The productivity of nations.
Duarte, Margarida ; Restuccia, Diego
In this article, we document observations on labor productivity
across countries over time. Using data from Heston, Summers, and Aten
(2002) on gross domestic product (GDP) per worker--our measure of labor
productivity--we emphasize three main facts about the distribution of
labor productivity across countries between 1960 and 1996. (1) First,
there is substantial dispersion in labor productivity across countries.
For instance, in 1960 an average worker in the richest 5 percent of
countries in the world produces about 35 times more output than an
average worker in the poorest 5 percent of countries in the world.
Second, disparity in labor productivity has increased over time. By
1996, the labor productivity ratio between the richest and poorest
countries increased to approximately 46. This increase in disparity is
explained by a substantial deterioration in labor productivity in the
poorest countries of the world relative to that of the United States. We
report several statistics of dispersion indicating that labor
productivity differences between the richest and poorest countries have
increased since the mid-1980s. This characterization of increased
dispersion in labor productivity contrasts with a relative stability
documented in previous studies, in which the coverage period ended in
1985.
Third, there is substantial mobility of individual countries in the
distribution of labor productivity over time. For instance, labor
productivity in Hong Kong relative to that in the United States rose
from 19 percent in 1960 to 94 percent in 1996--an increase of a factor
of almost 5 during the period--while relative labor productivity in
Venezuela declined from 94 percent in 1964 to 36 percent in 1996--a more
than twofold drop in relative productivity. We also document a number of
individual episodes of growth and decline. Accounting for these specific
labor productivity paths may prove useful not only from a policy
perspective, but also in testing and improving existing theories of
productivity levels or in the development of alternative theories.
This article relates to a large literature on the world
distribution of income that includes Kaldor (1961), Kuznets (1966),
Maddison (1995, 2001), Parente and Prescott (1993), Chari, Kehoe, and
McGrattan (1996), Jones (1997), among many others. We contribute to this
literature by adding the period between 1985 and 1996 to the analysis.
In addition, we focus on output per worker as opposed to output per
capita since output per worker relates more directly to theories of
labor productivity. The difference between the two measures is given by
the employment-to-population ratio. While there are substantial
differences in these ratios across countries, the differences are not
systematically related to development. Therefore, our summary statistics
characterizing output per worker over time are similar to statistics
calculated using output per capita. However, there are substantial
changes in employment-to-population ratios for individual countries over
time, and these changes are not systematically related to development or
growth in relative productivity. Therefore, for an individual country,
changes in output per capita can severely overstate or understate
changes in labor productivity.
There are two additional differences between this article and the
previous literature. First, we characterize disparity and mobility using
trended data. That is, we use the Hodrick-Prescott filter to abstract
from business-cycle fluctuations in the data. Second, we seek to
systematically identify remarkable episodes of growth (positive or
negative) in the data at some point during the 1960-1996 period. In the
literature, countries facing these episodes are typically referred to as
miracles and disasters. We document 13 miracle and 17 disaster episodes
in our data set. Among the miracle episodes, we report the movement of
labor productivity in Botswana relative to that in the United States
from 7 percent to 30 percent in 26 years; in Hong Kong, from 19 percent
to 94 percent in 36 years; and in China, from 4 percent to 8 percent in
18 years. We also document the recent, but not yet as long, growth
episodes of Chile, Ireland, and India, which may become miracle episodes
within the next two decades.
Furthermore, we also systematically document depression episodes in
our panel data. Ever since the study of the Great Depression in the
United States by Cole and Ohanian (1999), there has been substantial
interest in studying depression episodes (defined broadly as periods of
lower-than-usual relative productivity). (2) We follow this literature
in characterizing depression episodes by using the raw data on output
per worker relative to a trend growth of 2 percent per year. Even in our
relatively small sample period, we find that depressions are quite
common, both among rich and poor countries. We report 29 depression
episodes in Section 4.
Our study also relates to a broad literature on models that seek to
explain development facts such as those of disparity and mobility
discussed above. For excellent surveys of this literature see, for
instance, Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) and Caselli (2005). Our
study complements this literature by expanding and updating the set of
facts that theories of development should be able to explain.
This article is organized as follows. In the next section, we
describe in detail the data we use for the analysis. Section 2 documents
the main facts about dispersion and mobility in the distribution of
labor productivity. In Section 3, we discuss the remarkable episodes of
growth during the period, namely miracle and disaster episodes, and in
Section 4, we document the episodes of depressions. Section 5 discusses
our main findings relative to those using instead output per hour, an
alternative sample of countries, and output per capita. We conclude in
Section 6.
1. DATA
We focus on output per worker as our measure of labor productivity.
We use annual data on PPP-adjusted GDP per worker in chained 1996 prices
obtained from Heston et al. (2002), also known as the Penn World Table
V6.1 (PWT6.1). We choose the PWT6.1 for our analysis because it is the
most comprehensive source of comparable measures of output per worker
across countries.
We focus on output per worker in order to emphasize the connection
of the data with research on productivity differences across countries.
Although output per hour is a more complete measure of labor
productivity, we abstract from differences in hours per worker across
countries due to the lack of systematic data for a large number of
countries over the entire period of our study. However, in Section 5, we
use the available data on hours per worker to calculate output per hour
and discuss our findings relative to this more complete measure of labor
productivity. Measures of output per capita are appropriate when the
focus is on wealth differences across countries. (3) We also discuss our
findings relative to the use of output per capita in Section 5.
Our data set consists of annual observations for 99 countries from
1960 to 1996. (4) The countries in our data set satisfy two
restrictions. First, the total population of each country was at or
above 1 million people in 1996. Second, data was available at each date
from 1960 to 1996. We make this second restriction in order for the
sample of countries to be constant throughout the period of analysis.
Data is available for 48 countries from 1950 to 2000. However, countries
without observations between 1950 and 1960 and between 1996 and 2000
tend to be poorer countries. Thus, the smaller sample from 1950 to 2000
is less representative of the world distribution of output per worker
than our sample with 99 countries from 1960 to 1996.
In documenting observations about dispersion, mobility, and
miracles and disasters, we abstract from business-cycle fluctuations and
trend the data using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. (5) Abstracting from
business-cycle fluctuations when reporting development facts is not
innocuous. As we document in Section 4, countries undergo episodes of
substantial growth and decline that are not entirely related to their
development process. To illustrate the cycles in the annual data, we
report in Figure 1 the raw data on output per worker and the trended
data for four countries: the United States, Argentina, Romania, and
Switzerland. As is true with many other countries in our panel data,
these countries have undergone relatively short-lived variations in
their output per worker at different points in time. Our documentation
of the development facts abstracts from these fluctuations.
For the most part, we report statistics on output per worker
relative to that of the United States. Our view is that the United
States is a rich, stable, and diverse country. For most of the period of
analysis, the United States had the highest labor productivity.
Moreover, in the post-war period, (trended) labor productivity grew at
roughly 2 percent per year. Therefore, the United States represents a
good benchmark against which to measure potential gains in labor
productivity in all countries.
2. LABOR PRODUCTIVITY ACROSS COUNTRIES
We emphasize three facts about the distribution of labor
productivity across countries. First, there is a large disparity in
output per worker across countries. Second, there is a substantial
increase in disparity over time. Third, there are substantial movements
of individual countries in the world distribution of productivity. In
the remainder of this section we characterize these facts in detail.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Disparity
A remarkable fact of modern development data is the large disparity
in productivity among countries. Here we focus on different measures of
disparity and their evolution between 1960 and 1996.
We start by focusing on the five richest and five poorest countries
in our sample. We compute the ratio of average output per worker for the
five richest and five poorest countries for each year from 1960 to 1996,
illustrated in Figure 2. This ratio varies between 35 and 46 over the
period of analysis. That is, the average worker in the richest countries
produces between 35 and 46 times more output than the average worker in
the poorest countries. These are remarkable differences in labor
productivity.
This measure of disparity in productivity across countries has been
roughly constant from 1960, at 35, until the mid-1980s. The ratio
declined slightly around 1980 but has increased steadily since then to a
factor of 46 in 1996. (6) This increase in dispersion runs contrary to
the established view in the development literature that dispersion in
the world distribution of productivity has been rather constant over
time (see, for instance, Parente and Prescott 1993; Chari, Kehoe, and
McGrattan 1996). The reason for this view is that until about 1985 (the
end date in most previous studies), the productivity ratio of the
richest to the poorest countries was roughly constant. See Figure 2
where the line drawn at 1985 emphasizes the connection with the earlier
literature.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In Figure 3 we report the relative productivity of the five poorest
and five richest countries between 1960 and 1996, each normalized to 100
in 1960. (7) This figure shows that the increase in dispersion in
relative productivity between the richest and poorest countries reported
in Figure 2 is mostly due to the decline in relative productivity of the
five poorest countries. Between 1960 and 1996, relative productivity in
the richest countries fell by about 10 percent, while relative
productivity in the poorest countries fell by about 30 percent. It is of
interest to note that even the five richest countries declined in
productivity relative to that in the United States. Duarte and Restuccia
(2006) show that the decline in productivity in the richest countries
relative to that in the United States is accounted for by the movement
of employment to the service sector (associated with the process of
structural transformation) and the low labor productivity in this sector
relative to that in the United States.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
We now focus on the entire distribution of labor productivity
across countries. Table 1 reports the average relative output per worker
of countries at each decile of the distribution of countries and for a
selected number of years. The first decile includes the 10 percent of
countries at the bottom of the distribution of output per worker, while
the tenth decile includes the 10 percent of countries at the top of the
distribution of output per worker. The last two rows report the ratio of
the tenth decile to the first and the ratio of the ninth decile to the
second.
In 1960, the poorest 10 percent of countries had an average labor
productivity of around 3 percent of that of the United States, while the
richest 10 percent of countries had an average productivity of 90
percent of that of the United States, yielding a ratio of 26 between the
richest 10 percent to the poorest 10 percent of countries. In turn, for
the same year, the ratio of productivity for countries in the ninth
decile to the second decile is a factor of almost 10. Note that these
ratios increase substantially during our period of analysis, but
especially do so after 1980. Note also that, over time, countries in the
sixth, seventh, eighth, and ninth deciles improved their average
relative productivity (particularly those in the eighth and ninth
deciles) while countries in the bottom five deciles and in the top
decile had either fallen further behind or stagnated relative to that of
the United States. These patterns indicate that increasing dispersion in
relative labor productivity is occurring not only at the extremes of the
distribution but also in the middle.
Disparity in relative productivity between rich and poor countries
is apparent even for broader groups of countries. Table 2 reports the
average relative output per worker by quintile. Even when the 20 richest
and 20 poorest countries are averaged, dispersion in labor productivity
is large (a ratio of 15.8 between these two sets of countries in 1960
and 26.1 in 1996), and the poorest countries have lost ground in
productivity relative to the richest countries over time (from 4.7
percent of the United States in 1960 to 3.1 percent in 1996).
The disparity facts we have documented are supported by other
summary statistics of dispersion. The Gini coefficient, for instance, is
a commonly used measure of inequality. We compute the Gini coefficient
for each year in our sample and we find that this statistic confirms our
earlier findings. (8) The Gini coefficient was roughly constant (at
about 0.49) until the early 1980s and it has increased since then (to
about 0.52 in 1996).
Changes in the dispersion of relative labor productivity over time
across countries suggest movements of individual countries in the
distribution of productivity across countries over time. To document
these changes, we report the histogram of the distribution of relative
output per worker across countries at different points in time in Figure
4. The most noticeable change in the distribution from 1965 to 1995 is
the movement of mass from the middle of the distribution to the right
and to the left, creating what the literature calls "twin
peaks" in the world distribution of relative output per worker. (9)
Therefore, this statistic also captures an increase in the dispersion of
relative productivity across countries.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
We have presented statistics that capture an increase in the
dispersion of labor productivity across countries, especially after the
mid-1980s. This increase is relevant for theories of development
because, in these theories, relative productivity levels are related to
policies and institutional factors at the country level. We emphasize,
however, that the observed increase in disparity in productivity does
not necessarily imply an increase in income inequality in the world.
There are at least three reasons. First, our disparity statistics do not
adjust for changes in the employment-to-population ratios over time and
in the size of population across countries. In particular, improvements
in the standard of living in China and India alone (as we document later
in this article) imply improvements in the standard of living for a
sizeable portion of the population in the world (about 35 percent). (10)
Second, our disparity statistics do not adjust for inequality within
countries. Sala-i-Martin (2006) documents a reduction in global
inequality in income per capita when including within-country inequality
in the analysis. Third, our dispersion statistics do not capture
improvements in broader notions of quantity and quality of life, such as
improvements in life expectancy. (11)
In this section, we have documented that disparity in relative
productivity across countries is large and that it has increased over
the period of analysis. Below, we relate disparity in relative
productivity with the geographical location of countries. We report
substantial differences in labor productivity across regions in the
world as well as substantial movements in these regional differences
over time.
Table 3 reports averages of labor productivity by region for
selected years. For instance, in 1960 the average labor productivity of
the Asian countries in our data set was only 14 percent of that in the
United States (about the same level of relative labor productivity in
Africa) and 41 percent of that in Latin America. By 1996, Asia improved
its position relative to that of the United States to 34 percent,
surpassing both Latin America and Africa. On average, labor productivity
in Africa did not improve relative to that in the United States (at
roughly 12 percent). However, as we document below, this is a result of
disparate experiences within Africa, with some countries declining in
labor productivity both in absolute levels and relative to that of the
United States, as well as with countries growing faster than the United
States. In contrast, Latin America declined relative to the United
States, from about 34 percent in 1960 to 25 percent in 1996. In the case
of Latin America, the common path of relative labor productivity was one
of decline, perhaps with the only exception being Chile, which started
rapidly catching up to the United States in 1990. Countries in Western
Europe had a relative productivity of 62 percent in 1960, experienced a
period of relative fast gain to 77 percent in 1980, but have since
stagnated relative to the United States to average levels of 75 percent.
Canada, as well as countries in Oceania, had high relative labor
productivity in 1960 but slowly declined relative to the United States.
Mobility
Associated with changes in the dispersion of relative labor
productivity over time across countries is a substantial mobility of
individual countries in the distribution of relative productivity over
time. In the remainder of this section, we provide different
characterizations of mobility in our data set. In the next two sections,
we focus on individual country experiences.
To start, we characterize mobility in our data through two mobility
matrices. The matrix in Table 4 reports the frequency of movements,
defined over a period of 20 years, for relative productivity in our
sample. We consider 5 bins for relative productivity, which imply a
distribution of countries in 1960 that is roughly uniform. For each year
since 1960, we ask how the position in relative productivity for a
particular country changed in 20 years. Then we average all the
experiences across countries and over time (all the 20-year windows from
1960 to 1996) in Table 4. For instance, the first element of this
matrix, 0.86, is the average frequency with which countries with
relative productivity between zero and 0.075 in a given year also have
relative productivity between zero and 0.075 20 years later.
Mobility in Table 4 (as measured by the off-diagonal elements of
the matrix) is higher in the middle of the relative productivity
distribution than in its extremes. The diagonal elements of this matrix
are substantially higher for the poorest countries (with relative
productivity between zero and 0.075) and the richest countries (with
relative productivity between 0.6 and 1.2), compared to diagonal
elements for the other groups of countries. In addition, note that among
middle-productivity countries (those with relative productivity between
0.075 and 0.6), most improvements in relative productivity in a span of
20 years have occurred for the richer countries in this subset, while
most declines have occurred for the poorer countries. For instance, out
of all countries with relative productivity between 0.075 and 0.15 at
some year in our sample period, 20 years later, 46 percent of these
countries remained in the same relative productivity bracket and 38
percent declined to a relative productivity between zero and 0.075. In
contrast, for countries with relative productivity between 0.15 and 0.3,
20 years later, 57 percent remained in the same relative productivity
bracket and 26 percent improved to a relative productivity between 0.3
and 0.6. This finding is consistent with the characterization of deciles
in the previous subsection.
The matrix in Table 4 focuses on the mobility for relative
productivity in our sample. In Table 5 we report an alternative mobility
matrix constructed by quintile. In this matrix, the first element (0.78)
represents the average frequency with which countries in the bottom
quintile of the relative income distribution in a given year are also in
the bottom quintile 20 years later. Note that this second mobility
matrix focuses on mobility for the relative position of a country within
the distribution. Therefore, unlike Table 4, this matrix does not
provide direct information on changes in the level of average relative
productivity of countries in a given bin.
The same basic patterns described for Table 4 also emerge in this
second mobility matrix. In particular, mobility is lower for countries
in the bottom and top quintiles than in the middle quintiles.
We can also characterize mobility by comparing the level of
relative productivity of countries in 1960 and 1996. Figure 5 summarizes
this information. In this figure, countries in the 45-degree line
represent those in which productivity relative to that of the United
States has not changed from 1960 to 1996. Recall that for countries on
the 45-degree line, labor productivity grew at roughly 2 percent per
year during the sample period. Countries above (below) the 45-degree
line are those that have improved (deteriorated) their relative
productivity.
Figure 5 illustrates that individual countries have moved
substantially in the distribution of relative labor productivity during
this period. Particularly noticeable are the movements in relative
productivity of countries such as Hong Kong, Taiwan, Korea, Botswana,
the Democratic Republic of Congo, Angola, and Venezuela. (12)
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Finally, a summary statistic of the performance of individual
countries during the period from 1960 to 1996 is the annualized growth
rate of output per worker. Figure 6 shows that there are important
differences in this growth rate across countries. (13) Output per worker
in several countries deteriorated relative to that in the United States.
Countries that experienced this situation were both rich and poor in
1960. Relative rich countries that observed negative performances
include New Zealand, Switzerland, Venezuela, Canada, Sweden, the
Netherlands, and Argentina. The most notorious negative performers of
the poor countries in 1960 are Angola, Central African Republic, and the
Democratic Republic of Congo in Africa, and Nicaragua, Peru, and Bolivia
in Latin America. We find that in a surprisingly large number of
countries, such as Venezuela, Nicaragua, and many African countries,
output per worker fell in absolute terms from 1960 to 1996. The
explanation for these disparate growth experiences is a fundamental
question for future research. (14)
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
A large number of countries gained position in the distribution of
relative output per worker. These included relatively rich countries in
1960, such as Ireland, Spain, Austria, Italy, France, Belgium, and
Norway, as well as relatively poor countries, such as Taiwan, Hong Kong,
Singapore, Japan, Botswana, Thailand, and Romania. Again, understanding
the factors that explain these remarkable growth performances is of
first-order importance in development economics. (15) We note, however,
that there may be other relevant growth experiences that are not
captured by average growth because the experiences begin later than
1960. For instance, China, Ireland, and India are undergoing a miracle
growth process that started later than 1960. In the next section, we
study systematically remarkable growth experiences in the data.
3. MIRACLES AND DISASTERS
Within the period between 1960 and 1996, there have been
substantial movements of individual countries over time in the
distribution of relative output per worker. These movements are of
interest because they provide opportunities and challenges to theories
of development. Our documentation thus far has focused on countries with
high and low annualized growth rates of output per worker during the
entire period from 1960 to 1996. However, the time series of individual
countries in output per worker show episodes of substantial positive and
negative growth within this period. Therefore, growth as summarized by
the growth rate in output per worker between 1960 and 1996 may hide
interesting growth episodes that occur within this period. For this
reason, we seek to systematically identify episodes of substantial and
sustained growth or decline in relative productivity during our sample
period.
For each country, we record a miracle or disaster episode if
trended output per worker in a country relative to that of the United
States grows or declines by more than 2 percent per year for at least 15
consecutive years. That is, a miracle episode is one in which output per
worker grows at about 4 percent or more per year since trended output
per worker in the United States grows at roughly 2 percent per year.
Similarly, a disaster episode is one in which output per worker is
stagnant or declines. Our view is that countries that are lagging behind
the technology frontier should be able to double the growth rate of
world knowledge in a miracle experience, while disaster experiences
would feature no growth or decline in output per worker for a sustained
period of time.
For each growth episode, we record the starting and ending years of
the episode, the relative output per worker in the starting and ending
years, and the implied annualized growth rate of relative output per
worker during the episode. Tables 6 and 7 report the countries for which
the recorded growth episodes satisfy the two conditions specified above
for a miracle and a disaster. Notice that the changes in relative output
reported in these tables focus only on the period of substantial growth
or decline. However, for many of these countries, the process of growth
or decline may have started earlier or continued later than reported but
at lower rates. Moreover, many of the episodes reported may be censored
since the sustained process of growth or decline may have started before
1960 or may have continued after 1996.
As expected, Table 6 is composed mostly of Asian countries, such as
Taiwan, Japan, Hong Kong, among others. Notice that in some of the
episodes reported in this table, relative output per worker grew at an
annualized rate greater than 4 percent. Given the long time span of the
experiences, these countries improved their relative productivity
dramatically. For instance, in Botswana, relative productivity increased
from 7 percent in 1965 to 30 percent in 1991, and in Hong Kong, relative
productivity increased by a factor of 5, from 19 percent in 1960 to 94
percent in 1996. Note that, excluding Hong Kong, these countries are
still substantially below the level of U.S. labor productivity at the
end of their miracle episode.
The latest miracle episode reported in Table 6 is China. Since
1978, labor productivity in China relative to that of the United States
has grown at almost 4 percent per year, and by 1996, China doubled its
relative productivity to 8 percent (see Figure 7, Panel A). However,
this sustained period of growth in productivity relative to that of the
United States did not start until 1978; before then, relative labor
productivity was slightly declining or stagnant. While China is
undergoing a sustained period of growth, its growth performance between
1978 and 1996 is not as remarkable as other miracle episodes, such as
that experienced by Botswana and Hong Kong, especially considering that
China started its episode of growth by being only half as productive as
Botswana and 20 percent as productive as Hong Kong.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
It is worth emphasizing that our definition of miracle episodes (of
at least 15 years) rules out those episodes that started after 1982. For
instance, Chile, Ireland, and India had miracle experiences that started
after 1982 and have continued at least until 1996. In Chile, relative
output per worker grew at an average of 3.2 percent starting in 1990
(from 32 percent to 40 percent in 1996). In Ireland, relative output per
worker grew at 3 percent starting in 1989 (from 63 percent to 81 percent
in 1996), and in India, at 2.3 percent starting in 1992 (from 8 percent
to 9 percent in 1996).
Table 7 reports the disaster experiences in our sample period. Note
that all countries in this table are located either in Africa or in
Latin America. A remarkable feature of these disaster experiences is the
associated large and sustained declines in relative output per worker,
with some countries seeing their relative output per worker fall by
factors of 4 or more. While most countries in this table were relatively
unproductive at the onset of these experiences, the Latin American
countries were relatively productive. The most notable case is
Venezuela, where relative productivity fell from 87 percent in 1969 to
40 percent in 1989 (see Figure 7, Panel B). As in the case of miracles,
a number of disaster experiences started later than 1982 and therefore
are not reported in this table. However, we note that countries in this
group include Cameroon, Rwanda, Kenya, Honduras, Madagascar, Trinidad
and Tobago, Senegal, and South Africa.
4. DEPRESSIONS
In this section, we report depressions in our data set following
the characterization of Kehoe and Prescott (2002). A depression is
defined as a negative deviation from trend in output per worker that is
fast (leading to a fall in output per worker relative to trend of at
least 15 percent within ten years) and large (leading to a fall in
output per worker relative to trend of at least 20 percent during the
depression period). For this section, we also follow Kehoe and Prescott
(2002) in defining trend as the average annual growth rate of labor
productivity of the United States in the post-war period--about 2
percent. We emphasize that to characterize depressions, we use the raw
time series of output per worker for each country relative to a trend
growth of 2 percent. This procedure differs from our characterization of
miracle and disaster episodes in the previous section, where we use
trended data for each country relative to that for the United States.
Hence, depressions can be short- or medium-run episodes (closer to
business cycles), while miracles and disasters are long-run
characterizations that abstract from business-cycle movements.
We find that depressions are quite common, both among rich and poor
countries. Even in our relatively small sample period, we find 53
depression episodes. In Tables 8 and 9, we report 29 depressions in our
panel data. We exclude from these tables 24 depression episodes of
countries that also faced disaster episodes, as discussed in the
previous section. We report the country name and the approximate years
in which the depression began, in which output per worker fell below 85
percent (relative to its level in the starting year), and in which
output per worker fell below 80 percent (second to forth columns). We
also report the lowest level of output per worker relative to trend and
year during the depression period in the last two columns.
Table 8 summarizes the depression episodes of countries located in
Europe and Latin America during our sample period. Depressions in
Denmark, the Netherlands, and Switzerland started in the 1970s, and
during these experiences, output per worker relative to trend fell by as
much as 25 percent in Denmark and the Netherlands and 39 percent in
Switzerland. Many Latin American economies experienced depressions in
the 1970s and early 1980s and saw declines of output per worker relative
to trend of up to 50 percent. (16)
Table 9 summarizes the remaining depression experiences in our
panel data. With the exception of New Zealand, these are relatively poor
economies. However, the depression in New Zealand looks remarkably
similar to the other episodes reported in this table. In particular, New
Zealand has experienced a long depression, starting around 1973, with a
fall in output per worker relative to trend as large as 41 percent in
1992.
5. DISCUSSION
In this section, we discuss our findings relative to (i) a measure
of labor productivity that includes hours per worker, (ii) a restricted
set of countries for which price data is collected to compute
PPP-conversion factors (Benchmark countries in PWT6.1), and (iii) a
commonly used measure of income across countries--output per capita.
Hours per Worker
We focused on output per worker as our measure of labor
productivity across countries. We chose this measure because of the lack
of systematic data on hours per worker for a large set of countries and
time periods. However, there are data on hours per worker for some
countries and some time periods. We discuss the available evidence on
hours per worker and how this evidence may affect our findings about
dispersion and mobility in labor productivity. We combine the PWT6.1
data with the available data on hours per worker from the Conference
Board and Groningen Growth and Development Centre (2006) to obtain
output per hour. (17) We report the two measures of relative labor
productivity for 1996 in Figure 8, Panel A.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
In Figure 8, Panel A, countries on the 45-degree line represent
those in which hours per worker do not differ from the hours in the
United States. This is the case for most countries with some notable but
perhaps well-known exceptions. First, European countries tend to have
lower hours per worker than does the United States. In particular,
output per worker tends to understate labor productivity for these
countries by roughly 10 percent. (18) Second, there are countries where
hours per worker are higher than in the United States, such as Hong
Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, Mexico, and Chile.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
To illustrate the importance of differences in hours per worker
more directly, we decompose output per hour as the product of output per
worker and the inverse of hours per worker. In Figure 8, Panel B, we
plot hours per worker relative to that of the United States across
countries in 1996. Although differences in hours per worker across
countries are not too large, these differences are systematically
related to income, with poorer countries observing higher hours per
worker than richer countries. Hence, dispersion in output per worker
actually understates dispersion in labor productivity (output per hour).
In Figure 9 we plot the ratio of hours per worker, 1996/1960,
against the level of hours per worker in 1960. This figure suggests that
changes in hours per worker during the 1960-1996 period are not related
to the level of development. Hence, our summary statistics of changes in
dispersion in labor productivity over time are not affected by the
exclusion of hours per worker. It is worth emphasizing, though, that for
some countries in the upper end of the income distribution, changes in
hours per worker are substantial. Therefore, growth in output per worker
may understate growth in labor productivity for these countries (see
some European countries, such as the Netherlands, Belgium, and Norway,
in Figure 9).
Benchmark Countries
The PWT6.1 uses detailed price data across countries to construct
and price a common international basket of goods. These international
prices are then used to convert aggregate measures of output in domestic
prices to aggregate measures of output in international prices that are
comparable across countries. The factors of conversion are typically
called purchasing power parity (PPP). However, actual goods and services prices are collected for a subset of countries (from the ICP studies),
called Benchmark countries. Data for the remaining countries are filled
in using a variety of statistical techniques, perhaps rendering
PPP-converted data for these countries less reliable.
The most comprehensive and recent price collection was in 1996. We
restrict our sample to Benchmark countries in 1996 in order to assess
the importance of countries with lower quality data for our main
findings on labor productivity. Out of 99 countries in our sample, 67
are Benchmark countries in 1996. (19) We restrict our panel data to only
these 67 countries and recompute our baseline statistics. Our findings
hold for the restricted sample. In particular, we find that there is a
large disparity in relative productivity across countries at any point
in time in our sample, that disparity has increased since the mid-1980s,
and that there have been substantial movements of individual countries
in the distribution of relative output per worker.
Output per Capita
We have focused our analysis on output per worker as opposed to
output per capita. Our motivation is that facts on output per worker
relate more directly to theories of labor productivity. Nevertheless, we
recognize that measures of output per capita are more widely available.
For instance, Maddison (2001) documents long time series of comparable
measures of output per capita for 124 countries, while he offers only
limited time series (at most 6 years) of output per worker for only 45
countries. Hence, it is of interest to document how different our
characterization of labor productivity across countries would be if
instead we use data on output per capita. Noticing that output per
capita can be decomposed as the product of output per worker and the
employment-to-population ratio, we can establish two main findings about
the relationship between output per worker and output per capita. First,
while there are substantial differences in the employment-to-population
ratio across countries, these differences are not systematically related
to development. Therefore, our summary statistics characterizing output
per worker over time are roughly similar to statistics on output per
capita. Second, there are substantial changes in
employment-to-population ratios for individual countries over time, and
these changes are not systematically related to development or growth in
relative productivity (see Figure 10). Therefore, changes in output per
capita can severely overstate or understate changes in labor
productivity for individual countries.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
6. CONCLUSIONS
We have documented three remarkable facts about the distribution of
labor productivity across countries: there is a large disparity in labor
productivity across countries in the world, this disparity has increased
substantially since the mid-1980s, and there is substantial mobility of
individual countries in the distribution of labor productivity over
time.
Substantial progress has been made by confronting theories of
development to facts. By extending and updating the development facts,
we attempt to provide new opportunities and challenges to theories of
development. In documenting a number of individual growth experiences,
we intend to direct research efforts to explore a number of relevant
questions in development. Why have China and India been able to start a
miracle episode of growth in the 1980s and 1990s but not other countries
such as those in Latin America? What accounts for China's and
India's recent growth miracle? Why is labor productivity in Africa
falling behind that of the United States since the 1980s if it was
catching up until then? Why is labor productivity in Latin America
stagnant or falling behind that of the United States? Why is labor
productivity in Europe slowing down to levels below that of the United
States? Why has dispersion in relative labor productivity increased so
much since the mid-1980s? Is there a common factor explaining this fact
or is it related to a variety of country-specific factors?
APPENDIX: DATA SOURCES AND DEFINITIONS
We use data from Penn World Tables V6.1 (see Heston, Summers, and
Aten 2002) to construct annual time series of PPP-adjusted GDP per
worker in chained 1996 prices (variable RGDPWOK). We focus on countries
that have data for every year from 1960 to 1996 and that have at least
one million in population in 1996. These restrictions render a set of 99
countries, which includes (with country code in parentheses): Angola
(AGO), Argentina (ARG), Australia (AUS), Austria (AUT), Burundi (BDI),
Belgium (BEL), Benin (BEN), Burkina Faso (BFA), Bangladesh (BGD),
Bolivia (BOL), Brazil (BRA), Botswana (BWA), Central African Republic
(CAF), Canada (CAN), Switzerland (CHE), Chile (CHL), China (CHN), Cote
d'Ivoire (CIV), Cameroon (CMR), Republic of Congo (COG), Colombia
(COL), Costa Rica (CRI), Denmark (DNK), Dominican Republic (DOM),
Ecuador (ECU), Egypt (EGY), Spain (ESP), Ethiopia (ETH), Finland (FIN),
France (FRA), Gabon (GAB), United Kingdom (GBR), Ghana (GHA), Guinea
(GIN), Gambia (GMB), Guinea-Bissau (GNB), Greece (GRC), Guatemala (GTM),
Hong Kong (HKG), Honduras (HND), Indonesia (IDN), India (IND), Ireland
(IRL), Iran (IRN), Israel (ISR), Italy (ITA), Jamaica (JAM), Jordan
(JOR), Japan (JPN), Kenya (KEN), Korea (KOR), Sri Lanka (LKA), Lesotho
(LSO), Morocco (MAR), Madagascar (MGD), Mexico (MEX), Mali (MLI),
Mozambique (MOZ), Mauritania (MRT), Mauritius (MUS), Malawi (MWI),
Malaysia (MYS), Namibia (NAM), Niger (NER), Nigeria (NGA), Nicaragua
(NIC), the Netherlands (NLD), Norway (NOR), Nepal (NPL), New Zealand
(NZL), Pakistan (PAK), Panama (PAN), Peru (PER), Philippines (PHL),
Papua New Guinea (PNG), Portugal (PRT), Paraguay (PRY), Romania (ROM),
Rwanda (RWA), Senegal (SEN), Singapore (SGP), El Salvador (SLV), Sweden
(SWE), Syria (SYR), Chad (TCD), Togo (TGO), Thailand (THA), Trinidad
& Tobago (TTO), Turkey (TUR), Taiwan (TWN), Tanzania (TZA), Uganda
(UGA), Uruguay (URY), United States (USA), Venezuela (VEN), South Africa
(ZAF), Democratic Republic of Congo (ZAR), Zambia (ZMB), and Zimbabwe
(ZWE).
In Section 5 we use data on hours worked obtained from the Total
Economy Database of the Conference Board and Groningen Growth and
Development Centre (2006). We use data on annual hours worked per
employee from 1960 to 1996 for the following 30 countries: Argentina,
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, Switzerland, Chile,
Colombia, Denmark, Spain, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Greece, Hong
Kong, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, New
Zealand, Portugal, Singapore, Sweden, Turkey, Taiwan, United States, and
Venezuela. We divide our measure of output per worker from PWT by hours
to obtain a measure of output per hour. We make the implicit assumption
that employees and self-employed people work the same number of hours.
Clearly self employment differs across sectors and therefore countries;
whether this assumption is valid or not is an open question. There is
some evidence from household surveys in the United States that employees
and self-employed people work roughly the same amount of hours.
The Benchmark 1996 countries in our data set are: Argentina,
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Benin, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Brazil,
Botswana, Canada, Switzerland, Chile, Cote d'Ivoire, Cameroon,
Republic of Congo, Denmark, Ecuador, Egypt, Spain, Finland, France,
Gabon, United Kingdom, Guinea, Greece, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Ireland,
Iran, Israel, Italy, Jamaica, Jordan, Japan, Kenya, Korea, Sri Lanka,
Morocco, Madagascar, Mexico, Mali, Mauritius, Malawi, Nigeria, the
Netherlands, Norway, Nepal, New Zealand, Pakistan, Panama, Peru,
Philippines, Portugal, Romania, Senegal, Singapore, Sweden, Syria,
Thailand, Trinidad & Tobago, Turkey, Tanzania, Uruguay, United
States, Venezuela, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.
REFERENCES
Becker, Gary, Tomas Philipson, and Rodrigo Soares. 2005. "The
Quantity and Quality of Life and the Evolution of World
Inequality." American Economic Review 95 (1): 277-91.
Bello, Omar, and Diego Restuccia. 2003. "Venezuela's
Growth Experience." Manuscript, University of Toronto.
Bergoeing, Raphael, Patrick Kehoe, Timothy Kehoe, and Raimundo
Soto. 2002. "A Decade Lost and Found: Mexico and Chile in the
1980s." Review of Economic Dynamics 5 (1): 166-205.
Bourguignon, Francois, and Christian Morrison. 2002.
"Inequality Among World Citizens: 1920-1992." American
Economic Review 92 (4): 727-44.
Caselli, Francesco. 2005. "Accounting for Cross-Country Income
Differences." In Handbook of Economic Growth volume 1A, ed. P.
Aghion and S. Durlauf. Elsevier North-Holland.
Chari, V.V., P.J. Kehoe, and E.R. McGrattan. 1996. "Sticky
Price Models of the Business Cycle: Can the Contract Multiplier Solve
the Persistence Problem." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff
Report 217.
Cole, Harold, and Lee Ohanian. 1999. "The Great Depression in
the United States from a Neoclassical Perspective." Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 23 (1): 2-24.
Cole, Harold, Lee Ohanian, Alvaro Riascos, and James Schmitz. 2005.
"Latin America in the Rearview Mirror." Journal of Monetary
Economics 52 (1): 69-107.
Conference Board and Groningen Growth and Development Centre. 2006.
Total Economy Database. Available at: http://www.ggdc.net (accessed on
July 20, 2006).
Duarte, Margarida, and Diego Restuccia. 2006. "The Role of the
Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity." Manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Gollin, Douglas, Stephen Parente, and Richard Rogerson. 2002.
"The Role of Agriculture in Development." American Economic
Review Papers and Proceedings 92 (2): 160-64.
Heston, Alan, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten. 2002. Penn World
Table Version 6.1, Center for International Comparisons at the
University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Available at:
http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu (accessed on July 20, 2006).
Jones, Charles. 1997. "On the Evolution of the World Income
Distribution." Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (3): 19-36.
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1961. "Capital Accumulation and Economic
Growth." In The Theory of Capital, ed. F.A. Kutz and D.C. Hague.
New York: St. Martins.
Kehoe, Timothy, and Edward C. Prescott. 2002. "Great
Depressions of the 20th Century." Review of Economic Dynamics 5
(1): 1-18.
Klenow, Peter, and Rodriguez-Clare, Andres. 1997. "The
Neoclassical Revival in Growth Economics: Has It Gone Too Far?" In
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Kuznets, Simon. 1966. Modern Economic Growth. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press.
Maddison, Angus. 1995. Monitoring the World Economy: 1820-1992.
Development Centre Studies. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development.
______. 2001. The World Economy: A Millenial Perspective.
Development Centre Studies. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. "A
Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal
of Economics 107 (2): 402-37.
Parente, Stephen, and Edward C. Prescott. 1993. "Changes in
the Wealth of Nations." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review 17 (2).
Prescott, Edward C. 2002. "Prosperity and Depression."
American Economic Review 92 (2): 1-15.
______. 2004. "Why Do Americans Work So Much More Than
Europeans?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 28
(1).
Restuccia, Diego, Denis Yang, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2006.
"Agriculture and Aggregate Productivity: A Quantitative
Cross-Country Analysis." Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond.
Rogerson, Richard. 2005. "Structural Transformation and the
Deterioration of European Labor Market Outcomes." Manuscript,
Arizona State University.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 2006. "The World Distribution of
Income: Falling Poverty and ... Convergence, Period." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 121 (2): 351-97.
We would like to thank Borys Grochulski, Andreas Hornstein, and
Leonardo Martinez for their comments and Andrea Waddle for her comments
and excellent research assistance. All errors are our own. The views
expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
(1) Throughout the article, we refer to GDP per worker, output per
worker, and labor productivity interchangeably.
(2) This marked interest is reflected, for instance, in the work of
Prescott (2002) and in several articles published in a special volume of
the Review of Economic Dynamics edited by T. Kehoe and E.C. Prescott
(see Kehoe and Prescott 2002).
(3) Maddison (1995, 2001) documents comparable measures of output
per capita for a wide range of countries and time periods. However, we
note that, as in the PWT6.1, Maddison uses the detailed price data from
the International Comparisons Project (ICP) of the United Nations to
calculate purchasing power parity (PPP) conversion factors at a point in
time, and national accounts data to extrapolate over time. In this
sense, Maddison's output data is comparable to PWT6.1, especially
for the Benchmark countries (see Section 5 for a definition of Benchmark
countries).
(4) See the Appendix for a list of countries in our data set.
(5) We set the smoothing parameter [lambda] equal to 100.
(6) The ratio of average output per worker for the 5 richest and 5
poorest countries computed using the data set of 48 countries with data
from 1950 to 2000 shows the same pattern as in Figure 2. For this data
set, the ratio of rich to poor increases steadily from the early 1980s
to 2000.
(7) In 1960, the average output per worker of the five poorest
countries relative to that of the United States is 2.8 percent, while
the average of the five richest countries is 99 percent. By 1996,
average relative labor productivity is 2 percent in the five poorest
countries and 92 percent in the five richest countries.
(8) We compute the Gini coefficient as G =
[N/[N-1]][[[[summation].sub.i=1.sup.N](2i-N-1)[x.sub.i]]/[N.sup.2][mu]],
where x is an N x 1 vector with the observations sorted in ascending
order and [mu] is its mean. This coefficient varies between 0,
reflecting complete equality and 1, which indicates complete inequality
(all income is concentrated in only one country).
(9) See, for instance, Jones (1997).
(10) See, for instance, Bourguignon and Morrison (2002).
(11) See, for instance, Becker et al. (2005).
(12) Using 1985 as the end year implies much less dispersion in
relative productivity around the 45-degree line. This fact suggests that
there were substantial movements in relative productivity between 1985
and 1996. Particularly noticeable are Thailand, China, Tanzania, and
Ethiopia.
(13) Growth rate differences are not systematically related to the
level of relative productivity in 1960. For a documentation of this
finding, see. for instance, Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) and Chari,
Kehoe, and McGrattan (1996).
(14) See some related work in Bello and Restuccia (2003); Cole,
Ohanian, Riascos, and Schmitz (2005); Gollin, Parente, and Rogerson
(2002); and Restuccia, Yang, and Zhu (2006).
(15) See, for instance, Duarte and Restuccia (2006).
(16) Bergoeing et al. (2002) study the depression episodes of
Mexico and Chile in the 1980s.
(17) See the Appendix for a description of the data on hours per
worker.
(18) For instance, Prescott (2004) and Rogerson (2005) study the
implication of tax differences for labor supply levels in Europe and the
United States.
(19) See the Appendix for the list of these countries.
Table 1 Relative Output per Worker by Decile
1960 1970 1980 1990 1996
(percent)
Deciles:
D1 3.4 3.3 3.4 2.8 2.4
D2 6.0 5.8 5.5 4.6 3.7
D3 7.8 7.9 7.7 6.4 5.4
D4 11.0 10.6 12.2 11.4 10.6
D5 16.7 18.1 20.1 17.8 17.4
D6 21.2 22.8 27.8 25.1 23.9
D7 27.2 32.8 34.5 31.7 32.5
D8 38.6 44.1 50.2 48.0 51.0
D9 56.6 65.3 70.2 69.5 72.7
D10 89.6 89.7 88.3 85.2 86.0
Ratios:
D10/D1 26.3 27.1 25.9 30.9 35.6
D9/D2 9.5 11.3 12.7 15.2 19.6
Notes: Decile i (Di) includes countries within the 10 x (i - 1) and 10 x
i percent of the distribution.
Table 2 Relative Output per Worker by Quintile
1960 1970 1980 1990 1996
(percent)
Quintiles:
Q1 4.7 4.5 4.5 3.7 3.1
Q2 9.4 9.3 10.0 8.9 8.0
Q3 19.1 20.7 24.1 21.6 20.8
Q4 34.1 39.9 43.8 41.8 43.8
Q5 74.5 78.7 80.4 78.0 80.0
Ratios:
Q5/Q1 15.8 14.5 18.0 21.3 26.1
Q4/Q2 3.6 4.3 4.4 4.7 5.5
Notes: Quintile i (Qi) includes countries within the 20 x (i - 1) and
20 x i percent of the distribution.
Table 3 Relative Output per Worker by Region
1960 1970 1980 1990 1996
Asia 0.14 0.18 0.23 0.28 0.34
Latin America 0.34 0.35 0.35 0.28 0.25
Africa 0.12 0.13 0.14 0.12 0.12
Western Europe 0.62 0.71 0.77 0.75 0.75
Canada 0.92 0.90 0.88 0.83 0.79
Oceania 0.68 0.65 0.60 0.54 0.52
Table 4 Mobility Matrix--Relative Output per Worker
t + 20
0-0.075 0.075-0.15 0.15-0.3 0.3-0.6 0.6-1.2
t 0-0.075 0.86 0.11 0.03 0 0
0.075-0.15 0.38 0.46 0.11 0.05 0
0.15-0.30 0.01 0.15 0.57 0.26 0.01
0.3-0.6 0 0.02 0.22 0.48 0.28
0.6-1.2 0 0 0 0.10 0.90
Table 5 Mobility Matrix by Quintile
t + 20
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5
t Q1 0.78 0.21 0.01 0 0
Q2 0.22 0.64 0.11 0.03 0
Q3 0 0.14 0.62 0.24 0
Q4 0 0.02 0.24 0.58 0.16
Q5 0 0 0 0.16 0.84
Notes: Quintile i (Qi) includes countries within the 20 x (i - 1) and
20 x i percent of the distribution of relative output per worker.
Table 6 Miracle Episodes
Annualized Start Number Rel. Y/L
Country Growth (%) Year of Years Start End
Botswana 5.59 1965 26 0.07 0.30
Gabon 4.90 1960 15 0.21 0.42
Romania 4.80 1960 25 0.06 0.20
Taiwan 4.64 1960 36 0.12 0.63
Japan 4.56 1960 16 0.26 0.53
Hong Kong 4.54 1960 36 0.19 0.94
Greece 4.46 1960 15 0.34 0.66
Korea 4.20 1961 35 0.14 0.61
Singapore 4.10 1960 23 0.23 0.59
China 3.94 1978 18 0.04 0.08
Rep. of Congo 3.84 1960 24 0.04 0.10
Indonesia 3.62 1969 15 0.07 0.12
Thailand 3.39 1960 36 0.07 0.24
Notes: Annualized Growth is the growth rate in relative output per
worker during the episode. To obtain an approximate annualized growth
rate in output per worker, add 2 percent from growth in output per
worker in the United States. Rel. Y/L is relative output per worker.
Table 7 Disaster Episodes
Annualized Start Number Rel. Y/L
Country Growth (%) Year of Years Start End
Dem. Rep. of Congo -6.45 1971 25 0.06 0.01
Mauritania -6.14 1977 19 0.14 0.04
Nicaragua -5.51 1974 22 0.33 0.10
Mali -5.06 1980 16 0.06 0.03
Mozambique -5.03 1971 16 0.08 0.03
Angola -4.82 1969 27 0.17 0.05
Peru -4.48 1977 19 0.39 0.16
Nigeria -3.99 1980 16 0.06 0.03
Central African Rep. -3.94 1973 23 0.09 0.04
Bolivia -3.93 1980 16 0.21 0.11
Zambia -3.74 1976 20 0.09 0.04
Venezuela -3.69 1968 21 0.87 0.40
Niger -3.23 1960 36 0.10 0.03
Ghana -3.09 1978 15 0.08 0.05
Cote d'Ivoire -3.06 1980 16 0.14 0.08
Chad -2.91 1980 16 0.07 0.05
Madagascar -2.72 1975 21 0.06 0.03
See notes in Table 6.
Table 8 Depressions--Europe and Latin America
Year at (%) Lowest
Country 100 85 80 Level (%) Year
Denmark 1972 1980 1990 75 1992
the Netherlands 1976 1983 1992 75 1994
Switzerland 1972 1978 1983 61 1996
Argentina 1979 1982 1985 59 1990
Chile 1970 1975 1975 67 1983
Colombia 1989 1992 1992 71 1993
Costa Rica 1977 1981 1982 57 1996
Dominican Rep. 1980 1990 1990 77 1991
Ecuador 1979 1986 1987 66 1996
El Salvador 1977 1980 1980 58 1989
Guatemala 1979 1984 1986 70 1996
Jamaica 1970 1976 1976 48 1996
Mexico 1980 1986 1987 65 1995
Panama 1981 1987 1988 70 1989
Paraguay 1990 1994 1994 72 1994
Uruguay 1979 1983 1983 73 1985
Notes: Depressions are characterized using raw output per worker
relative to a 2 percent trend. The second to fourth columns report the
approximate year the depression started, the year in which output per
worker relative to trend falls below 85 percent, and the year in which
output per worker relative to trend falls below 80 percent. The last two
columns report the level and year of the lowest output per worker
relative to trend during the depression episode.
Table 9 Depressions--Rest of the World
Year at (%) Lowest
Country 100 85 80 Level (%) Year
New Zealand 1973 1977 1979 59 1992
Benin 1964 1974 1975 74 1980
Congo 1984 1989 1989 57 1996
Ethiopia 1982 1985 1991 60 1992
Gabon 1977 1981 1982 62 1988
Gambia 1982 1990 1992 64 1996
Guinea 1960 1967 1968 64 1984
Iran 1975 1980 1980 55 1989
Jordan 1985 1989 1989 65 1991
Namibia 1978 1980 1980 52 1996
Papua New Guinea 1972 1980 1981 65 1990
Philippines 1980 1984 1985 62 1994
Togo 1980 1986 1987 50 1996
See notes in Table 8.