Borrowing by U.S. households.
Weinberg, John A.
Wherever one turns these days, one seems to run into comments about
the financial condition of the American household. Most of these
comments refer to sources of increasing stress on the American consumer,
from the historically low household savings rate to the historically
high rates of bankruptcy and debt delinquency. On top of all this,
demographic trends are raising the prospect of having to finance the
coming retirement of the baby boom generation. These conditions have led
some to question the ability of consumer spending to hold up under such
growing financial stress. Credit markets and consumers' use of
credit products take a central place in this picture. Stories in the
popular business press have taken the view that consumer debt will
represent a drag on consumption growth in 2006, as the burden of making
payments on debt limits households' abilities to make other
purchases. (1)
Debt and credit are value-laden terms that evoke distinct images in
people's minds. Indeed, cultural historian Lendol Calder has noted
the seemingly contradictory value judgments that run through American
cultural attitudes about borrowing. (2) "Credit" is seen as a
good thing, in that it allows the household financial flexibility in
meeting its consumption needs. On the other hand, "debt" is
typically viewed as bad, because it represents a lack of self-discipline
and holds the household hostage to its past choices. And so we have what
appears to be a paradox. The ability to borrow is both liberating and
constraining--a path to both rising wealth and the poorhouse.
Another way to view this seeming paradox is to think of
"credit" and "debt" from two different vantage
points. "Credit" typically refers to the moment when a
borrower has access to funds made available by a lender. From this
vantage point, it is a tool to help households achieve their desired
levels of consumption. "Debt," on the other hand, is an
after-the-fact concept, referring to the amount owed. We see this
dichotomy in contemporary discussions of credit markets. The expansion
of access to credit for households previously thought to be sharply
constrained in their ability to borrow is a stated goal of public
policy. On the other hand, the financial stress facing some heavily
indebted households is seen by many as a problem requiring a public
policy solution.
This essay explores the use of credit by U.S. households. The first
section describes some facts concerning consumer borrowing and its
growth in recent decades. The following sections present some of the
economics of household borrowing, beginning with an explanation of the
role of borrowing in helping a household to meet its consumption goals
over time, and then using that perspective to interpret the facts. This
perspective generally does not support the view that consumer debt
causes future weakness in consumption growth at the macroeconomic level.
This essay's initial focus is on averages and aggregates,
examining trends in total borrowing by U.S. households and assessing
those trends from the point of view of the typical or average household.
While this perspective is appropriate for thinking about broad trends in
credit markets, it can mask the fact that market changes can have
different impacts on different people. Indeed, these differences are
often important to the way people think about public policy toward
credit markets. A look at more disaggregated data, in fact, reveals that
much of the expansion of credit that has occurred in recent decades has
come in the lower brackets of the income distribution. Accordingly, the
essay will address the question of whether the economics of borrowing by
lower-income individuals is significantly different from the general
economics of credit.
1. TRENDS IN CONSUMER CREDIT
How indebted are U.S. consumers? In 2004, the ratio of all consumer
debt to disposable personal income was about 108 percent. The bulk of
this debt, 84 percent of income, was in the form of mortgage debt, with
the remaining 24 percent in revolving and nonrevolving consumer credit.
Historically, the debt-to-income ratio has shown steady growth over much
of the last half-century as is shown in Figure 1. Total debt to income
stood at about 35 percent in 1952 and rose to around 50 percent by 1960.
It then fluctuated between 55 and 60 percent for much of the 1960s and
1970s, before beginning a sustained increase in the mid-1980s. But by
far the largest share of this growth has been in the mortgage portion of
household credit, which was 23 percent of income in 1952. By contrast,
nonmortgage consumer credit roughly doubled in this 50-year period,
going from 12 to 24 percent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As is apparent, a very large part of the increase in household debt
since the 1950s has been the rise of mortgage debt. To some extent, this
rise in mortgage debt does not represent the typical homeowner borrowing
more against the house that he or she owns. Rather, part of this
increase is due to a steadily rising rate of homeownership, which went
from 55 percent of U.S. households in 1950 to 69 percent in 2005.
Another source of this increase is growth in the value of housing assets
owned by consumers. Especially in the 1990s, the median value of
privately owned homes grew faster than median income. Still, households
have generally increased the share of their homeownership financed by
mortgage debt.
Growth in the use of credit has been widespread among U.S.
households. While borrowing by households in all income ranges has
grown, this growth has been the most pronounced among households with
medium and low levels of income. Also, while disparities in borrowing
behavior continue to exist between minority and nonminority households,
those disparities have tended to decline. This type of disaggregated
information comes primarily from the Federal Reserve Board's Survey
of Consumer Finances (SCF), which is conducted every three years. An
analysis of trends for households in different ethnic and income groups
was conducted by Raphael Bostic. (3) Trends for people at different
income levels are discussed later in this essay.
Does rising debt to income mean that the typical household's
debt burden has risen? The debt burden of a household is usually
measured by the payments on its debts relative to its income. Given the
wide variety of terms on retail credit--from fixed term, fixed interest
rate mortgages to open-ended lines of credit with variable
rates--specification of the "payments" used to determine the
burden of servicing one's debts is not straightforward. But the two
main determinants of a household's repayment obligation are the
amount of debt and the interest rates charged. So, while a precise
measurement of the payment burden would require detailed data on loan
characteristics at a very disaggregated level, it is possible to
construct a rough estimate from aggregate data. Dean Maki provides one
such estimated time series of the aggregate debt burden of U.S.
households. (4) For the time period covered in that series, from 1980 to
2000, the payment burden fluctuates around an average level of about 13
percent. The debt-service burden tends to rise during expansions and
fall during recessions. This pattern reflects two other facts. First,
interest rates tend to rise in expansions and fall in recessions. But,
perhaps more importantly, the growth rate of consumer credit is also
procyclical, with credit growing more rapidly in expansions, on average.
The burden households face in servicing their debts, together with
the pattern of growth in those debts, focuses attention on the
"credit is good, but debt is bad" dichotomy. Does the data on
household debt suggest more that "credit" acts a tool for
managing consumption growth or that the burden of "debt"
constrains consumption growth, as is suggested in the popular media.
Making this distinction empirically is difficult, since both these
forces may be at work for any given household and the mix may vary
considerably across households. Maki finds that his debt burden measure
does not have strong predictive power for consumption growth, suggesting
that, on average, debt is not a strong constraining force. In addition,
growth in consumer credit tends to be positively correlated with future
consumption growth. This relationship suggests that credit is an
important tool for households in making their consumption choices. How
household make those choices is the subject of the next section.
2. HOW HOUSEHOLDS USE FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS
It is important to view use of credit in the broader context of how
a household chooses to consume and save or borrow over its lifetime. A
household's financial decisions are driven by the fact that its
income varies over time. Broadly speaking, there are two types of
variation in income. First, there is a typical, largely predictable,
pattern by which an individual's income first rises, say from young
adulthood into middle age, then falls as the person or household moves
into retirement. But there are also variations in income that are less
predictable. Households face an array of shocks that affect their
ability to participate and earn income in the labor market. Some of
these shocks have only temporary effects, like an illness that keeps a
worker out of the workforce but from which the worker fully recovers.
Others can be more long lasting, like a permanent decline in demand
facing an industry in which a worker has accumulated a great deal of
experience and skill.
Against these variations in income, a household uses financial
services related to saving and borrowing to achieve the best lifetime
pattern of consumption possible. What makes one pattern of consumption
better than another? Well, for one thing, more is better than less, so a
pattern that gives a household more consumption of goods and services at
every point in time is clearly better than one that gives less. But most
comparisons of consumption patterns over one's lifetime are not so
straightforward. In particular, saving and borrowing decisions have to
do with trading off consumption today for consumption in the future. So
the important point to bear in mind is that household financial
decisions are driven not so much by how people feel about having a
bigger savings account or being more in debt as they are by how people
feel about having more consumption today versus more consumption in the
future.
One principle for thinking about people's preferences for
consumption over time and how those preferences affect financial
decisions is that people typically have a preference for smooth
consumption--consumption that doesn't vary too much over time. In
other words, a household that gets a one-time windfall, like from
winning a lottery, for example, will probably not want to spend it all
immediately on consumption of goods and services. Rather, the lucky
household will want to save some of its temporarily higher income so
that it can spread the consumption benefits over a longer period of
time. An important distinction here is between spending on durable
versus nondurable goods. A lottery winner may in fact pour a large bulk
of his or her winnings into the purchase of durable goods. But such
expenditures bear a similarity to savings, because durable goods provide
benefits to their owner over an extended period of time, and the key
thing about consumption smoothing is that the individual will want to
use a temporary rise in income to generate consumption benefits that
last over a long time period. This logic works on the other side as
well, when a household faces a temporary income shortfall but expects to
have higher income in the future. Such a household will want to keep its
consumption up by drawing down savings or borrowing against those future
increases in income.
The desire for smooth consumption over time can be explained by
economists' usual assumption of diminishing marginal utility. This
simply means that the less someone has consumed of a good or of goods
and services in general, the more eager he or she is to increase
consumption. So, if a household has a low income today but expects a
higher income in the future, it faces the prospect of having less
consumption today than in the future. According to diminishing marginal
utility, the household would be eager to give up some of its consumption
in the relatively abundant future for a little more in the present.
The same characteristic of people's preferences for
consumption that makes them prefer smooth consumption over time also
makes them dislike facing risk to their consumption opportunities. That
is, diminishing marginal utility of consumption implies that people are
risk averse and will be willing to take costly actions or purchase
costly insurance to avoid risk.
So the usual assumptions about consumer preferences imply that
households will typically desire a smooth consumption path even as their
incomes vary over time. The two main sources of income variation are
life-cycle effects and the effects of shocks to an individual's
ability to earn income. To a large extent, the life-cycle pattern of
income is predictable. Labor income rises from young adulthood to middle
age, reaches a peak in the 45-54 age range, and then falls. Smoothing
consumption over this pattern of income would usually imply borrowing
(or drawing down savings) when young, paying off debt and accumulating
savings in the peak earning years, and using those savings for
consumption in the later years.
Shocks to a household's income come in two forms. Some shocks
are specific to an individual household. Prolonged illness of a wage
earner, for instance, can limit a household's earning ability. This
sort of specific uncertainty in income is referred to as idiosyncratic.
Other shocks affect larger groups of people. Swings in employment caused
by decline of an industry or by the ups and downs of the business cycle
affect the incomes of many households. That is, some income fluctuations
are associated with aggregate risk. Financial markets are more effective
at helping people smooth consumption against idiosyncratic shocks than
against systematic or aggregate shocks. In fact, if financial markets
worked perfectly, then people would be able to completely protect
themselves against idiosyncratic shocks. Similarly, complete and
well-functioning financial markets would allow people to smooth out
their lifetime variation in income, since this is largely predictable.
In this case, the only fluctuations in consumption would be those
arising from aggregate income risk.
In perfect financial markets, in addition to cases where standard
saving and borrowing instruments are used, households would have access
to a wide array of contracts that would allow them to insure against any
specific event that might cause a disruption to their incomes. But
financial markets are not perfect, and there are limitations to
households' abilities to smooth their consumption, even against
idiosyncratic or life-cycle income fluctuations. Households and other
market participants face an array of constraints on the types of
financial contracts available for managing income risk. Some of these
constraints have to do with information. Lenders typically cannot
perfectly screen borrowers according to their likelihood or propensity
to default. It is also difficult to monitor the behavior of borrowers
once they have taken a loan. Other constraints have to do with the costs
of enforcing contracts. Bankruptcy laws, for instance, limit the options
available to a lender if a borrower defaults. These constraints have two
kinds of effects. First, they limit the extent of specific insurance
against income fluctuations that households can receive, making saving
and borrowing the main means of consumption smoothing for many
households. Second, the constraints tend to raise the costs of borrowing
and place upper limits on the amount of debt any given household can
accumulate. So while the bankruptcy option actually facilitates
consumption smoothing for households that have fallen on hard enough
times--by releasing them from some debt payment obligations--the more
general effect of bankruptcy laws and other credit market constraints is
to increase the cost of borrowing and to therefore limit opportunities
to smooth consumption.
As Figure 1 clearly shows, the largest part of household debt is
that used to finance housing. This specific use of credit is quite
similar to the general use of credit for consumption smoothing purposes,
since the purchase of a home--a very lumpy transaction--allows the
household to consume a smooth stream of housing services. And while
constraints associated with limited information and enforcement costs
place limits on a household's unsecured borrowing capacity, such
limitations are less stringent when borrowing is collateralized, as in
the case of mortgage credit. Collateral reduces the risk of loss for the
lender should a borrower become unable to repay a loan. Similarly, a
portion of nonmortgage consumer credit is used to purchase cars and
other durable goods. Much of this credit is tied directly to--that is,
secured by--the items purchased. Still, the fastest growing part of
nonmortgage credit, especially since the 1990s, has been unsecured
borrowing.
3. THINKING ABOUT CHANGES IN CREDIT MARKETS--CAUSES
Figure 1 showed how consumers' use of credit has grown over
time. This growth could be the result of a number of factors. One
possibility is changes in the rate of income growth. Remember that in
the most basic description of consumption behavior, a household will
seek to perfectly smooth its consumption over time. This means that a
household expecting a growing income will borrow against future income
to even out its consumption expenditures. The amount that a household
will want to borrow will depend on how rapidly it expects its income to
grow. So the total amount of borrowing done by households in an economy
might be expected to depend on the anticipated growth in income. This
logic--faster anticipated income growth makes people willing to take on
more debt--carries over to the case where financial markets (and
therefore consumption smoothing) are not perfect.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
There have, in fact, been several swings in average income growth
in the United States in the last 50 years. Figure 2, for instance, shows
real GDP per capita. Of particular note is an extended period of slow
growth around 1980, with a pickup in growth beginning around 1984 and
continuing to the present, with two brief interruptions for the
recessions of the early 1990s and the early 2000s. This latter period of
faster income growth roughly coincides with the period of greatest
growth in household debt-to-income ratios. And debt growth was basically
flat during the extended period of stagnating income growth.
People's beliefs about their future income prospects are one
determinant of the demand for credit. Demand could also be affected by
variability of income. Given the limitations to financial arrangements
that result from information and enforcement constraints, saving and
borrowing constitute the main tool used by households to smooth
consumption in the face of income risk. A household will feel
well-prepared to deal with shocks to its income if it has a pool of
savings to draw on or if it is confident that it will have ample access
to credit. So, if a household faces an upper limit on how much credit it
will receive from financial institutions, it will want to make sure it
stays far enough away from that upper limit so that hitting the limit in
the event of a reduction in income would be unlikely. If income risk
increases--if income becomes more variable--the household will want to
increase this cushion between its borrowings and its debt limit.
Evidence examined by Dirk Krueger and Fabrizio Perri suggests that
income risk faced by households has increased since 1980, implying a
rising possibility of running up against limits on debt capacity. (5)
This change could have been a force for lessening household demand for
borrowing, perhaps partially offsetting the increase in demand that is
likely to have come from faster income growth. On the other hand,
Krueger and Perri argue that rising income risk could actually increase
a household's borrowing capacity. Their argument follows from the
assumption that, following default on a loan, a household's access
to credit would be sharply reduced. Rising income risk makes losing
access to credit more costly and therefore could make a borrower less
likely to default. Knowing that a borrower is less likely to default
makes a lender more willing to lend. So the effects of rising income
risk on overall household borrowing are uncertain. But there are other
factors affecting both demand and supply that could be at work in U.S.
credit markets.
The make-up of household consumption among housing services,
durable goods, and nondurable goods is one additional demand-side factor
that could affect household borrowing. Since homes and durable goods are
quite typically purchased with credit, an increase in consumers'
relative demand for these goods could well be associated with an
increase in borrowing. Some evidence in favor of this factor appeared
earlier in this essay. As previously mentioned, rising homeownership and
rising home values relative to income are at least suggestive of an
increase in the relative demand for housing.
Also on the demand side, a household's willingness to borrow
could be affected by its perceptions about the consequences of default.
In the United States, defaulting borrowers can seek the protection of
the bankruptcy law, which allows them to either reschedule their
payments to their creditors (under Chapter 13 of the bankruptcy code) or
dismiss their debts in exchange for surrendering their assets, above a
personal exemption (under Chapter 7, with exemptions determined at the
state level). Some observers have argued that a greater propensity to
file for bankruptcy is evidence of consumers seeing default as less
costly than in the past and is one cause of rising consumer
indebtedness. This is often discussed in terms of a sense of stigma that
households may feel when filing for bankruptcy. The argument is that
stigma, a psychic cost of default, has declined over time, perhaps for
cultural reasons not directly related to credit market conditions. Such
a decline of the perceived costs of default would make a household more
willing to borrow at a given interest rate.
But the effect that a decline in stigma or in other costs of
default has on borrowing amounts is at least muted because of the effect
this change would have on lenders and the price of credit. Borrowers who
increase their debt because they do not mind defaulting increase the
risk faced by lenders, and lenders, in turn, will have to raise their
interest rates in order to compensate for this increase in risk. This
rise in interest rates will tend to reduce borrowing, especially by
those who consider themselves unlikely to default. In fact, Kartik
Athreya has shown that the overall effect of declining stigma would
likely be a decline in total borrowing. (6)
There could also be factors on the supply side of credit markets
that contributed to a period of rising debt among U.S. households. In
particular, technological improvements have reduced the costs to lenders
of evaluating borrowers and managing exposures to default risks. This
type of change would amount to a reduction of the overall cost of
lending and would thereby lead to an increase in the supply of credit.
This increase in supply would show up in a reduction in the financial
intermediary's "spread" between the interest paid to
retail savers and the rate charged on loans.
Of course, the financial intermediary that makes the loan is not
the ultimate supply of funds to a borrower. Rather funds originate with
the savings of other households or businesses. And the funds could come
from within the same country or from abroad. In recent years, funds from
other countries have indeed been a major source of supply for U.S.
credit markets. Even though the bulk of this foreign investment is the
purchase of government securities, these transactions do constitute an
increase in the total amount of funds flowing into U.S. financial
markets, which could translate into an easing of credit conditions for
borrowing households.
Interpreting evidence on interest rates or spreads over time is
made difficult by another trend in the pricing of loans. There is an
increasing tendency of lenders to differentiate their lending terms
based on borrower characteristics that are associated with default risk.
In the 1980s, consumer lenders, especially for unsecured debt like
credit card borrowings, usually set a single interest rate at which they
lent to all acceptable borrowers. Lenders then used relatively rough
evaluations of borrower-default risk to determine who got credit.
Advances in credit scoring and other techniques allow lenders to
estimate borrowers' default risk in a more precise way than was
possible in the past, making it easier to offer different prices to
borrowers, depending on their risk characteristics. This change has
differing effects on the various types of borrowers. Very low-risk
borrowers probably benefit, as they pay an interest rate that more
closely reflects their risk level. On the other end of the spectrum,
high-risk borrowers, who previously were screened out of access to
credit, also benefit by finding their ability to borrow enhanced.
Borrowers in the middle, on the other hand, could be hurt by a move from
uniform to differential pricing of credit. These in-between borrowers
may have benefited in the past from interest rates that averaged them in
with lower-risk borrowers. The effects on different types of borrowers
of increased use of differential pricing are detailed by Wendy Edelberg.
(7) Still, the technological change that makes differential pricing more
practical is the same change that lowers the overall costs of lending,
making it likely that many, if not most types of borrowers, have seen
either a reduction in the cost of borrowing or an increase in access to
credit.
Another change on the supply side of credit markets that would have
effects similar to declining costs of lending is an increase in the
degree of competition among lenders. If competition is weak, then
lenders are able to set interest rate margins at levels that more than
compensate for risk and the costs of lending. Many descriptions of the
credit card lending market describe it as having relatively weak
competition in the 1980s. (8) The structure of the credit card market
has changed considerably since then, with many observers concluding that
increased competition has put downward pressure on interest rate
spreads. Competition appears to have increased in the mortgage lending
market as well, where consumers are increasingly able to search over a
nationwide pool of potential lenders, rather than being restricted to a
smaller set of local firms. Falling average costs of borrowing, from a
combination of improved technology and increased competition, appears to
be a major contributing factor to the expansion of consumer credit. (9)
4. THINKING ABOUT CHANGES IN CREDIT MARKETS--CONSEQUENCES
Changes in credit market conditions shift the demand or supply of
credit, resulting in changes in the amount of borrowing done by
households. The data show clearly that the net effect of these changes
in recent decades has been to increase borrowing relative to income. But
to evaluate these changes, we would like to have a sense of how they
affected the overall economic well-being of the typical household. Some
of the changes discussed in the previous section were supply changes
that have the effect of reducing the cost of borrowing. These changes
enhance households' ability to smooth their consumption and are
therefore likely to make the average household better off.
When an increase in borrowing is driven by increases in demand for
credit, the effect on a household's well-being depends on the
reasons for the increase in demand. For instance, a temporary increase
in borrowing could result from a disruption to a household's
income. While the use of credit allows the household to respond
efficiently to the disruption, the rise in borrowing in such an instance
is occurring as the household is becoming worse off. So, a short-lived
surge in borrowing could be an indicator of households experiencing some
financial stress. But the evidence reviewed in this essay deals more
with a sustained rise in borrowing. As discussed previously, the
demand-side factor most likely to be associated with such a sustained
increase is rising expectations of income growth. In this case,
increased debt would be associated with improving economic well-being.
Given that a main motivation in households' use of credit is
smoothing of consumption, one way to assess the impact of credit
expansion is to ask whether this expansion has facilitated consumption
smoothing. The previous section noted evidence studied by Krueger and
Perri that points to rising income risk for U.S. households since the
1980s. These authors also examine the variability of consumption and
find that, while consumption risk has risen over time as well, it has
not risen nearly as much as income risk. They conclude that
households' ability to smooth consumption has improved over time,
consistent with a view that the expansion of credit has, on average,
benefited households.
The fact that the typical household's welfare improves with a
sustained expansion of credit does not mean that such a trend creates no
problems or difficulties. Most importantly, the forgoing discussion
assumes that household decisionmaking is well-informed by the relevant
facts and based on sound analysis of the costs and benefits of credit.
While this may be a reasonable assumption for enough households to make
our conclusion about the "average" household valid, there may
well be households whose decisions are imprudent, naive, or based on
faulty analysis. This may be particularly true in a period when credit
use is growing relatively rapidly. First, a period of credit expansion
may be a period when the number of new and inexperienced borrowers is
particularly high, and such borrowers may be more likely to make
mistakes in their financial decisions. Second, if the growth of credit
is associated with the introduction of new credit instruments or new
ways of pricing credit, even some more experienced borrowers may not
fully appreciate the implications of their decisions under the new
arrangements.
If credit market changes leave some consumers relatively uninformed
about the choices they face, then these changes could also create
opportunities for some providers of credit services to exploit
consumers' lack of knowledge. It should, therefore, not be
surprising to see periods of rapid credit growth coincide with increased
instances and allegations of abusive practices. One particular area of
change and growth in credit markets in the last 15 years has been in
subprime lending. Products and practices in the subprime market have
expanded the set of consumers with access to credit, meaning the average
subprime borrower is even more likely to be an inexperienced borrower
than the average borrower overall. So, in recent years we have seen
rising public concern regarding potentially predatory lending, or
abusive practices in the subprime lending market.
Of course, even for borrowers who are capable of evaluating their
credit market opportunities and making well-informed decisions, outcomes
are not always positive. A consumer may face unanticipated expenses or
changes in income that limit the ability to service debt, leading to
default, bankruptcy, or foreclosure on a mortgaged home. And it is often
hard to know, after the fact, whether a distressed borrower made a sound
financial decision at the time a loan was originally taken out. So
distinguishing those who were victimized from those who were careless and from those who were just unlucky is not always possible.
The growth in bad outcomes from borrowing, a trend that follows
from the general growth in the use of credit, can be a driving force for
proponents of a public policy response to credit market phenomena. As
more borrowers find themselves experiencing difficulties, sentiment
emerges for policies that could keep consumers out of credit-induced
financial trouble. With such policies tending to be aimed at protecting
borrowers of low and moderate means, a look at the relevant facts
regarding credit use by households of different income levels may prove
useful.
5. BORROWING TRENDS ACROSS THE INCOME DISTRIBUTION
The data presented in Figure 1 provide a picture of the borrowing
behavior of the entire household sector. That is, these data might be
thought of as reflective of the average household in the United States.
These trends appear to be explained by the supply and demand factors
discussed in the previous section. But as was mentioned before, changes
in credit market conditions do not affect all households in the same
way. In particular, the uses and consequences of debt may differ among
households at different income levels. Figure 3 presents information on
household borrowing trends across the income distribution. These data
are drawn from the Federal Reserve Board's SCF, which is conducted
every three years, with the most recent data coming from the 2001
survey. (10) The data from this source do not stretch back as far as the
aggregate data, but they do include the period of rapid credit growth in
the 1990s.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The five graphs in the figure show the growth in median
debt-to-income ratios for the second, third, and fourth income quintiles and for the top two income deciles. In broad terms, the trends for
different income quintiles look similar to the aggregate, with
debt-to-income ratios rising steadily through the 1990s. In percentage
terms, this growth was the most pronounced for the group between the
20th and 39th percentiles, which registered a 290 percent increase,
albeit from a very low base. By contrast, the median debt-to-income
ratio among the wealthiest households--the top quintile--rose by 48
percent.
The poorest consumers--those in the lowest income quintile--are
missing in Figure 3. This is because the figure shows median debt to
income for each quintile, and throughout this period, fewer than half of
all households in the lowest quintile had any debt. If we were to plot,
instead, the median ratio in each quintile only for those households
with debt, the lowest quintile would look more similar to the others.
Doing this leaves out growth in debt that comes from increased
participation in credit markets and measures only the extent to which
borrowing increased by people who were already borrowing. Among
households having at least some debt, debt-to-income ratios grew
fastest--78 percent growth from 1989 to 2001--for households in the
lowest quintile. At the same time, the fraction of low- and
moderate-income households with debt increased during this period. This
rate of "participation" in taking on debt increased in all
income groups below the median, with the fastest growth coming in the
second lowest quintile.
The predominance of debt-to-income growth among households in the
lower part of the income distribution raises questions about whether the
causes or consequences of growing credit use among these households are
different than for households at or above the median income level. As
described in Section 3, there are both demand and supply factors that
have contributed to the growing use of credit among U.S. households. On
the demand side, a major determinant of borrowing is a household's
expectations of income growth. The growth of the aggregate use of credit
in the 1990s lines up well with a pickup in income growth during that
period. But income growth was uneven, with income inequality expanding.
That is, the acceleration of income growth occurred more for
higher-income households. So this demand-side factor might not have been
as important for the growth of borrowing by low-income households.
On the supply side, the main factors increasing debt have been
improvements in technology that allow improved underwriting practices
and a move to greater sensitivity of prices depending on borrowers'
risk characteristics. Both of these factors are likely to have improved
financial markets' and institutions' ability to bear the risks
associated with lending to lower-income households. The greater
variability of pricing, in particular, is likely to have helped expand
credit to households that previously would have been rationed out of the
credit market. This effect may be reflected in the growth in the
fraction of low-income households that hold credit.
To the extent that growing credit use among low-income households
is being driven by growth in the number of borrowers, it is likely that
this expansion has brought new, inexperienced borrowers into the market.
This is consistent with the direction of much of the recent discussion
about consumer credit policy.
6. POLICY RESPONSES TO CHANGES IN CREDIT MARKETS
There are three broad types of policy approaches to limiting
financial difficulties for borrowers. First, one can imagine policies
aimed at the problem of borrowers being uninformed about financial
choices. Second, policies that seek to identify and punish instances of
abuse by lenders could provide some protection to borrowers. Finally,
regulators could try to place limits on the terms and prices that
lenders can offer in the marketplace.
Efforts to raise consumers' understanding of financial choices
have gained considerable attention recently. There are two broad sets of
tools that serve this goal. One can require disclosures by lenders with
the aim of ensuring that consumers can easily compare alternative credit
options. This is the approach taken under the truth in lending laws. It
is not always easy to summarize all of the relevant conditions in a
credit contract with a few simple numbers, however. As the variety of
terms and conditions available in the market continues to expand, there
may be a limit to how much disclosures alone can enhance consumer
knowledge.
The other avenue to creating better informed consumers is through
the provision of financial literacy services. Credit counseling is one
form of such services, and the 2005 bankruptcy legislation included
counseling from an approved nonprofit provider as a precondition for
bankruptcy filing. The act also provides for the development of
postfiling educational materials. There has also been movement in some
states to require financial literacy curricula in public primary and
secondary schools. Some financial institutions and trade associations
have become directly involved in the development of financial literacy
programs, perhaps as an investment in their public image, but also
perhaps because many banks see better informed customers as a legitimate
business goal.
What exactly is it that consumers should learn from financial
education? The goal, presumably, is for a household to be able to make
informed, forward-looking choices with regard to the use of credit
instruments. But being able to fully calculate the expected present
value of different options may be beyond the reach of many consumers.
Retail credit products are not simple financial contracts. They often
involve provisions that amount to options for either the borrower or the
lender. Such options might be explicit in the contract, like the option
to prepay a mortgage, or implicit, like the option to file for
bankruptcy. Accurately evaluating options is difficult, even for the
financially sophisticated. Perhaps one realistic goal of financial
education is for borrowers to appreciate that if one credit alternative
has a lower initial monthly payment than another, then it is probably
more costly on another dimension. Borrowers who can understand such
trade-offs are less likely to make choices that have a high chance of
negative outcomes.
A by-product of raising the level of financial savvy among
borrowers is that the potential gain to deceptive and abusive practices
would be reduced. Still, there will always be instances of such
behavior, and effective law enforcement is an important supplement to a
well-informed population of borrowers. Prosecution of specific acts,
however, is difficult and costly, leading some to advocate credit market
regulations that prohibit certain practices that are believed to be
particularly susceptible to abuse. The prospect of prohibiting specific
contractual terms presents a difficult trade-off. Such a prohibition may
effectively prevent some instances of bad outcomes such as defaults,
foreclosures, or bankruptcies. And some of those instances would
undoubtedly represent cases where it was probably not in the
borrower's best interest to take out a loan with the particular
terms. Some would be the result of borrowers simply making mistakes, and
some would arise from lenders being deceptive or manipulative. But some
cases of bad outcomes would result even for borrowers making sound,
well-informed choices. For those, the particular credit contract was the
best option at the time they borrowed.
A prohibition of a particular practice limits some households'
ability to manage their finances and consumption. So such a regulatory
approach to credit market behavior necessarily protects some borrowers
at the expense of others. Still, one could argue that such a policy is
warranted if it were the case that the group that would be helped is
much larger than the group that would be hurt, or if the amount by which
some are helped significantly exceeds the amount by which others are
hurt. But the type of data necessary to make this kind of determination
is very hard to come by. To fully understand the overall impact on
borrowers of a particular lending practice and to assess the likely
effect of prohibiting it, one would want to take a look at a sample of
households, some who used the product in question and some who did not.
By tracking that sample for a considerable period, both before and after
taking on the loan, one would reveal the average determinants of using
the product together with its impact.
Without such detailed data, the regulatory prohibition of lending
practices should be viewed very cautiously. The general description
provided in this essay of the economics of and trends in household
credit suggests that, on the whole, the growth of credit we have
observed in recent decades has been beneficial for consumers, providing
them with an expanded set of options for managing their lifetime
consumption. And this observation points to an important principle for
evaluating changes in credit markets, whether those changes are in the
form of new products or new regulations. The decision to borrow is
inherently a forward-looking decision. Households borrow to align their
consumption today, as well as their holdings of housing and durable
goods, with their beliefs about their consumption possibilities in the
future. Accordingly, the appropriate perspective in evaluating the
addition or elimination of a credit product is from the point in time at
which a household is making a borrowing choice. Is a household made
better off or worse off by having access to this product? Adopting this
perspective does not mean that one should ignore the bad outcomes that
result from use of the product. It means, instead, that one should think
of those bad outcomes as part of a distribution of possible outcomes and
ask whether this distribution presents the household, on average, with
better consumption opportunities than would be available without the
product. Without the data necessary to evaluate the distribution of
outcomes, we are left simply knowing that the elimination of a
particular credit product may help some but hurt others. Simply knowing
that there is a trade-off is a first step, but a small step on the way
to policy analysis.
REFERENCES
Athreya, Kartik. 2004. "Shame as It Ever Was: Stigma and
Personal Bankruptcy." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 90 (Spring): 1-19.
Ausubel, Lawrence. 1991. "The Failure of Competition in the
Credit Card Market." American Economic Review 81 (March): 50-81.
Bostic, Raphael W. 2002. "Trends in Equal Access to Credit
Products." In The Impact of Public Policy on Consumer Credit, eds.
Thomas Durkin and Michael Staten. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers,
171-203.
Calder, Lendol. 1999. Financing the American Dream: A Cultural
History of Consumer Credit. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Edelberg, Wendy. 2003. "Risk-based Pricing of Interest Rates
in Household Loan Markets." Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary
Affairs, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2003-62.
Eisinger, Jesse. 2006. "Night of the Living Debt." Wall
Street Journal (January 4): C1.
Krueger, Dirk, and Fabrizio Perri. 2005. "Does Income
Inequality Lead to Consumption Equality? Evidence and Theory."
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Department Staff Report
363 (June).
Maki, Dean. 2002. "The Growth of Consumer Credit and the
Household Debt Service Burden." In The Impact of Public Policy on
Consumer Credit, eds. Thomas Durkin and Michael Staten. Boston: Kluwer
Academic Publishers, 43-63.
This article first appeared in the Bank's 2005 Annual Report.
The author is John A. Weinberg, a Senior Vice President and Director of
Research. Kartik Athreya, Ned Prescott, Aaron Steelman, and Alex Wolman
contributed valuable comments to this article. The views expressed are
those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
System.
(1) An example is "Night of the Living Debt" in the
January 4, 2006, Wall Street Journal.
(2) See Calder (1999).
(3) Bostic (2002).
(4) Maki (2002).
(5) See Krueger and Perri (2005).
(6) See Athreya (2004).
(7) Edelberg (2003).
(8) A notable example is Ausubel (1991).
(9) Athreya (2004) examines alternative sources of rising credit
and finds a strong case for technology and/or competition as a primary
factor.
(10) At the time this Report was in production, the 2004 SCF
results had not yet been released.