Inflation uncertainty and the recent low level of the long bond rate.
Mehra, Yash P.
Many analysts and policymakers have been intrigued by the recently
observed low levels of long-term interest rates. Figure 1 charts the
actual and predicted levels of the nominal yield on ten-year U.S.
Treasury bonds over 1994Q1 to 2005Q1; the predicted values were
generated using the historical relationship that had existed between the
long bond yield and several of its macroeconomic determinants including
long-term inflation expectations, near-term outlook for the economy, and
the stance of monetary policy. The prediction errors are also charted
there. As one can see, for the past few years the actual long bond rate
has remained consistently below what is predicted using these standard
economic determinants. (1) Other analysts using somewhat different
economic determinants have come to the same conclusion that the long
bond rate has recently been substantially lower than can be explained by
macroeconomic conditions. (2)
In order to explain the recent puzzling behavior of long-term
interest rates, two alternative hypotheses have received prominent
attention in the financial press. (3) The first one attributes the
current low level of the long bond rate to the lowering of the inflation
risk premium. In particular, this hypothesis posits that as a result of
the improved inflation performance of the U.S. economy, inflation
uncertainty has declined, leading to lowering of inflation risk
premiums, which is reflected in lower real and nominal bond yields. (4)
The other hypothesis attributes recent declines in long-term interest
rates to increases in purchases of U.S. Treasury securities by foreign
central banks. (5)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This article develops an empirical test of the first hypothesis,
using a reduced-form interest rate equation that links the long bond
rate directly to macroeconomic variables, including an empirical proxy
for inflation uncertainty. I focus on the first hypothesis for two
reasons. First, despite the popularity of the first hypothesis in the
financial press, it has not yet been formally investigated. In most
previous research, the evidence in favor of the first hypothesis comes
from the term structure model, indicating that term premiums have
declined and that part of this decline is attributed to a decline in the
inflation risk premium. This article, however, constructs a direct
empirical measure of inflation uncertainty and examines whether the
recent behavior of the long bond rate can be linked to the recent
reduction in inflation uncertainty. Second, some previous research has
indicated that the empirical evidence favoring the second hypothesis is
fragile in the sense that the empirical evidence--the long bond rate is
influenced by direct foreign capital inflows--is due to the most recent
data. (6) In view of these considerations, I focus on the first
hypothesis, but I do examine the robustness of results with respect to
inclusion of foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in
the list of macroeconomic determinants.
It is widely understood that investors holding long-term U.S.
Treasury bonds bear an inflation risk, because actual inflation that is
higher or lower than what they forecasted when they bought bonds would
make their holding of bonds significantly less or more valuable. Hence,
if there is considerable uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts
in the sense that the probability distribution of long-term inflation
forecasts is widely dispersed, investors demand compensation for bearing
the inflation risk, and hence long bond rates contain risk premiums.
Since we do not have a direct empirical measure of uncertainty
about long-term inflation forecasts, this article constructs an
empirical proxy making two identifying assumptions. The first assumption
is that uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts is positively
correlated with uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts, so
that when investors become more uncertain about their short-term
inflation forecasts, their uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts also increases. The second assumption is that uncertainty
about short-term inflation forecasts can be approximated by the mean
squared error (MSE) of short-term inflation forecasts, so that
uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts rises when the variance (in particular, the MSE) of ex-post short-term inflation forecast errors
increases. Given these two assumptions, I examine the MSE of short-term
inflation forecasts, using survey data on private-sector GDP inflation
expectations. In particular, the article creates a time series on
uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts, using rolling
three-year windows on the MSE of short-term inflation forecasts over
1984Q1 to 2004Q3. (7)
The resulting time series on uncertainty about short-term inflation
forecasts has a clear downward trend over 1984 to 2004, which is
consistent with the downward trend in mean and variance of short-term
inflation forecasts. This trend suggests that reduction in short-term
inflation uncertainty may reflect the good inflation performance of the
U.S. economy; namely, short-term inflation uncertainty declined because
inflation both steadily declined and became more predictable.
The article then estimates a reduced-form bond rate equation that
links the long bond rate to macroeconomic variables, including the
aforementioned empirical measure of uncertainty about short-term
inflation forecasts. The results indicate the long bond rate is
positively correlated with short-term inflation uncertainty over the
full sample period of 1984Q1 to 2004Q3, suggesting that an increase in
uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts raises uncertainty
about long-term inflation forecasts and hence may account for the
presence of the inflation risk premium in the bond rate. However, the
results also indicate that the estimated coefficient that measures the
response of the long bond rate to short-term inflation uncertainty has
declined since 2001Q4, implying that in recent years an increase in
short-term inflation uncertainty is associated with a
small-to-negligible increase in uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts. In fact, the results are consistent with the hypothesis that
the inflation risk premium embedded in the long bond rate has
disappeared, thereby accounting in part for the current low level of the
long bond rate.
As stated above, one of the identifying assumptions in the
empirical work here is that uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts is positively correlated with uncertainty about short-term
inflation forecasts and that the magnitude of this positive correlation is stable over the sample period being studied. However, the result
above--the correlation of the long bond rate with short-term inflation
uncertainty has weakened in recent years--may be interpreted to mean
that the identifying assumption made above does not hold for the
complete sample period of 1984 to 2004; namely, while in the past an
increase in short-term inflation uncertainty may have increased
uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts, it no longer does so.
This development may be the consequence of increased Fed credibility. It
is only recently that investors have become more confident that the
current low and stable short-term inflation will continue in the long
run so that a given increase in short-term inflation uncertainty now
leads to a small-to-negligible increase in uncertainty about long-term
inflation forecasts, and hence investors demand lower inflation risk
premiums than before. This consequence of increased Fed credibility can
be seen in the fact that it is only recently that both short- and
long-term inflation forecasts have become fully anchored, in contrast to
the early part of the sample period when they were not anchored.
The empirical work here that attributes the current low level of
the long bond rate to a lower inflation risk premium is robust to the
inclusion of foreign official capital inflows in the list of
macroeconomic determinants of bond yields. The results do indicate the
long bond rate is negatively correlated with this measure of foreign
official capital inflows, however, this correlation is marginally
significant and fragile, being absent in the period prior to the recent
episode of increased capital inflows. Together, these results favor the
hypothesis that attributes the recent low level of the long bond rate
mostly to lowering of inflation risk premiums.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. In Section 1, I
examine the behavior of uncertainty about short-term inflation
forecasts, constructed using private-sector, ex-post inflation forecast
errors. Section 2 contains discussion of a reduced-form interest rate
equation that relates the long bond rate to macroeconomic variables.
Section 3 presents empirical results, and concluding remarks are in
Section 4.
1. A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS: SOURCES OF DECLINE IN UNCERTAINTY ABOUT
SHORT-TERM INFLATION FORECASTS
As indicated at the outset, if there is considerable uncertainty
about long-term inflation forecasts, holders of long-term U.S. Treasury
bonds bear an inflation risk and hence long bond yields have embedded in
them inflation risk premiums. Since one does not have a direct empirical
measure of uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts, the article
proceeds under the assumption that uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts is positively correlated with uncertainty about short-term
forecasts. This section constructs the empirical measure of uncertainty
about short-term inflation forecasts and analyzes its behavior over the
sample period of 1984Q1 to 2004Q3.
Measuring Uncertainty about Short-Term Inflation Forecasts
If inflation had been harder to forecast in the past, then it is
likely to raise uncertainty about agents' current forecasts of
expected future inflation rates. Given this basic idea, the article
examines ex-post inflation forecast errors, focusing on the MSE of
one-to-four-quarters-ahead inflation forecasts. If the MSE of inflation
forecasts increases over time, then it is likely to raise the variance
of agents' current forecasts of expected future inflation rates and
hence will lead to increased uncertainty about their mean inflation
forecasts. For inflation forecasts, I use private-sector GDP inflation
forecasts from the Philadelphia Fed's Survey of Professional
Forecasters (denoted hereafter as SPF). (8) I use survey data because
recent evidence indicates that surveys perform much better than some
standard reduced-form inflation forecasting models in predicting future
inflation. (9) Despite the evidence in Romer and Romer (2004) that
Greenbook inflation forecasts are more accurate relative to
private-sector forecasts, I use the latter because Greenbook forecasts
are released to the public with a five-year delay, and hence bond yields
are likely to reflect private-sector inflation expectations. Since
surveys are used, I compute forecast errors using real-time data on
actual inflation as in Romer and Romer (2004). I create time series on
the MSE of one-to-four-quarters-ahead inflation forecasts, using rolling
three-year windows over 1984Q1 to 2005Q3. (10) This time series is an
empirical proxy measuring uncertainty about short-term inflation
forecasts, denoted hereafter as short-term inflation uncertainty.
Figure 2 charts the rolling MSE of contemporaneous, one-quarter-
and four-quarter-ahead inflation forecasts over 1984Q1 to 2004Q3. (11)
As can be seen, the evidence of a decline in short-term inflation
uncertainty is quite clear, as the MSE of inflation forecasts has
drifted down intermittently since 1984. In particular, focusing on the
MSE of the four-quarter-ahead inflation forecasts, short-term inflation
uncertainty declined significantly first during the latter half of the
1980s, increased somewhat in the first half of the 1990s, and then again
drifted lower beginning in the late 1990s.
Low Inflation, Great Moderation, and Short-Term Inflation
Uncertainty
One plausible explanation of the decline observed in short-term
inflation uncertainty over 1984Q1 to 2005Q3 is the good inflation
performance of the U.S. economy due to Federal Reserve policy during
this period. In particular, this explanation posits that, under Chairman
Volcker and Chairman Greenspan, the Federal Reserve gradually had moved
toward a policy framework that places a heavy weight on the requirement
that the central bank keep inflation low and stable and hence the
public's expectations of inflation under control. In addition,
during this sample period the Fed has taken a number of steps toward
increased transparency meant to reduce the public's uncertainty
about the Fed's long-term inflation objective (Bernanke 2003,
2004). As a result, inflation has trended down and stabilized at low
levels, thereby making inflation more predictable and contributing to
lower short-term inflation uncertainty.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 3 provides a visual confirmation of the hypothesis that
decline in short-term inflation uncertainty is related to good inflation
performance of the U.S. economy over 1984Q1 to 2005Q3. Focusing on the
behavior of the four-quarter-ahead actual inflation and its forecast,
the top panel in Figure 3 charts the variance of actual future inflation
and the MSE of its forecast, calculated as before using rolling
three-year windows. The middle panel charts the rolling mean of
inflation forecasts, whereas the bottom panel charts the rolling
variance of GDP inflation forecasts. The top and middle panels indicate
that the series measuring the MSE of the inflation forecast has a
downward trend that is shared by the series measuring the mean forecast
but not by the series measuring the variance of actual inflation. This
suggests that short-term inflation uncertainty declined not because
inflation was less volatile but because inflation trended down. (12)
Furthermore, the bottom panel indicates that variance of the predictable
component of inflation also declined significantly during this period,
suggesting increased predictability of inflation. Figure 3 thus provides
a visual confirmation of the hypothesis that short-term inflation
uncertainty declined because inflation both trended down and became more
predictable. (13)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Current Low Short-Term Inflation Uncertainty and Anchoring of
Long-Term Inflation Expectations
Figure 4 highlights another key feature of the recent favorable inflation performance: the current low level of short-term inflation
uncertainty has accompanied decline in volatility of long-term inflation
expectations. The top panel in Figure 4 plots the rolling MSE of
four-quarter GDP inflation forecasts as before, and the other panel
charts the rolling standard deviation of the ten-year-ahead CPI expected
inflation. As one can see, during the past few years the standard
deviation of the ten-year CPI inflation forecast has been zero,
suggesting the recent stabilization and anchoring of long-term inflation
expectations.
One simple explanation of this recent anchoring of long-term
inflation expectations is that the recent period of low short-term
inflation uncertainty has increased confidence that inflation will
remain low and stable in the long run, which was absent before. This
outcome may be the consequence of increased Fed credibility that
occurred near the end of the sample period. During the early part of the
sample period 1984 to 2005, though short-term inflation uncertainty
declined to lower levels, long-term inflation expectations did not
stabilize, reflecting the lack of Fed credibility. As one can see,
during the early part of this sample period, both short-term and
long-term inflation forecasts were not stabilized (see the bottom panel
in Figure 3 and the lower panel in Figure 4). One implication of this
different behavior of long-term inflation expectations is that the
correlation of the long bond rate with short-term inflation uncertainty
is likely to be weaker near the end of the sample period than it is
during the early part, meaning a given rise in short-term inflation
uncertainty is unlikely to raise uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts as much as it did previously. This implication is confirmed by
the empirical work in the following section, which attributes the recent
decline in the inflation risk premium to reduced sensitivity of the long
bond rate to uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts. (14)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
2. A REDUCED-FORM EMPIRICAL MODEL OF THE LONG BOND RATE
In this section, I discuss a reduced-form empirical equation that
links the long bond rate to macroeconomic variables, including the
empirical proxy for short-term inflation uncertainty. I also describe
the data used to estimate the reduced-form equation.
Long Run: The Fisher Equation
The reduced-form interest rate equation that underlies the
empirical work here has two parts: a long-run and a short-run part. The
long-run part, based on the Fisher equation, relates the level of the
bond rate to long-term inflation expectations, risk premiums, and a
risk-free long real rate, as in (1.3).
(1 - [T.sub.t]) B[R.sub.t] = r[r.sub.t] +
[a.sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t.sup.e]; [a.sub.[pi]] = 1, (1.1)
r[r.sub.t] = rr* + [a.sub.r] R [P.sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t], (1.2)
B[R.sub.t] = (1/1 - [T.sub.t])[rr* + [a.sub.r] R [P.sub.t] +
[a.sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t.sup.e] + [[mu].sub.t]]; [a.sub.[pi]] = 1, (1.3)
where B R is the long bond rate; [T.sub.t] is the marginal tax rate on interest income in period t; r[r.sub.t] is the after-tax expected
long real rate; rr* is the after-tax, risk-free expected long real rate;
R P is a risk premium variable; [pi]* is long-term inflation
expectations; and [mu] is the stationary disturbance term. Equation 1.1
is just the long-run Fisher equation that relates the after-tax long
bond rate to the expected long real rate and inflation expectations.
Equation 1.2 says the expected long real rate is mean stationary once we
account for the presence of risk premiums in bond yields. If we
substitute (1.2) into (1.1), one gets equation (1.3), which relates the
level of the bond rate to long-term inflation expectations, risk
premiums, and a risk-free long real rate.
The coefficient [a.sub.[pi]] is the after-tax Fisher coefficient
that measures the response of the after-tax bond rate to inflation
expectations and is generally assumed unity. The key point to note is
that in the presence of taxes on interest income, the long bond rate
should rise during an inflation episode by an amount that exceeds
expected inflation sufficiently to compensate lenders both for their
loss of capital due to inflation and for the taxation of interest
income. Hence, in the presence of the tax effect, the before-tax Fisher
coefficient ([a.sub.[pi]]/(1 - [T.sub.t])) is likely to exceed unity,
its exact magnitude varying with the marginal tax rate on interest
income. (15) Furthermore, a significant component of risk premiums
embedded in bond yields is likely to be inflation risk, arising as a
result of unpredictable movements in long-term expected inflation.
Short Run: Short-Run Changes in the Bond Rate are Dominated by
Changes in the Outlook for the Economy and the Stance of Monetary Policy
The bond rate equation given in (1.3) is long run and is motivated using the Fisher equation, in which the level of the long bond rate is
related to the risk-adjusted expected long real rate and expected
inflation. The expected long real rate is, however, unobservable. Recent
research that has expanded term structure models of bond yields to
include macroeconomic factors suggest that changes in the expected long
real rate reflect changes in expected future short rates, which in turn
are likely to be correlated with changes in the outlook for the economy
and changes in the current and future stance of monetary policy. (16) In
order to control for influences of other macroeconomic variables on the
long bond rate, I consider the following short-run, error-correction
specification of the bond rate equation (Mehra 1984, 1994):
[DELTA](1 - [T.sub.t]) B[R.sub.t] = [f.sub.0] +
[f.sub.[DELTA]rp][DELTA]R[P.sub.t] +
[f.sub.[DELTA][pi]][DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.e] + [k.summation over (h=1)]
[f.sub.1rs][DELTA][dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [k.summation over (h=1)]
[f.sub.2rh] [DELTA][dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [f.sub.3r]u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t]
- [f.sub.ec][[mu].sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (2)
where [[mu].sub.t-1] = (1 - [T.sub.t-1]) B[R.sub.t-1] - rr* -
[a.sub.r] R [P.sub.t-1] - [a.sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t-1.sup.e]
where h is the forecast horizon, [DELTA][dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] is
change in the h-quarter-ahead forecast of real growth,
[DELTA][dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] is change in the h-quarter-ahead forecast
of the inflation rate, and u[DELTA]FFR is the surprise component of the
change in the federal funds rate. Equation 2 relates short-run changes
in the after-tax bond rate to three sets of economic variables: the
first set contains first differences of economic variables that enter
the long-run Fisher equation here ([DELTA]R[P.sub.t],
[DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.e]); the second set contains variables measuring
changes in the outlook for the economy and stance of monetary policy
([DELTA][dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e], [DELTA][dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e],
u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t]); and the third set contains only a lagged
error-correction variable ([[mu].sub.t-1]), measured as a gap between
the actual level of the long rate and the level consistent with the long
bond equation. The coefficient on the error-correction variable in (2)
is hypothesized to be negative, meaning the bond rate declines if in the
previous period the actual bond rate was high relative to the level
consistent with its long-run determinants specified in (1.3).
In the empirical bond equation (2), changes in the outlook for the
economy are measured as changes in private-sector forecasts of real
growth and inflation. The expected signs of coefficients that appear on
changes in anticipated real growth and inflation variables in (2) are
positive, suggesting that accelerated future real growth or inflation is
likely to lead to higher future short real rates and hence to a higher
long real rate. The positive correlation between the long real rate and
higher anticipated real growth or inflation may arise as a result of
"lean-against-the-winds" monetary policy strategy; namely, the
private sector expects the Federal Reserve to raise the funds rate
target when real growth or inflation is anticipated to accelerate,
leading to higher future short real rates.
The impact of monetary policy actions on the expected long real
rate is captured by the "surprise" component of changes in the
funds rate target. Recent research indicates that bond yields respond to
this surprise component and that the nature of the yield curve response
depends crucially on the interpretation of market participants'
reasons behind the policy move. If the policy move is interpreted to
reveal "new" information about the outlook for inflation and
real growth, interest rates of all maturities, including the long end,
move in the same direction as the funds rate target. If, on the other
hand, market participants view the policy move as driven by changes in
the central bank's preferences (such as a shift to a more
inflation-averse policy), long and short rates move in opposite
directions (Ellingsen and Soderstrom 2001, 2004; Gurkaynak, Sack, and
Swanson 2005). Thus, this literature suggests that the response of the
long bond rate to policy is time varying, and the bond rate may actually
fall if bond market participants interpret policy tightening as
resulting in lower inflation in the long run.
Combining Long- and Short-Run Parts
Equation (2) is the short-term bond equation that relates changes
in the bond rate to (a) "changes" in the private-sector
outlook for real growth and inflation; (b) the surprise component of
changes in the funds rate target; (c) changes in long-term inflation
expectations and risk premiums; and (d) the lagged value of an
error-correction variable, measuring discrepancies between the actual
level of the bond rate and the level consistent with the long-run Fisher
equation (1.3). If we substitute the expression for the error-correction
variable into (2), we get a reduced-form long bond equation as in (3).
[DELTA](1 - [T.sub.t]) B[R.sub.t] = [f.sub.0] + [f.sub.[DELTA]rp]
[DELTA]R[P.sub.t] + [f.sub.[DELTA][pi]] [DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.e] +
[k.summation over (h=1)] [f.sub.1rh][DELTA] [dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] +
[k.summation over (h=1)] [f.sub.2rh][DELTA][dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] +
[f.sub.3r]u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] - [f.sub.ec] (1 - [T.sub.t-1])
B[R.sub.t-1] + [f.sub.ec]rr* + [f.sub.ec][a.sub.r] R [P.sub.t-1] +
[f.sub.ec][a.sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t-1.sup.e] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
[DELTA]BR=(1/(1 - [T.sub.t]))[[[delta].sub.0] +
[f.sub.[DELTA]rp][DELTA]R[P.sub.t] + [f.sub.[DELTA][pi]]
[DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.e] + [k.summation over (h=1)] [f.sub.1rh]
[DELTA][dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [k.summation over (h=1)] [f.sub.2rh]
[DELTA] [dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [f.sub.3r]u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] -
[f.sub.ec](1 - [T.sub.t-1]) B[R.sub.t-1] + [f.sub.ec][a.sub.r] R
[P.sub.t-1] + [f.sub.ec][a.sub.[pi]][[pi].sub.t-1.sup.e]] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (3)
where [[delta].sub.0] = [f.sub.0] + [f.sub.ec]rr*.
Three key features of the short-term bond equation (3) need to be
highlighted. The first is the equation relates changes in the bond rate
to changes and levels of some macro variables, in particular long-term
inflation expectations. As a result, it is possible to recover estimates
of the coefficients of the long-run Fisher equation from the short-run,
reduced-form equation. Thus, if we estimate the unrestricted
reduced-form (3), the after-tax Fisher coefficient [a.sub.[pi]] is
recovered as the estimated coefficient ([f.sub.ec][a.sub.[pi]]) on
lagged inflation expectations ([[pi].sub.t-1.sup.e]) divided by the
absolute value of the estimated coefficient ([f.sub.ec]) on the lagged
bond rate (B[R.sub.t-1]). (17) The second feature to highlight is that
the short-run response of the long bond rate to macroeconomic variables
is likely to vary over time, as the marginal tax rate on interest income
is not constant over time. The third feature to note is that in a steady
state where the private sector's near-term real growth and
inflation expectations are stabilized and where there are no monetary
policy surprises, the long bond rate will converge to the level
determined by the Fisher equation. (18)
Estimating the Bond Rate Equation: Description of the Data
The long bond equation (3) is estimated using quarterly data over
1984Q1 to 2005Q3. The long bond rate (BR) is the nominal yield on
ten-year U.S. Treasury bonds observed in the third month of the quarter.
The measure of monetary policy is the funds rate observed in the third
month of the quarter. The survey forecast of the ten-year-ahead CPI
expected inflation rate ([[pi].sub.t.sup.10]) is used as a proxy for
long-term inflation expectations. The private-sector outlook for the
economy is measured by the Survey of Professional Forecasters'
(SPF) near-term forecasts of real growth and inflation, currently
conducted by the Philadelphia Fed and released by the end of the second
month of the quarter. Inflation uncertainty is measured by the series on
inflation unpredictability, discussed in the previous section. The tax
rates used are from the series on the (average) marginal tax rate on
interest income given in the NBER's TAXSIM model. (19)
In some previous research, the surprise component of the change in
the funds rate has been calculated using data from the fed funds futures
market (Kuttner 2001). I, however, follow the strategy in Romer and
Romer (2004) and construct a different measure of monetary policy
surprise. Romer and Romer develop a measure of policy shocks by removing
the component of changes in the funds rate target that are due to past
and anticipated developments in the economy, and they capture the effect
of anticipated developments on the funds rate target using Greenbook
forecasts of real growth and inflation. So, Romer and Romer's
measure of policy shocks is free of movements anticipated by the Federal
Reserve.
However, what one needs here is a measure of policy shocks that are
free of movements anticipated by bond market participants. Hence, I
purge the funds rate target of anticipated movements by using
private-sector forecasts of real growth and inflation. In particular, I
purge the endogenous and anticipated movements in the funds rate by
running the following regression.
[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [k.summation over (h=1)]
[[alpha].sub.1s][DELTA][dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [k.summation over (h=1)]
[[alpha].sub.2h][dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] +
[[alpha].sub.3][dot.y.sub.t.sup.e] + [[alpha].sub.4][dot.p.sub.t.sup.e]
+ [k.summation over (s=1)] [[alpha].sub.3s][DELTA][y.sub.t-s] +
[k.summation over (s=1)] [[alpha].sub.6s][DELTA][P.sub.t-s] +
[[alpha].sub.7] F F [R.sub.t-1] + u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t], (4)
where FFR is the actual funds rate, y is actual real growth, p is
actual inflation rate, u[DELTA]FFR is the residual, and the rest of the
variables are defined as before. The residual u[DELTA]FFR from the
estimated regression (4) is the measure of the surprise component of
changes in the funds rate target. Since the funds rate target is the
average value of the actual funds rate observed in the third month of
the quarter, the regression (4) provides estimates of changes in the
funds rate anticipated based on the latest information available to bond
market participants.
The funds rate equation (4) is estimated over 1983Q1 to 2005Q3 and
is reproduced below:
[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] = [-.63.(3.4)] + [4.summation over
(h=0)][.03.(0.2)] [DELTA] [dot.y.sub.t+h.sup.e] + [4.summation over
(h=0)] [.63.(2.6)] [DELTA] [dot.P.sub.t+h.sup.e] +
[.19.(4.4)][dot.y.sub.t.sup.e] + [.17.(2.0)][dot.P.sub.t.sup.e] +
[.04.(1.6)][DELTA][y.sub.t-1] + [.10.(2.2)][DELTA][P.sub.t-s] -
[.06.(1.9)] FF[R.sub.t-1] + u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] (5)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] = .44,
where all variables are defined as before. As one can see, changes
in the funds rate target are significantly correlated with changes in
forecasts of GDP inflation, besides being correlated with changes in
lagged inflation and real growth. Changes in the funds rate target are
also correlated with forecast levels of GDP inflation and real growth.
In the empirical work here, the residual from the estimated funds rate
equation (5) is used as a proxy for the surprise component of change in
the funds rate target. (20)
As indicated above, the bond equation (3) allows for the presence
of the tax effect. Hence, the equation is estimated using data
observations on variables that have been pre-multiplied by the
time-varying tax series (1/(1 - [T.sub.t])). (21) The bond rate equation
is estimated by ordinary least squares.
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
This section discusses estimates of the bond equation (3) over
1984Q1 to 2004Q3. In order to examine robustness of results, I also
estimate the bond equation over a shorter sample period, 1984Q1 to
2000Q4, excluding observations pertaining to the most recent sub-period
of low bond yields and increased foreign official inflows into U.S.
Treasury securities.
Estimates of the Bond Rate Equation: With and Without Inflation
Uncertainty
Table 1 contains estimates of the bond rate equation (3) over two
sample periods, 1984Q1 to 2000Q4 and 1984Q1 to 2004Q3. The columns
labeled (1.1) and (1.2) contain estimates of what is denoted hereafter
as the "baseline" bond equation. In the baseline bond
equation, the long-run part contains long-term inflation expectations
and the short-run part includes macroeconomic variables measuring
changes in the outlook for the economy and monetary policy. If we focus
on estimates of the baseline equation for the shorter period of 1984Q1
to 2000Q4, they suggest the following observations. First, short-term
changes in the bond rate are significantly correlated with changes in
long-term inflation expectations and the short-term outlook for real
growth and GDP inflation. The estimated coefficients that appear on
these macroeconomic variables are statistically significant and
correctly signed, indicating that accelerations in long-term expected
inflation and short-term forecasts of real growth and inflation are
associated with a higher bond rate.
Second, the long bond rate is positively correlated with the
surprise component of the change in the funds rate, suggesting that
policy tightening is associated with a rising bond rate. The estimated
coefficient on policy surprises has a positive sign, suggesting that on
average policy surprises have conveyed new information about the state
of the economy.
Third, the estimated after-tax Fisher coefficient [a.sub.[pi]] that
measures the long-term response of the bond rate to inflation
expectations is positive and far above unity. Since the baseline bond
equation is estimated without controlling for the potential influence of
inflation uncertainty on the long bond rate, the estimated Fisher
coefficient may be biased upward, capturing in part the inflation risk
premium embedded in the long bond yield. (22)
Finally, the above-noted three observations about the relationship
between the long bond rate and macroeconomic variables continue to hold
if we consider estimates of the baseline equation over the full sample
period given in the column labeled (1.2).
The columns labeled (2.1) and (2.2) in Table 1 contain estimates of
the baseline equation augmented to include the empirical measure of
short-term inflation uncertainty. Three results need to be highlighted.
The first one is that the long bond rate is positively correlated with
short-term inflation uncertainty, as the estimated coefficient on the
pertinent variable is positive and statistically different from zero.
(23) The estimated coefficient on short-term inflation uncertainty has a
positive sign, suggesting that an increase in uncertainty about
short-term inflation forecasts raises uncertainty about long-term
inflation forecasts and hence may account for the presence of the
inflation risk premium in the bond rate. The second result to note is
that estimates of coefficients on other macroeconomic variables remain
mostly unaffected when the bond equation is estimated controlling for
the influence of inflation uncertainty, with the exception of the
coefficient that appears on the lagged level of inflationary
expectations (compare estimates across columns labeled [1.1] through
[2.2]). The estimated after-tax Fisher coefficient is now close to unity
(the p-value of the null hypothesis that [a.sub.[pi]] = 1 is .90,
leading to the acceptance of the hypothesis), suggesting that failure to
control for the presence of the inflation risk premium yields an unduly
large estimate of the Fisher coefficient. Finally, the results appear
robust across two sample periods considered here. In particular, the
estimated coefficient on short-term inflation uncertainty remains
positive and statistically significant in both sample periods,
suggesting the result that inflation uncertainty matters in determining
the long bond yield is not due to the most recent data.
Testing Stability of the Bond Rate Equation: Disappearance of the
Inflation Risk Premium
Even though estimates of the baseline equation augmented with
inflation uncertainty as reported in Table 1 appear similar across two
sample periods, I now formally test parameter stability of the bond
equation. As discussed earlier, one popular explanation of the current
low level of the bond rate is that bond market participants are now
demanding lower inflation risk premiums than before. Figures 2 and 3
indicate that uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts declined
steeply during the early part of the sample period 1984Q1 to 2004Q3 and
so did variances of both GDP and long-term CPI inflation forecasts.
However, during the early part, both short-term inflation uncertainty
and variances of both GDP and long-term CPI inflation forecasts remained
fairly high, meaning uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts
remained high and long-term inflation expectations remained highly
variable. Since then, short-term inflation uncertainty has declined,
although modestly, and this modest decline in short-term inflation
uncertainty has been accompanied by a significant reduction in the
volatility of inflation expectations. In particular, the standard
deviation of the ten-year-ahead CPI expected inflation has hovered
around zero during the past few years, suggesting that market
participants expect inflation to remain low and stable in the long run
(see Figure 4). These considerations suggest that correlation of the
long bond rate with short-term inflation uncertainty, which is a proxy
for its correlation with uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts, may not be stable over the sample period, 1984Q1 to 2004Q3.
In particular, the coefficient [a.sub.r] that measures the long-term
response of the bond rate to short-term inflation uncertainty may have
declined in recent years, because an increase in short-term inflation
uncertainty may not raise uncertainty about long-term inflation
forecasts as much as it did previously. Hence, I formally test parameter
stability, using the Chow test with the break date treated as unknown
over 1994Q1 to 2002Q4.
Figure 5 plots p-values of a Chow test for stability of different
coefficients in the augmented bond equation as a function of the break
date over 1994Q1 to 2002Q4. Panel A in Figure 5 plots the p-value of a
Chow test where the null hypothesis is that all coefficients of the long
bond rate equation are stable against the alternative that they have
changed at the given date; panel B plots the p-value for stability of
coefficients in the long-run part (coefficients on the constant term,
inflation uncertainty, and long-term inflation expectations); and panel
C plots the p-value for stability of coefficients in the short-run part
(coefficients on changes in anticipated real growth and inflation and
the surprise component of the change in the funds rate). The dashed line
indicates a p-value of .05. In Figure 5, one main observation is that
there is evidence of parameter instability only in the long-run part of
the bond equation, suggesting that coefficients that appear on inflation
uncertainty and long-term inflation expectations have changed, with the
break date being 2001Q4. I assume the after-tax Fisher coefficient
[a.sub.[pi]] has not changed and equals unity, because bond investors
must be compensated for expected inflation even if they expect inflation
to remain low and stable forever. Hence, I capture the break in the
long-run part of the equation by allowing a different coefficient on
short-term inflation uncertainty, because bond market participants may
demand a lower inflation risk premium if they expect inflation to remain
low and stable in the long run. (24)
Columns (3.1) and (3.2) in Table 1 present the estimated augmented
bond equation that allows for the presence of a break in the coefficient
on inflation uncertainty, captured here by including a dummy variable interacting with lagged inflation uncertainty. Column (3.1) contains
unrestricted estimates, whereas column (3.2) contains estimates under
the restrictions that the after-tax Fisher coefficient [a.sub.[pi]] is
unity and that the coefficient on inflation uncertainty is positive
before 2001Q4 but zero thereafter. The p-value for the null hypothesis
that the Fisher coefficient [a.sub.[pi]] equals unity and the risk
coefficient [a.sub.r] is zero is .28, which is large, leading to the
acceptance of the null. As shown, the estimated coefficient on the slope
dummy variable is negative and statistically different from zero,
suggesting that the long bond rate has become less sensitive to
inflation uncertainty in recent years. In fact, estimates are consistent
with the disappearance of the inflation risk premium in the long bond
rate. In the pre-break period of 1984Q1 to 2001Q3, the average inflation
risk premium is estimated to be about .98 of a percentage point,
whereas, in the post-break period, the average risk premium is zero.
(25)
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
An Alternative Test of Lower Inflation Risk Premiums: Testing for a
Shift in the Fisher Coefficient
The key result here is that the long bond rate is no longer
correlated with the empirical measure of short-term inflation
uncertainty, indicating the disappearance of inflation risk premiums
from bond yields. But the aforementioned result is derived using the
bond rate equation in which inflation uncertainty is measured by the MSE
of short-to-medium-term GDP inflation forecasts. I now consider an
alternative test of the hypothesis that inflation risk premiums have
declined, using only the baseline bond equation. The basic idea behind
the test is that if the bond rate equation is estimated without
including a direct empirical measure of inflation uncertainty, then the
estimated after-tax Fisher coefficient is likely to be above unity,
because bond market participants must be compensated for inflation as
well as for inflation-related risk. Hence the hypothesis inflation risk
premiums that have declined can be tested by examining the temporal stability of the after-tax Fisher coefficient. Under the null hypothesis
that inflation risk premiums have disappeared in recent years, the
after-tax Fisher coefficient should now be closer to unity than it has
been before.
For the full sample period 1984Q1 to 2004Q3, the estimated baseline
bond equation is already reported in the column labeled (1.2) in Table
1. As one can see, the estimated after-tax Fisher coefficient is 1.5,
far above unity, reflecting in part the presence of inflation-related
risk premiums. Figure 6, which is similar to Figure 5, re-examines
parameter stability of the baseline equation and plots p-values of a
Chow test for stability of different coefficients as a function of the
break date over 1994Q1 to 2002Q4. As can be seen, there is evidence of
parameter instability not in the short-run part but in the long-run part
of the bond rate equation, suggesting that the coefficient on long-term
expected inflation has changed, with the break date being 2001Q4. Given
such evidence of instability, I re-estimate the bond equation over
1984Q1 to 2004Q3, allowing the presence of a different Fisher
coefficient since 2001Q4 and using a slope dummy. The estimated baseline
bond equation is reported below in (6).
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[DELTA]B[R.sub.t] = [.04.(0.4)] + [.32.(3.4)][[pi].sub.t-1.sup.10]
- [.10.(2.4)]([[pi].sub.t-1.sup.10] * D[U.sub.t-1]) - [.23.(3.5)]
B[R.sub.t-1] + [.29.(2.1)][DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.10] +
[.19.(1.8)][DELTA][dot.y.sub.t.sup.e] +
[.38.(2.1)][DELTA][dot.P.sub.t.sup.e] + [.19.(1.8)]u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t].
(6)
Fisher Coefficient: [a.sub.[pi]] = 1.42(Pre-break) Adjusted
[R.sup.2] = .22 SER = .526 = 1.00(Post-break),
where DU is a dummy variable defined as unity over 2001Q4-2005Q1
and zero otherwise and where other variables are defined as before (see
Table 1). As shown, the estimated after-tax Fisher coefficient is now
unity and is consistent with the reduced magnitude of the inflation risk
premium. Since the bond rate equation is estimated in first difference
form, this reduction in the magnitude of the Fisher coefficient will
result in reducing the level of the long real rate associated with
long-term inflation expectations. The survey forecast of the
ten-year-ahead CPI inflation rate has hovered around a narrow 2 percent
to 2.5 percent range in recent years. Given that the magnitude of the
Fisher coefficient declined by about 40 basis points, the reduction in
after-tax real and nominal bond yields that can be attributed to
reduction in inflation-related risk premiums may range between .8 of a
percentage point to about 1.1 percentage points.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Predicting the Recent Low Level of the Long Bond Rate
I now present evidence that the bond equation that allows for the
presence of a downward shift in the Fisher coefficient as in equation
(6) is consistent with the actual behavior of the long bond rate in
recent years. In particular, I estimate the bond equation (6) over
1984Q1 to 2004Q3 and simulate it dynamically over 1994Q1 to 2004Q3.
Figure 7 charts the simulated values generated using actual values of
right-hand-side explanatory variables. Actual values of the bond rate
and the forecast errors are also charted there. This figure suggests two
observations. First, this equation predicts reasonably well the actual
path of the bond rate over 1994Q1 to 2004Q3. The mean prediction error
is small and equals .20, and the root mean squared error is one-half of
a percentage point. Second, during the past two-and-a-half years, the
ten-year bond rate has hovered around 4 percent, and this behavior of
the bond rate seems consistent with economic fundamentals, once we allow
for a break in the Fisher coefficient.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Robustness: Assessing the Potential Role of Increased Foreign
Purchases of U.S. Treasury Securities
As indicated at the beginning, another popular explanation of the
current low level of long-term interest rates is that increased
purchases of U.S. Treasury securities by foreign individuals and foreign
central banks may have contributed to the recent declines in long bond
rates. Figure 8 charts foreign official net purchases of U.S. securities
(summed over four quarters) as a percentage of lagged U.S. GDP, and this
chart clearly indicates a significant increase in foreign official net
purchases during the past few years.
One preliminary test of the above-noted explanation is to augment the baseline bond equation (4) to include the level and/or change in
foreign official purchases and examine whether the long bond rate is
negatively correlated with foreign official inflows over 1984Q1 to
2004Q3. In order to determine whether results are due to the most recent
large foreign inflows, I also estimate the bond equation over a shorter
sample period, 1984Q1 to 2000Q4.
Table 2 presents estimates of the augmented baseline bond equations
over two sample periods. The columns labeled (4.1) and (4.2) present
estimates of the baseline equation augmented to include foreign official
capital inflows, whereas the columns labeled (5.1) and (5.2) contain
estimates of the baseline equation augmented to include both foreign
inflows and the empirical measure of inflation uncertainty. If we focus
on estimates from the baseline equation with foreign inflows over the
shorter sample period 1984Q1 to 2000Q4, they suggest the long bond rate
is not significantly correlated with foreign official inflows. The
estimated coefficients that appear on empirical measures of foreign
inflows are not statistically different from zero (the p-value for the
null hypothesis--coefficients on the level and change in foreign
official inflows are zero--is .45, which is large and leads to the
acceptance of the null hypothesis). The result that the long bond rate
is not correlated with foreign capital inflows continues to hold if we
augment the baseline equation to include both capital inflows and the
empirical measure of inflation uncertainty. As can be seen, the
estimated coefficient on foreign official inflows remains statistically
insignificant, whereas the estimated coefficient on inflation
uncertainty is correctly signed and statistically significant (compare
coefficients across columns labeled [4.1] and [5.1] in Table 2).
If we consider estimates of the augmented baseline equations over
the full sample period that spans the recent period of large foreign
inflows, the results are mixed. The estimated coefficient that appears
on the level of foreign inflows is still not statistically different
from zero. However, the estimated coefficient that appears on the
variable measuring change in foreign inflows turns negative and is
marginally significant, suggesting part of the decline observed in the
long bond rate in recent years may be due to increased foreign purchases
(see the coefficient on foreign capital inflows in columns labeled [4.2]
and [5.2] in Table 2). But these results also imply that negative
correlation between changes in the long bond rate and changes in foreign
official purchases found in the full sample period are mainly attributed
to the most recent period and hence are not indicative of the presence
of a consistent relation between bond yields and increased foreign
purchases of U.S. Treasury securities. Thus, the hypothesis that the
current low level of the long bond rate is in part due to increased
foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities must be
considered tentative. (26)
4. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
One suggested explanation of the current low level of the long bond
rate is that inflation risk premiums have declined. This explanation
posits that, as a result of the good inflation performance of the U.S.
economy and increased confidence that the Federal Reserve will keep
inflation low and stable, investors are now demanding lower inflation
risk premiums than before. This lowering of inflation risk premiums is
reflected in lower real and nominal yields on bonds. This article
develops an empirical test of the aforementioned explanation.
Since we do not have a direct empirical measure of uncertainty
about long-term inflation forecasts, the article develops an empirical
proxy for uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts, assuming
uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts is positively correlated
with uncertainty about short-term ones. Another assumption is that if
inflation had been harder to forecast in the past, it would raise the
variance of current forecasts of expected future inflation rates,
leading to increased uncertainty about future expected inflation. Given
these basic assumptions, the article examines the MSE of
short-to-medium-term inflation forecasts, using survey data on
private-sector GDP inflation expectations. In particular, the article
creates a time series on the MSE of short-term inflation forecasts,
using rolling three-year windows over 1984Q1 to 2004Q3. This time series
can be viewed as measuring uncertainty about short-term inflation
forecasts and hence may provide information on uncertainty about
long-term inflation forecasts. The time series measuring uncertainty
about short-term inflation forecasts has a downward trend that appears
to be consistent with the downward trend in mean and variance of
forecast inflation, suggesting inflation uncertainty declined over this
period because inflation both steadily declined and became more
predictable.
The results indicate the long bond rate is positively correlated
with the empirical measure of short-term inflation uncertainty over the
full sample period 1984Q1 to 2004Q3, which suggests that an increase in
uncertainty about short-to-medium-term inflation forecasts raises
uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts and hence may account
for the presence of the inflation risk premium in the bond rate.
However, the results also indicate that the estimated coefficient that
measures the response of the long bond rate to short-term inflation
uncertainty has declined since 2001Q4, implying that an increase in
uncertainty about short-term inflation forecasts has not raised
uncertainty about long-term inflation forecasts as much as it did
previously. In fact, the results are consistent with the hypothesis that
the inflation risk premium embedded in the long bond rate has
disappeared, thereby explaining the current low level of the long bond
rate.
Another competing explanation of the recent low level of the long
bond rate is increased purchases of U.S. Treasury securities by foreign
central banks, which may have contributed to reducing nominal yields on
long-term bonds. The empirical work here indicates the long bond rate is
in fact negatively correlated with foreign capital inflows over the full
sample period. However, this negative correlation between the long bond
rate and foreign official inflows found in the data is marginally
significant and fragile, arising mainly as a result of most recent
capital inflows and hence may not be indicative of the presence of a
consistent relation between foreign capital inflows and bond yields.
Hence, the second hypothesis must be considered tentative. Together,
these results by far favor the explanation that attributes the recent
low level of the long bond rate mostly to the reduction in inflation
uncertainty.
REFERENCES
Ang, Andrew, Geert Bekaert, and Min Wei. 2006. "Do Macro
Variables, Asset Markets, or Surveys Forecast Inflation Better?"
Finance and Economic Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board,
Washington, D.C.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2003. "A Perspective on Inflation
Targeting." Remarks at the Annual Washington Policy Conference of
the National Association of Business Economists, Washington, D.C.
______. 2004. "Fedspeak." Remarks at the Meetings of the
American Economic Association, San Diego, California.
______. 2006. "Testimony of Chairman Ben S. Bernanke."
Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress.
Clouse, Jim. 2004. "Reading the Minds of Investors: An
Empirical Term Structure Model for Policy Analysis." Finance and
Economic Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.
Diebold, Francis X., Monika Piazzesi, and Glen D. Rudebusch. 2005.
"Modeling Bond Yields in Finance and Macroeconomics." American
Economic Review 95 (2): 415-20.
Dudley, Bill. 2006. "Low Bond Risk Premia: The Collapse of
Inflation Volatility." U.S. Economics Analyst, U.S. Economic
Research Group, Goldman Sachs (January).
Ellingsen, Tore, and Ulf Soderstrom. 2001. "Monetary Policy
and Market Interest Rates." American Economic Review 91 (5):
1594-1607.
______. 2004. "Why Are Long Rates Sensitive to Monetary
Policy?" Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper 160.
Feenberg, Daniel, and Elisabeth Coutts. 1993. "An Introduction
to the TAXSIM Model." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 12
(1): 189-94.
Greenspan, Alan. 2005. "Remarks by Chairman Alan
Greenspan." Central Bank Panel Discussion, International Monetary
Conference, Beijing, People's Republic of China. June 6.
Gurkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack, and Eric T. Swanson. 2005.
"Do Actions Speak Louder than Words? The Response of Asset Prices
to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements." International Journal
of Central Banking (May): 55-93.
Hordahl, Peter, Oreste Tristani, and David Vestin. 2006. "A
Joint Econometric Model of Macroeconomic and Term-Structure
Dynamics." Journal of Econometrics 131 (1-2): 405-44.
Kim, Don H., and Jonathan H. Wright. 2005. "An Arbitrage-Free
Three-Factor Term Structure Model and the Recent Behavior of Long-Term
Yields and Distant-Horizon Forward Rates." Finance and Economics
Discussion Series Paper No. 33.
Kuttner, Kenneth N. 2001. "Monetary Policy Surprises and
Interest Rates: Evidence from the Fed Funds Futures Market."
Journal of Monetary Economics 47: 523-44.
Mehra, Yash. 1984. "The Tax Effect, and the Recent Behavior of
the After-tax Real Rate: Is it Too High?" Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Review 70 (4): 8-20.
______. 1994. "An Error-Correction Model of the Long-term Bond
Rate." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 80 (4):
49-67.
Romer, Christina and David Romer. 2004. "A New Measure of
Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications." A paper presented at
Economic Fluctuations and Growth Research Meeting, NBER, July 17.
Tanzi, Vito. 1980. "Inflationary Expectations, Economic
Activity, Taxes, and Interest Rates." American Economic Review
(March): 12-21.
Tulip, Peter. 2005. "Has Output Become More Predictable?
Changes in Greenbook Forecast Accuracy." Finance and Economic
Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.
Warnock, Francis E., and Veronica Cacdac Warnock. 2005.
"International Capital Flows and U.S. Interest Rates." Finance
and Economic Discussion Series Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.
Wu, Tao. 2005. "The Long-Term Interest Rate Conundrum: Not
Unraveled Yet?" Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic
Letter (April).
The author thanks Juan Carlos Hatchondo, Hubert Janicki, Roy Webb,
and John Weinberg for helpful comments. The views expressed are those of
the author and do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) As discussed fully later, the reduced-form long bond equation
used to generate the predicted values relate the long bond rate to
long-term inflation expectations, near-term forecasts of real growth and
inflation, and the surprise component of change in the fed funds rate
target, denoted here as the baseline bond rate equation. This equation
is estimated over 1984Q1 to 2004Q3 and simulated dynamically over 1994Q1
to 2005Q1, conditional on actual values of macroeconomic determinants
and assuming the Fisher coefficient is unity. The predicted values
charted in Figure 1 are the simulated values.
(2) See, for example, Warnock and Warnock (2005). Chairman Bernanke
(2006) in his recent testimony to the U.S. Congress also notes that
long-term interest rates have remained relatively low given recent
strong real growth and rising short-term interest rates.
(3) Some other hypotheses that have surfaced in the financial press
have not been considered serious enough to warrant much attention. For
example, one hypothesis involves the behavior of pension funds. This
hypothesis attributes the recent decline in the long bond rate to
increased demand for longer-term bond portfolios by pension funds and
insurance companies that are needed to replenish their underfunded retirement plans. However, these funding shortfalls are not considered
large enough to be able to explain the recent behavior of long-term
interest rates. Another hypothesis posits that the current low level of
the long bond rate may be signaling economic weakness. Most reduced-form
interest rate models usually control for the influence of future real
growth on current bond yields, yet those models still cannot account for
the recent low level of the long bond rate.
(4) See, for example, Greenspan (2005), Kim and Wright (2005),
Dudley (2006), and Bernanke (2006). Although several analysts attribute
the low level of the long bond rate to lower bond risk premiums, they
differ with respect to reasons for the collapse in risk premiums.
Chairman Greenspan has focused on increased globalization and
integration of financial markets as sources of the favorable inflation
performance in many countries including the United States, whereas
others (for example, Dudley 2006) attribute the favorable inflation
performance to monetary policy. In contrast, Kim and Wright have
emphasized the potential role of increased demand for U.S. Treasury
securities relative to supply. The empirical work here focuses on
domestic factors that might be at the source of the favorable inflation
performance.
(5) See, for example, Wu (2005) and Warnock and Warnock (2005).
Chairman Bernanke (2006) has focused instead on increased capital
inflows arising as a result of an excess of desired global savings over
the quantity of global investment opportunities that pay historically
normal returns. The examination of the global savings glut hypothesis is
beyond the scope of this article.
(6) See, for example, the evidence in Wu (2005) and Warnock and
Warnock (2005).
(7) Tulip (2005) uses this approach to investigate whether output
has become predictable, using Greenbook forecasts.
(8) Ideally, one needs to examine the MSE of ten-year-ahead
Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation forecasts. However, for the sample
period 1984 to 2005Q3 studied here, it is not possible to generate
enough observations on the forecast error. Hence, I focus on the MSE of
short-term GDP inflation forecasts, assuming reduction in inflation
uncertainty at short-term forecast horizons will lead to reduction in
uncertainty at the long-term forecast horizon.
(9) Ang, Bekaert, and Wei (2006).
(10) I get qualitatively similar results using somewhat longer
four-year rolling windows.
(11) Because I use lead data in generating forecast errors, the
sample period ends in 2004Q3.
(12) The argument that, over the sample period 1984Q1 to 2005Q3,
the series measuring the variance of inflation does not depict a
downward trend is not inconsistent with the evidence in previous
research that volatility of inflation (measured by the variance of
inflation) observed in the sample period since 1984 has been low
relative to the one observed in the period before.
(13) As noted in Tulip (2005), the variance of actual future
inflation is algebraically related to MSE as shown below.
[1/n] [12.summation over (n=1)] ([[pi].sub.t+4] -
[bar.[pi]])[.sup.2] = [1/n] [12.summation over (n=1)]
([e.sub.t+4])[.sup.2] + [1/n] [12.summation over (n=1)] ([f.sub.t+4] -
[bar.[pi]])[.sup.2] + [2/n] [12.summation over (n=1)]([f.sub.t+4] -
[bar.[pi]])[e.sub.t+4], Variance = MSE + Predicted Variation +
Covariance
where [[pi].sub.t+4] is actual four-quarter-ahead inflation, f is
the survey forecast, e is the forecast error, and [bar.[pi]] is the
sample mean. Hence, in the top panel, the distance between the line
plotting variance and the line plotting MSE equals the sum of the last
two terms. If we ignore the last term, the second term on the right-hand
side of the equation above measures variance of the predictable
component of inflation. The bottom panel in Figure 3 has charted the
second term.
(14) Figure 4 indicates that, for most of the 1990s, short-term
inflation uncertainty remained low and stable, while long-term inflation
expectations were stabilized. In order to uncover the relationship
between the long bond rate and inflation uncertainty, one needs a period
during which the potential explanatory variables, including the
empirical measure of short-term inflation uncertainty, have varied
considerably, as was the case during the early part of the sample
period.
(15) Tanzi (1980).
(16) The reduced-form empirical bond rate equation estimated here
is in spirit based on the recent empirical work that links bond yield
dynamics to macroeconomic variables. To explain it further, as in
finance literature, bond yields are modeled as risk-adjusted averages of
expected future short rates. Expectations of future short rates,
however, depend in part on expectations of future macroeconomic
variables, which are generated using either a structural or a VAR model
of the economy. This methodology thus relates bond yield dynamics to
macroeconomic variables. See Clouse (2004) and Hordahl, Tristani, and
Vestin (2006) for an empirical illustration of this joint econometric modeling of macroeconomic and term-structure dynamics and Diebold,
Piazzesi, and Rudebusch (2005) for a summary of this literature.
(17) Estimate of the constant term in the long Fisher equation is
not identified.
(18) To be specific, consider a steady state in which coefficients
in (3) assume values given below: [f.sub.[DELTA]rp] =
[f.sub.[DELTA][pi]] = [f.sub.1rs] = [f.sub.2rs] = [f.sub.3r] =
[a.sub.rp] = 0, [f.sub.ec] = 1, then the long bond rate equals the
risk-free long expected real rate and expected inflation.
(19) See Feenberg and Coutts (1993) for more details. The tax
series used is the one that measures the federal marginal tax rates on
interest income.
(20) The first four estimated autocorrelation coefficients of the
monetary policy surprise series are .20, .15, .06, and .02, which are
insignificantly different from zero, suggesting that time series in fact
do measure policy surprises.
(21) See Tanzi (1980) and Mehra (1984) for details.
(22) The sign of bias in the estimated Fisher coefficient is
positive because inflation risk, which is omitted from the regression,
is likely to be positively correlated with the level of expected
inflation; namely, inflation uncertainty is large if expected inflation
is high and variable.
(23) The preliminary empirical work indicated that the long bond
rate is positively correlated with the lagged level of the empirical
measure of inflation uncertainty. First differences of this variable do
not enter the bond equation. Together these results imply that inflation
uncertainty enters the long-run part of the bond equation.
(24) The alternative--that investors would not want to be
compensated for expected inflation--is not reasonable.
(25) The magnitude of the inflation-related risk premium at time t
is simply the long-term coefficient on inflation uncertainty times
period t value of the time series measuring inflation uncertainty. In
the pre-break period, the long-term coefficient on inflation uncertainty
is .35 and the sample mean of the MSE of the four-quarter-ahead
inflation forecast is 2.8 percentage points, suggesting that the average
inflation risk premium over 1984Q1 to 2001Q4 is about 98 basis points.
In the post-break period, however, the long-term coefficient on
inflation uncertainty is not different from zero, suggesting that the
inflation risk premium has disappeared.
(26) The evidence in previous research on the role of foreign
official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in explaining the current
low level of the long bond rate is also mixed. Wu (2005) reports
evidence indicating the long bond rate is not at all correlated with
foreign official purchases. Warnock and Warnock (2005) report mixed
evidence; they also find the estimated coefficient on the foreign
official capital inflows in their reduced-form interest rate equation is
not statistically different from zero over the estimation period that
excludes the surge in inflows of the past few years.
Table 1 Estimates of the Bond Rate Equation
Dependent Variable: [DELTA]B[R.sub.t]
Sample Period Ending in
Independent (1.1) (1.2) (2.1)
Variables 2000Q4 2004Q3 2000Q4
const.
B[R.sub.t-1] -.18 (2.6) -.21 (3.2) -.24 (3.4)
[[pi].sub.t-1.sup.10] .28 (2.6) .32 (3.0) .23 (2.3)
R[P.sub.t-1] .09 (2.4)
DU * R[P.sub.t-1]
[DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.10] .28 (1.9) .30 (2.1) .23 (1.6)
[DELTA][y.sub.t+s.sup.e] .24 (1.8) .18 (1.6) .25 (1.9)
[DELTA][P.sub.t+s.sup.e] .45 (2.3) .41 (2.2) .48 (2.5)
u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] .28 (2.4) .19 (1.8) .27 (2.4)
[a.sub.[pi]] 1.57 1.54 1.0
[a.sub.r] .39
[R.sup.2] .25 .20 .31
SER .530 .537 .509
Dependent Variable: [DELTA]B[R.sub.t]
Sample Period Ending in
Independent (2.2) (3.1) (3.2)
Variables 2004Q3 2004Q3 2004Q3
const.
B[R.sub.t-1] -.25 (3.8) -.30 (4.4) -.27 (4.3)
[[pi].sub.t-1.sup.10] .26 (2.5) .27 (2.6) .27 (4.3)
R[P.sub.t-1] .09 (2.3) .10 (2.8) .10 (3.5)
DU * R[P.sub.t-1] -.34 (2.2) .10 (3.5)
[DELTA][[pi].sub.t.sup.10] .24 (1.7) .27 (1.7) .24 (1.8)
[DELTA][y.sub.t+s.sup.e] .18 (1.7) .22 (2.1) .20 (1.9)
[DELTA][P.sub.t+s.sup.e] .43 (2.4) .45 (2.5) .44 (2.5)
u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] .20 (2.0) .16 (1.6) .19 (1.9)
[a.sub.[pi]] 1.0 .92 1.0
[a.sub.r] .35 .35; 0.0 (a)
[R.sup.2] .25 .28 .28
SER .522 .509 .510
Notes: The reported coefficients (with t-values in parenthesis) are from
the bond rate equation (4) of the text estimated over the sample period
that begins in 1984Q1 but ends as indicated above. BR is the ten-year
bond rate, [[pi].sup.10] is the ten-year-ahead survey inflation
forecast, RP is an inflation risk variable measured as the MSE of
forecast errors, [DELTA][y.sub.t+s.sup.e] is the average of zero-to-
four-quarter-ahead (survey) real growth forecasts,
[DELTA][dot.P.sub.t+s.sup.e] is the average of zero-to-four-quarter-
ahead (survey) GDP inflation forecasts, u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] is the
surprise component of change in the funds rate, DU is a dummy variable
defined as unity over 2001Q4 to 2005Q3 and zero otherwise, [R.sup.2] is
adjusted-R squared, and SER is the standard error of estimate.
[a.sub.[pi]] is the long-term after-tax coefficient on ten-year expected
inflation (Fisher coefficient) and [a.sub.r] is the long-term
coefficient on the inflation-related risk variable. All equations are
estimated by ordinary least squares, using time series data pre-
multiplied by (1/(1-T a[x.sub.t])), where T a[x.sub.t] is the marginal
tax rate on interest income.
a: post-break [a.sub.r]
Table 2 Estimates of the Bond Rate Equation, Including Foreign Official
Holdings of U.S. Treasury Securities
Dependent Variable: [DELTA]B[R.sub.t]
Sample Period Ending in
Independent (4.1) (4.2) (5.1) (5.2)
Variables 2000Q4 2004Q3 2000Q4 2004Q3
const.
B[R.sub.t-1] -.19 (2.6) -.22 (3.4) -.25 (3.3) -.27 (3.9)
[[pi].sub.t-1.sup.10] .29 (2.5) .34 (3.1) .22 (1.9) .28 (2.5)
R[P.sub.t-1] .10 (2.6) .09 (2.4)
r[k.sub.t-1] .03 (0.2) -.01 (0.1) .10 (0.8) .02 (0.2)
[DELTA]r[k.sub.t] -.20 (1.0) -.28 (1.6)* -.18 (0.9) -.30 (1.8)*
[DELTA] .30 (2.0) .33 (2.2) .24 (1.7) .28 (1.9)
[[pi].sub.t.sup.10]
[DELTA] .20 (1.5) .14 (1.3) .20 (1.6) .15 (1.4)
[y.sub.t+s.sup.e]
[DELTA] .42 (2.0) .37 (1.9) .41 (2.1) .38 (2.1)
[P.sub.t+s.sup.e]
u[DELTA]FF[R.sub.t] .26 (2.2) .17 (1.6) .24 (2.1) .18 (1.7)
[a.sub.[pi]] 1.53 1.50 .90 1.0
[a.sub.r] .41 .35
[R.sup.2] .25 .21 .31 .26
SER .533 .535 .508 .517
Notes: rk is foreign official holdings of U.S. Treasury securities,
expressed as a proportion of lagged GDP; other variables are defined as
in Table 1. See notes in Table 1.
* significant at the .10 level.