, Mexico, and Peru. The two main mints in the Spanish colonies
of South America were located in Lima and Potosi. Most of the coins
circulating in the territories of the Rio de la Plata (today Argentina)
were silver coins minted in Potosi (Elia 1942a, 429).
The Potosi mint was under the direct control of the Spanish Crown,
which held a monopoly for issuing coins. Mining, on the other hand, was
a private enterprise. The Crown, though, provided miners with most of
the essential inputs and heavily taxed their production. One of the most
notorious institutions of the time was the mita, an annual recruitment
of forced Indian labor that was assigned to the different miners
according to a system of concessions. In 1779 the Spanish Crown created
the Banco de San Carlos that provided credit and other basic inputs to
miners in Potosi and monopolized the purchase of silver in the region
(Tandeter 1992, 198-99). The diezmo, a 10 percent tax, was charged on
all silver production.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The mint issued coins according to general orders from the Spanish
Crown. (10) The relative supply of different denominations of coins was
in principle determined by directives from Spain and decisions by the
mint's administrators (part of the Crown's bureaucracy). Under
this scheme the supply of fractional money, in principle, did not
automatically adjust to its demand, and imbalances became common. (11)
During the second half of the 18th century, a system of two-year
concessions was instituted for the administration of the mints on behalf
of the Crown. The concession contracts stipulated targets for the cost
of production and the proportion of fractional money to be minted
(Dargent Chamot 2005, Ch. 15).
There were two types of silver coins in circulation at the time of
the creation of the Viceroyalty: the coins called de cordoncillo and the
older, hammered coins (or cobs) called macuquina. The coin de
cordoncillo had the edges marked to prevent clipping and the macuquina
had variations in thickness, weight, and shape, making it a coin of
mediocre quality. The macuquina had been in circulation since the time
when hammering was the common minting practice (in Potosi, from 1575
until 1773). In principle, both coins de cordoncillo and macuquina of
all existing denominations were in circulation. However, a high
proportion of the stock of circulating low-denomination coins were
macuquina, as these were the coins that had been minted for a longer
period of time. (12)
The high-denomination, full-bodied silver coins were commonly
called plata doble and the low-denomination coins, plata sencilla
(Bonura 1992, 40; Tandeter 1992, 157). Most plata sencilla was of the
macuquina type and not full-bodied (due to intentional clipping and the
normal wear and tear resulting from their use and age). The plata doble,
on the other hand, were mostly high-quality, full-bodied silver coins
that were relatively scarce and especially useful for payments of
imported goods from Spain.
In terms of the denomination structure, the main denominations were
the peso, also called peso fuerte and the real with a nominal value of
one-eighth of the peso. There were also coins of half, two, and four
reals (Elia 1942a, 432). Cuartillos, coins of one-fourth of a real, were
only minted in Potosi after 1794 and in very small quantities (Dargent
Chamot 2005, Ch. 17).
Gold coins were very scarce in the area and of relatively high
purchasing power. The most common gold coin was the doubloon of eight,
which was equivalent to approximately 16 silver pesos and was mostly
used for international trade and hoarding. Overall, gold coins were not
used in small domestic transactions, and for this reason they play no
major role in the discussion that follows.
In 18th century Spain, small change was partly provided by the
issuing of vellon, a low-denomination coin made with a mixture of copper
and small quantities of silver. According to Bonura (1992, 39-40), the
vellon did not circulate in the region of the Rio de La Plata (see also,
Cortes Conde and McCandless 2001, 384). These token coins were not
commonly minted in Potosi, probably because of their high minting costs
and an alleged (yet, somewhat surprising) reluctance of the general
population to accept them in exchange. Interestingly, Romano (1998, 133)
reports extensively on a similar phenomenon taking place in colonial
Mexico (see also Hamilton 1944, 35). The reason for this phenomenon,
however, is not yet well understood. (13)
The Problem of Small Change
On several occasions between 1770 and 1810, the local elites
complained to the Crown about the shortage of small change. In 1773 the
king, partly as an attempt to deal with the scarcity of small change,
banned any export of fractional money from the colonies. Specifically,
the king prohibited the shipment of pieces of half, one, and two reals
to Spain and instructed the Viceroys to intensify their efforts to
ensure that the royal mints coin enough silver in those denominations
"for the vast commerce of America" (Hamilton 1944, 37). (14)
The macuquina was heavily used in domestic transactions, usually
circulating at par value. However, its poor quality complicated its
normal use and generated many complaints among the locals. (15) Its
irregular shape made the macuquina very susceptible to clipping,
creating uncertainty about its intrinsic value. Furthermore, by 1784 all
circulating macuquina was at least ten years old (hammered coins were
last produced in Potosi around 1773) and, hence, in very bad shape. At
that time, the king issued an order to collect and remint all the
macuquina in the colonies. After five years, in 1789 the order was
reissued, allowing for a fixed two-year period to complete the process.
In fact, after those two years, Viceroy Arredondo again postponed the
recovery period with no explicit time limit. This process suggests that
the officials in the colonies were reluctant to enforce the order to
remint the macuquina as they perceived that doing so would only
aggravate the shortage of small change. In fact, during the same period,
Viceroy Arredondo proposed the creation of a token coin to be used in
domestic trade. He explicitly pointed to the scarcity of small change as
a justification. The Spanish Crown denied the proposal and instead
ordered that all mint houses in the area start minting cuartillos (Elia
1942a, 425-26; Dargent Chamot 2005, Ch. 15).
The nature of the small change problem was twofold. First,
low-denomination coins (that is, coins of two reals or less) were minted
in significantly smaller proportions than the silver pesos; and second,
the purchasing power of the lowest-denomination coin was very high. (16)
In terms of the relative amounts of low-denomination coins that
were minted in Potosi, Tandeter (1992, 157) reports that, in the
mid-1700s, 85 percent of the minting was done in plata doble (i.e.,
coins of four reals and higher). By the same token, Romano (1998, 117)
explains that most of the coins minted in the Spanish colonies in
America during the 18th century were of high denomination, with the
eight-real (peso) pieces amounting to at least 95 percent of the annual
issues of silver coins both in Mexico and in Peru. (17) Dargent Chamot
(2005, Ch. 15) reports the reluctance of the Superintendent of the mint
of Potosi in 1784 to issue large quantities of cuartillos, considering
them too costly to produce. In general, cuartillos were issued in very
limited amounts, and only later in the period (in Potosi, starting only
in 1794). (18)
One way to get an idea of the high purchasing power of the
denomination structure that was predominant in the region is to compare
the value of silver coins with the level of nominal wages for unskilled
rural workers. For example, at the time, a slave in the rural areas near
Buenos Aires would normally receive an allowance of one real per week to
buy "soap and tobacco." A free rural seasonal worker (a peon)
had an average wage of around four pesos per month (although monthly
wages fluctuated significantly across workers, from two to seven pesos;
see Amaral 1987, 267-72). This monthly wage implied a daily wage of
around one-and-a-half reals that amounted to three coins of half real,
which was effectively the smallest denomination coin. A similar
situation took place in the early stages of other monetary systems. For
example, Hanson (1979, 283) reports that, of the common coins in
circulation in Pennsylvania and Massachusetts (both British colonies) in
1742, the lowest-denomination coin represented about three days'
wages for an unskilled laborer at the time.
Some Consequences
The lack of small-denomination coins resulted in the use of
unofficial means of payment in everyday transactions (Bonura 1992, 40).
One of these instruments, the contrasenas, became very popular.
Contrasenas were small metal (tin) discs with the initials of the issuer
printed on them (Elia 1942a, 428; Prebisch 1921, 199). In everyday
transactions requiring small change that the parties (buyer and seller)
lack, the buyer could make payments in two possible ways. One way was to
pay using contrasenas previously issued by the particular merchant
participating in the transaction, in which case the transaction would
terminate with the payment. The other way was for the buyer to pay in
high-denomination silver coins. In this case, when necessary, the change
resulting from the transaction would be provided in contrasenas issued
by the seller. Sometimes, even the contrasenas issued by a third party
were used as change. In general, the third party was a well-known
merchant in the area and the individuals engaged in the transaction were
holding his contrasenas as a result of previous transactions. (19)
The use of contrasenas did not, of course, solve all the problems.
In fact, their extensive use resulted in widespread fraud and
falsification. Later on, contrasenas were gradually substituted with
private IOUs issued directly on paper. (20) These IOUs were
inconvertible and also circulated widely in the region (Prebisch 1921,
199). They are a precursor of the inconvertible paper money that was
introduced in the region more than a decade after the 1810 Revolution.
(21)
Another way people circumvented the lack of small change was by
developing even simpler credit arrangements. Customers would build up a
debit at the community store until it was possible to settle the payment
using higher-denomination coins that were more readily available (Schmit
2003, 265). Obviously, the use of this kind of informal credit was
limited to cases where the owner of the store was relatively certain
that the customer had reasons to secure a permanent relationship with
the store.
The Premium
There is some evidence that in the City of Buenos Aires during
colonial times, the hard peso sometimes circulated at a premium over
fiduciary silver coins, i.e., the low-denomination, usually not
full-bodied plata sencilla (Prebisch 1921, 195; Bonura 1992, 40-41).
(22) Interestingly, the premium was lower (and even zero) in the
periphery (the interior), creating a flow of plata sencilla from Buenos
Aires to those regions. (23) In 1790 the authorities in Buenos Aires
asked the Crown to introduce legal restrictions to abolish "the 3
percent premium of the hard peso." In 1798, after the Crown did not
respond, the request was reiterated. The main justification for the
request was the constant flow of fractional coins out of Buenos Aires to
the interior. The official document stated that this flow had
"reduced the quantity of small-denomination coins,... creating
difficulties in the change or reduction of the plata doble to the
sencilla ... the specie so necessary for making small daily purchases,
which are very indispensable transactions" (see Bonura 1992, 41).
(24)
With respect to the evolution of the premium over time, it appears
that the premium was fairly constant. Bonura (1992, 49), for example,
reports that the premium was still around 3 percent in 1812, when the
authorities in Buenos Aires engaged in another legal attempt to reduce
it. Sargent and Velde (2002) associate periods of shortages of small
change with periods of depreciation in the value of fractional money.
The evidence from Argentina is too sparse to test this hypothesis (but,
in principle, no clear trend in the premium was observed in the region).
2. EVIDENCE FROM EARLY ARGENTINA
In 1810, the Cabildo (the town council) of Buenos Aires declared
autonomy from the Spanish Crown. With the end of the Viceroyalty of the
Rio de la Plata, Buenos Aires lost Upper Peru from its area of
influence; and with Upper Peru, the mint of Potosi and the silver mines.
(25)
This transitional period was associated with general monetary
disarray in the region. The confrontation with Upper Peru (which had
remained loyal to the Crown) and the necessary financing of military
expenses (including significant imports that needed to be paid in
specie) created a sharp contraction in the amount of available means of
payment in Buenos Aires (Prebisch 1921, 198). During this period, many
government officials proposed a compulsory remint of all the old coins
in circulation. Furthermore, some of these proposals included the
imposition of a steep proportional tax upon reminting. In view of these
proposals, it seems that hiding and hoarding coins was a natural
reaction of the population.
The new government made several attempts at issuing new coins
during this period. In 1813, after temporarily recovering the city of
Potosi, the first Argentinean coin was minted. A year later, however,
the Independence Army lost Potosi to royal forces and the minting
stopped. (26) Some minting of silver pesos took place in the province of
Cordoba during 1815, but in very limited amounts (Elia 1942a, 433). At
that time, illegal private minting of cobs and other (very low quality)
silver counterfeits was common in the northwest region of the country
(Bonura 1992, 73). In 1817 Governor Guemes officially authorized the
circulation of "illegal" coins (after being officially
stamped) in the territory under his jurisdiction in the northwest part
of the country. He gave as a justification for this resolution the
"evils associated with the lack of means of payment" (Elia
1942a, 435). A year later, the federal authority banned the circulation
of these "Guemes" coins, establishing a severe punishment for
those who accepted and/or held them. Overall, no real progress was made
in providing the economy with appropriate means of payment during the
first decade after the revolution (Bonura 1992, 81).
Besides the general monetary disorder, some specific episodes
suggest the existence of shortages of fractional money. In this respect,
two situations appear most relevant: the provision of copper coins
approved in 1821 after several years of discussions and the
authorization granted to the Bank of Buenos Aires to issue paper notes
of relatively low denomination in 1823. (27)
Copper Coins
In June 1815 the newly created government in Buenos Aires started
evaluating the introduction of "provisional money" in the form
of copper coins (Bonura 1992, 61). For this purpose, the government
commissioned an extraordinary consulting body of experts to study the
issue. The authority's motivation for the introduction of these
coins was twofold. The first was that shortages of small change were a
recurrent problem that needed to be fixed. In August 1815 the body of
experts presented a detailed report in which they unanimously agreed
that introducing copper coins was essential for eliminating the
inconveniences resulting from the persistent lack of small change
(Bonura 1992, 65).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The second motivation was the possibility of obtaining extra
resources for a government that was in desperate need of financing. (28)
This issue was the subject of important disagreement among experts. They
discussed the estimated costs of minting copper coins extensively, but
they did not reach an agreement, so the implementation was postponed
(Bonura 1992, 65). Sporadically, during the next five years, the
government authorities in Buenos Aires revisited the possibility of
issuing copper coins but never managed to implement the idea. (29)
Finally, in October 1821, a law was passed allowing the government
to arrange the minting of 100,000 pesos in copper coins of one-tenth of
a real (Elia 1942a, 437). These coins, the first Argentinean copper
coins, were minted in Birmingham, England (at Boulton's mint).
Fifty thousand pesos of those coins were received and put into
circulation in July 1823. (30) Elia (1942a, 437) reports that the public
immediately absorbed that first lot of coins and the government then
requested that the Birmingham mint deliver the rest of the coins as soon
as possible. Both the small denomination of these copper coins and their
generalized acceptance by the public seem indicative of the high level
of unsatisfied demand for fractional money that existed during that
period. (31)
Paper Money
In June 1822 the government in Buenos Aires gave a group of local
businessmen an exclusive 20-year concession to create the first (and
only) bank in the region. The Bank of Buenos Aires (also called Banco de
Descuentos) was supposed to be fully funded with private capital. Part
of the government's justification for allowing the creation of the
Bank was the need to provide appropriate means of payment to the
community (Irigoin 2003, 65). (32) Trade liberalization after the
revolution resulted in a substantial increase in commercial activity, in
turn creating the urgent need for more developed monetary and financial
institutions in the region.
However, this was not the only motivation for the creation of the
Bank. In fact, there is some evidence indicating that the primary reason
was to allow the government to access cheaper financing. By 1822 the
government was heavily involved in a civil war and was quickly running
out of resources (Prebisch 1921, 201). The plan was that the government
would take loans from the bank at preferential rates.
Some of the factors that triggered the creation of the Bank of
Buenos Aires seem indicative of the persistent shortage of
low-denomination money. First, from discussions at the time it is clear
that private IOUs (vales) and contrasenas were still in circulation when
the Bank was created in 1822 (Elia 1942b, 323; Prebisch 1921, 199;
Irigoin 2003, 65). The use of vales and contrasenas can be taken as
evidence of the need for fractional money. To the extent that parties in
a transaction were willing to accept these very imperfect means of
payment, which were clearly associated with significant risk of fraud
and counterfeiting, it must be the case that no better payment methods
were available (Prebisch 1921, 199).
Second, while initially the Bank of Buenos Aires was only allowed
to issue notes in denominations no lower than 20 hard pesos, in mid-1823
the government agreed to authorize the Bank to start issuing
lower-denomination bills. These bills came to replace some Treasury
notes of similar denomination that the Ministry of Finance had
introduced only months before. The Bank issued bills of one, three, and
five hard pesos, convertible to gold and silver coins upon presentation
at the Bank's window (Elia 1942b, 326). While these denominations
were not, by any means, the lowest of the prevailing structure, they
were commonly used in domestic transactions. Also, they were probably
considered the natural intermediate step in the move toward lower
denominations.
During the first two years of its existence, the Bank issued
convertible money notes well in excess of its reserves of gold and
silver that resulted in a confidence crisis in 1825. Early in 1826, the
Bank was taken over by the government and its money notes were declared
inconvertible. The notes stayed in circulation but only based upon
government fiat. The perceived insufficiency of means of payment
prevailing in the region was then replaced by excessive printing of
inconvertible paper money. A regime of high inflation followed, which
lasted for many decades. (33)
3. FINAL REMARKS
In this article I reviewed evidence that suggests that shortages of
small change were a problem in the economy of the Rio de la Plata area
during the colonial period and the first two decades after independence.
Evidence of this sort is already available for several other regions
around the world. It is interesting to verify that a similar monetary
phenomenon took place in Argentina during the early stages of its
political and economic development.
Several features made the evidence presented here especially
interesting. First, while most of the European evidence comes from
economies where free minting was in place, in Argentina during the late
colonial period the supply of coins was under the direct control of the
Spanish Crown. Minting policies, then, were not uniquely directed to
improve the smooth functioning of the monetary economy in the colonies.
Spain was the main provider of high-quality silver coins to the rest of
Europe during that time. For this reason, a major motivation for the
Crown's policies was to maintain an international reputation of
high quality for Spanish coins. These competing objectives probably
increased the chances of misalignments between demand and supply of
denominations.
Second, the evidence clearly illustrates the interaction between
money and credit during the early stages of monetary development. To
bypass the problem of small change, agents in the economy developed
rudimentary credit arrangements that allowed them to trade with one
another. Two schemes were prevalent. In one scheme, the buyer would
extend credit to the seller through the use of contrasenas; in the
other, the seller would grant credit to the buyers by allowing them to
accumulate a debit in a temporary account. It is a general principle in
monetary economics that money and credit act as close substitutes. In
general, however, the emphasis has been on explaining how monetary
exchange increases the trading possibilities in an economy where credit
is not always feasible (as in Kiyotaki and Wright 1993). The evidence
presented here highlights the reciprocal fact that when the convenience
of monetary exchange is undermined by, in this case, the lack of small
change, agents turn to imperfect credit arrangements to carry out their
economic transactions. (See Jin and Temzelides [2004] and Cuadras-Morato
[2005] for a formal discussion of some of these issues.)
Finally, it was interesting to see the newly created government
confronting all the basic economic issues involved in the provision of
small change when deciding to introduce copper coins. On one hand,
effective fractional coins needed to be of relatively high quality to
avoid counterfeiting. On the other hand, high-quality, low-denomination
coins were very costly to produce. The government realized that only a
large scale of production could lower the unitary cost of production to
an acceptable level. The lack of sufficient mineral input delayed
production of copper coins for several years. In the end, the government
resorted to importing the coins from England, an international producer
of coins for which scale of production was obviously not an issue.
REFERENCES
Amaral, Samuel. 1987. "Rural Production and Labour in Late
Colonial Buenos Aires." Journal of Latin American Studies 19 (2):
235-78.
Bonura, Elena. 1992. "Aproximaciones al Estudio del Problema
Monetario de las Provincias del Rio de la Plata, 1810-1820."
Historiografia Rioplatense 4: 39-84.
Bordo, Michael D., and Carlos A. Vegh. 2002. "What If
Alexander Hamilton Had Been Argentinean? A Comparison of the Early
Monetary Experiences of Argentina and the United States." Journal
of Monetary Economics 49: 459-94.
Butlin, Sydney James. 1953. Foundations of the Australian Monetary
System 1788-1851. Melbourne University Press: Victoria.
Cortes Conde, Roberto, and George McCandless. 2001.
"Argentina: From Colony to Nation: Fiscal and Monetary Experience
of the Eighteen and Nineteenth Centuries." In Transferring Wealth
and Power from the Old to the New World, ed. Michael D. Bordo and R.
Cortes Conde. Cambridge University Press: 378-413.
Cuadras-Morato, Xavier. 2005. "Circulation of Private Notes
During a Currency Shortage." Mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.
Dargent Chamot, Eduardo. 2005. Las Casas de Moneda Espanolas en
America del Sur. Available at http://www.tesorillo.com (accessed on
March 30, 2006).
Elia, Oscar Horacio. 1942a. "Evolucion de la Moneda en la
Republica Argentina: Desde sus Origenes hasta 1822." Revista de
Ciencias Economicas (April): 415-37.
______. 1942b. "Nuestro Primer Banco." Revista de
Ciencias Economicas (May): 323-30.
Halperin Donghi, Tulio. 1972. Revolucion y Guerra: Formacion de una
Elite Dirigente en la Argentina Criolla. Siglo Veintiuno Editores:
Buenos Aires.
Hamilton, Earl J. 1944. "Monetary Problems in Spain and
Spanish America. 1751-1800." Journal of Economic History 4 (1):
21-48.
Hanson, John R. II. 1979. "Money in the Colonial American
Economy: An Extension." Economic Inquiry 17 (April): 281-86.
Irigoin, Maria Alejandra. 2000. "Inconvertible Paper Money,
Inflation, and Economic Performance in Early Nineteenth Century
Argentina." Journal of Latin American Studies 32: 333-59.
______. 2003. "La Fabricacion de Moneda en Buenos Aires y
Potosi y la Transformacion de la Economia Colonial en el Rio de la Plata
(1820 y 1860)." In La Desintegracion de la Economia Colonial, ed.
Maria A. Irigoin and Roberto Schmit. Editorial Biblos, Buenos Aires:
57-91.
Jin, Yi, and Ted Temzelides. 2004. "On the Local Interaction
of Money and Credit." Review of Economic Dynamics 7: 143-56.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Randall Wright. 1989. "On Money as a
Medium of Exchange." Journal of Political Economy 97 (June):
927-54.
______. 1993. "A Search-Theoretic Approach to Monetary
Economics." American Economic Review 83 (March): 63-77.
Lee, Manjong, Neil Wallace, and Tao Zhu. 2005. "Modeling
Denomination Structures." Econometrica 73 (May): 949-60.
Prebisch, Raul. 1921. "Anotaciones Sobre Nuestro Medio
Circulante." Revista de Ciencias Economicas (October): 190-205.
Redish, Angela. 1984. "Why Was Specie Scarce in Colonial
Economies? An Analysis of the Canadian Currency, 1796-1830."
Journal of Economic History 44 (3): 713-28.
Rolnick, Arthur J., and Warren E. Weber. 2003. Book Review. Journal
of Political Economy 111 (2): 459-63.
Romano, Ruggiero. 1998. Moneda, Seudomonedas y Circulacion
Monetaria en las Economias de Mexico. Fondo de Cultura Economica:
Mexico.
Sargent, Thomas J., and Francois Velde. 1999. "The Big Problem
of Small Change." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31 (May):
137-61.
______. 2002. The Big Problem of Small Change. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Schmit, Roberto. 2003. "Enlaces Conflictivos: Comercio,
Fiscalidad y Medios de Pago en Entre Rios durante la Primera Mitad del
Siglo XIX." In La Desintegracion de la Economia Colonial, ed. Maria
A. Irigoin and Roberto Schmit. Editorial Biblos: Buenos Aires: 251-76.
Supple, Barry E. 1957. "Currency and Commerce in the Early
Seventeenth Century." Economic History Review, New Series 10 (2):
239-55.
Tandeter, Enrique. 1992. Coaccion y Mercado. Sudamericana: Buenos
Aires.
Wallace, Neil. 2003. "Modeling Small Change: A Review
Article." Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (6): 1391-1401.
______, and Ruilin Zhou. 1997. "A Model of a Currency
Shortage." Journal of Monetary Economics 40 (3): 555-72.
The author is a Senior Economist in the Research Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. E-mail: Huberto.Ennis@rich.frb.org. I
would like to thank Elena Bonura, Martin Gervais, Andreas Hornstein, Bob
Hetzel, Todd Keister, Robert King, Diego Restuccia, Andrea Waddle, and
Steve Williamson for helpful comments. All translated quotations are my
own. All errors are also my own. Part of this work was done while I was
visiting the Central Bank of Argentina, whose hospitality is gratefully
acknowledged. The views expressed here do not necessarily represent
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
(1) Some high-inflation economies sometimes experience imbalances
in their denomination structure, resulting in relative scarcity of small
change. The monetary authority becomes reluctant to provide large
quantities of low-denomination means of payment, which are relatively
costly to produce and, due to high inflation, have a short useful
lifespan.
(2) A full-bodied coin is one that has metallic content worth as
much as the coin's face value. Token coins are subsidiary coins
that have lower intrinsic value than the value at which they can be
exchanged with the monetary authority for full-bodied coins.
(3) Sargent and Velde (2002) do, in fact, find some supporting
evidence for this hypothesis in their review of the historical record of
many European countries. Unfortunately, as we will later see, such an
evaluation is not possible with the data available for the colonial
period in South America.
(4) See also Wallace and Zhou (1997) and Lee, Wallace, and Zhu
(2005).
(5) Supple (1957, 244-45) reports that this kind of confusion was
also common in 17th century England.
(6) Before 1776, the colonies of the Rio de la Plata were under the
control of the representative of the king residing in the Peruvian area.
(7) Halperin Donghi (1972, 48) reports that exports of gold and
silver from Buenos Aires amounted to about 80 percent of total exports
in 1796.
(8) Also, in 1622, in an attempt to stop the outflow of precious
metals from Upper Peru, the Spanish Crown created the customs of
Cordoba, an inland post that was supposed to control all trade between
the port of Buenos Aires and the highland regions in the northwest
(Upper Peru). The effectiveness of this measure was undermined by
rampant smuggling.
(9) Sargent and Velde (2002, 125) discuss the "bullion famine" of medieval Europe in the context of their model and also
conclude that talking about general shortages of coins is difficult to
rationalize. Instead, they maintain that the monetary anomalies involved
were the consequences of shortages of small change.
(10) Romano (1998, 133) reports that the original 16th century
royal ordinances creating the mints in Mexico and Peru, including the
one in Potosi, stated explicitly the rules for the proportions of the
different denomination of coins to be minted. In particular, only a
fourth of the coins were supposed to be of low denomination. These
original orders, though, were not always strictly followed and changed
over time.
(11) In an alternative scheme called "free minting,"
private agents holding silver or gold are able to go to the mint and
exchange their metal for coins of the denomination of their choice. This
scheme was predominant in Europe (see Sargent and Velde 2002, 20).
(12) Low-denomination coins were minted in relatively low
proportions and, hence, most of the stock in circulation was fairly old.
High-denomination coins were minted more intensively and were exported
in large proportions, resulting in a stock with a lower average age.
(13) Vellon was issued in colonial Mexico in 1542 and the general
population refused to accept it. The experiment was a complete failure.
Hamilton (1944, 36) argues that the vellon was so grossly overvalued that the population preferred to continue using cocoa beans as a mean of
payment. Romano (1998, 134-35), instead, suggests that the local elites
actually opposed the issuing of vellon based on political motivations.
The reason vellon was not issued in the Spanish colonies in America is
an unanswered question in the literature.
(14) Butlin (1953, 81-82) reports that the government in Australia
(a British colony) used similar legal instruments to avoid the export of
coins in 1813. Sargent and Velde (2002) report legal restrictions on the
export of coins in medieval England (p. 132) and in Venice on May 1268
(p. 163). See Wallace and Zhou (1997) for a rationalization of this type
of official restriction.
(15) See Hamilton (1944, 25-26) for an account of similar problems
in the area of colonial Mexico.
(16) Bonura (1992, 39) recognizes the relatively high purchasing
power of the cuartillo and finds it puzzling that no lower-denomination
coins were issued before 1794.
(17) The proportion of low-denomination coins in circulation was
probably higher since high-denomination coins were more intensively
exported.
(18) Starting in 1793, cuartillos were also minted in colonial
Mexico. According to Hamilton (1944, 38), the cuartillos were "too
small for convenient use and struck in inadequate quantities" and,
hence, "did not end the disorder in the fractional coinage."
(19) In colonial Mexico, it was popular to use for payments small
wooden disks with the name of the issuer (a merchant) printed on them.
These disks were called tlacos and they emerged in response to the
recurrent shortages of small change that took place in the Mexican
territory during the 18th century (Romano 1998, 137; Hamilton 1944,
36-38). Tin-made tokens with similar characteristics as the contrasenas
circulated in England in 1576 (Sargent and Velde 2002, 266).
(20) Butlin (1953, 26-27) describes privately issued promissory notes that circulated in Australia during the colonial period and the
rampant forgery that originated around them.
(21) Hanson (1979, 285) convincingly argues that the origin of
paper currency in the colonies of North America was the result of the
persistent shortages of low-denomination coins. He provides evidence of
the issuance of private circulating notes by merchants early in the
process. Sargent and Velde (2002, 203) discuss evidence from 1577 France
that documents the widespread use of private IOUs in response to the
shortages of small change.
(22) Tandeter (1992, 157) reports that the plata doble had a
premium over the plata sencilla in the Villa of Potosi in the mid-1700s.
He attributes the premium to the fact that the plata doble was the one
preferred in long-distance trade.
(23) This kind of geographic dispersion in the exchange rate of
coins was also observed across the French territory during the 1570s, a
period of monetary "chaos" (Sargent and Velde 2002, 200).
(24) In principle, one would expect shortages of small change to be
associated with, if anything, a premium on low-denomination coins. This
is the opposite of what is reported here. It seems likely, however, that
the premium was not uniform across transactions, and that the 3 percent
premium on hard pesos was predominant only in large-value transactions
and international trade.
(25) For a good overview of the economic factors that led to the
breakup of the Viceroyalty into different countries, see Cortes Conde
and McCandless (2001).
(26) Minting of Argentinean coins in Potosi resumed for a short
period in 1815.
(27) Experiences in other countries influenced these two decisions.
For example, the general perception in Buenos Aires was that copper
coins were being used with great success in Portugal (Bonura 1992, 77).
With respect to banking, reports of the benefits associated with the
operation of the Bank of England were one of the main motivations for
the creation of the Bank of Buenos Aires (Prebisch 1921, 199-200).
(28) Token coins are usually circulated at a value greater than
their intrinsic value. For this reason, they have the potential to
become a source of revenue for the monetary authority. During 1817, the
government was evaluating the possibility of opening a mint in the city
of Cordoba. After concluding that the project would not be profitable
for the government, the idea was abandoned. The evidence seems to
indicate that there was a problem of insufficient scale of production.
Apparently, the set-up costs of operating a mint were very high, and the
quantity of metal available from the mines of Famatina, the planned
source of basic input, was not enough to make the enterprise profitable
(Bonura 1992, 72).
(29) The issue of minting copper coins was again extensively
discussed in 1818 when the new government was evaluating the possibility
of establishing an official mint in Buenos Aires (Bonura 1992, 75).
(30) To put some perspective on these numbers, note, for example,
that in 1923 total tax revenue for the province of Buenos Aires was
around two million pesos (see Bordo and Vegh 2002, Table 1). In other
words, the gross revenue from the introduction of this first batch of
copper coins in 1823 was about 2.5 percent of total annual tax revenue.
(31) The circulation of token coins was never automatic in the
early stages of monetary development. It often happened that the
population, accustomed to full-bodied coinage, distrusted the validity
of token copper coins as an acceptable means of payment. See Butlin
(1953, 37) for the case of Australia and Sargent and Velde (2002, 210)
for the case of France in the 1590s (see also footnote 13 in this
paper). Of course, counterfeiting was always a potential problem in the
case of circulating token coins (see, for example, Sargent and Velde
2002, 217-18). The fact that these first copper coins were minted in
England using frontier technology at the time probably reduced the risk
of counterfeiting making the coins more likely to circulate.
(32) Redish (1984) reports that a similar justification was used at
the time of the creation of the first Canadian banks at the beginning of
the 19th century.
(33) After 1825 the authorities in both Bolivia and Buenos Aires
started a period of sustained monetary expansion and inflation (Irigoin
2003, 60). In Bolivia, the minting and systematic debasement of silver
coins (moneda feble) was the main fiscal instrument of the new
government. These coins circulated also in the northwest regions of
Argentina. In Buenos Aires, the government printed large amounts of
inconvertible paper money to finance increasing fiscal deficits. The
paper peso depreciated around 200 percent during 1826 and continued
depreciating in the following years. For a detailed discussion of the
monetary history of Argentina during this period, see Irigoin (2003),
Bordo and Vegh (2002), and Irigoin (2000). In general, the paper money
from Buenos Aires did not circulate in the provinces. In the interior of
the country, several provincial governments attempted to issue their own
paper money but faced substantial problems in inducing its circulation,
as the general population deeply mistrusted the viability of fiat money.
In 1826 the province of Corrientes issued 3,000 hard pesos in
low-denomination notes, but acceptance was limited and the experiment
became a complete failure (Irigoin 2003, 67). Sometimes the government
introduced extreme legislation to try to encourage the circulation of
the money notes. For example, in 1840 the provincial authority in
Tucuman instituted the death penalty for those not accepting in exchange
the paper money printed by the Northern League, a coalition of
northwestern provinces (Halperin Donghi 1979, 91).
Table 1 Silver Coins--Main Denominations
Cuartillo 1/4 real
Medio Real 1/2 real
Real
Real de a Dos 2 reals
Medio Peso 4 reals
Peso 8 reals