Inflation and changing expenditure shares.
Wolman, Alexander L. ; Ding, Fan
Inflation is an index of price changes for many goods. As such, the
behavior of inflation is determined by the behavior of (1) price changes
for individual goods, as well as (2) the weights that the index puts on
the price changes of different goods. Most macroeconomic analyses of the
time-series behavior of inflation--whether empirical or
theoretical--implicitly emphasize the former determinant of inflation.
(1) Theoretical analyses tend to focus on one-sector models in which
there are no weights to shift, and empirical analyses tend to focus on
the univariate properties of some broad inflation rate.
If rates of price change did not differ much across goods, then
shifts in the weights would not matter much for inflation. In fact,
there has been substantial variation in price change behavior across
goods, and the weights on two of the three broad categories in
consumption price indexes have shifted dramatically over the last 50
years (Figure 1). Those facts motivate us to investigate the importance
of changing weights for three fundamental time-series properties of
inflation: level, volatility, and persistence. The extent to which
shifting weights are important for these properties may have
implications for macroeconomic modeling. Suppose that inflation was
highly persistent but that all of the persistence was accounted for by
long-term shifts in the weights in the inflation measure. We might then
conclude that in one-sector macroeconomic models, high inflation
persistence is not a desirable feature.
We propose and implement two approaches to measuring the
contribution of changing expenditure shares to inflation behavior. Both
involve constructing an alternative inflation measure that holds fixed
the weights on price changes for different goods. We describe the
behavior of the level, volatility, and persistence of the alternative
inflation measures. The role of changing expenditure shares is then
revealed by the divergence between the behavior of actual inflation and
the fixed-weight measures. Neither approach leads to a dramatic revision
in our understanding of post-war U.S. inflation; that is, the broad
features of inflation over the past 50 years cannot be accounted for by
changing expenditure shares. However, in more subtle ways, changing
expenditure shares have been important for the behavior of inflation.
For example, we attribute 15 basis points of quarterly inflation, on
average, to changing expenditure shares over the period from 1947 to
2004. Expenditures have shifted to services, and the relative price of
services has risen persistently over the last 50 years. This shift
toward services has tended to make the overall inflation rate higher,
other things equal. The caveat "other things equal" is
important. Expenditure share shifts have been one factor influencing the
behavior of inflation, but monetary policy has had the ability to
counteract the effect of shifting expenditure shares on inflation. Thus,
one could reinterpret the statement above as "in order to achieve
the inflation behavior we have observed, monetary policy has had to
counteract a 15-basis-point upward effect on inflation coming from the
long-run shift in expenditures toward services."
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
It is important to make clear at the outset that we are not arguing
that one should measure inflation by holding fixed the weights on
different goods. It is well known that good price indexes from the
standpoint of economic theory ought to have time-varying weights that
reflect time-varying expenditure patterns. Our concern is instead one of
fact-finding: Given the existence of changes in expenditure shares, to
what extent can those changes account for the behavior of inflation? To
answer this question, we construct alternative fixed-weight price
indexes.
For the most part, recent literature on inflation in the United
States has abstracted from the heterogeneity that underlies overall
inflation. Notable exceptions are Clark (2003) and Bauer, Haltom, and
Peterman (2004). Bauer, Haltom, and Peterman focus on the behavior of
core inflation over the last 20 years. They decompose core inflation
into contributions of different goods and services. These contributions
are the product of expenditure shares and individual price changes.
Bauer, Haltom, and Peterman find that just two components, rent and used
vehicles, account for much of the decline in consumer price index (CPI)
inflation over this period. Clark's emphasis is on inflation
persistence, which we will discuss further. He contrasts the behavior of
inflation persistence over time to the behavior of the persistence of
disaggregated price changes. He finds that the persistence of
disaggregated price changes tends to be lower than the persistence of
inflation. Our article differs in its explicit emphasis on changing
expenditure shares over time. Clark's findings, though, suggest
that expenditure share behavior may be an important determinant of
inflation persistence.
1. INFLATION IN THE UNITED STATES
The variables we are concerned with are all produced by the Bureau
of Economic Analysis of the United States Department of Commerce. They
are the price index for personal consumption expenditure; the subindexes
for durable goods, nondurable goods, and services; and the expenditure
shares for durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. Before turning
to the behavior of these variables, it is useful to provide some
background on price indexes, and, in particular, on the price index for
personal consumption expenditure. (Henceforth, we will refer to this
index as the PCE price index, and to its rate of change as PCE
inflation.)
PCE inflation data are constructed from underlying price and
quantity data for a large number of categories of goods and services. In
turn, the price data for those underlying categories are constructed
from more direct observation of prices on an even larger number of
specific items (i.e., goods and services). The latter construction is
performed mainly by the Department of Labor's Bureau of Labor
Statistics. For the most part, the same item prices that form the basis
for PCE inflation also form the basis for the more widely known CPI
inflation, which is produced by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. We focus
here on PCE inflation for two reasons. First, the methodology used to
produce the PCE inflation numbers corresponds more closely to notions of
price indexes suggested by economic theory. Second, the PCE methodology
makes it more straightforward to decompose inflation in a way that
isolates the effect of changing expenditure shares.
The formula used to create the PCE inflation rate is known as a
Fisher ideal index. We will first provide the formula and then interpret
it. (2) We define [[pi].sub.t] to be the PCE inflation rate in quarter
t, [x.sub.i,t] to be the period t dollar expenditures on category i, and
[[pi].sub.i,t] to be the rate of price change for category i from period
t - 1 to period t. The PCE inflation rate is
[[pi].sub.t] = [square root of ([[I.summation over (i=1)]
[[omega].sub.i,t-1][[pi].sub.i,t]][[I.summation over (i=1)]
[[theta].sub.i,t][[pi].sub.i,t]])], (1)
where
[[omega].sub.i,t] [equivalent to]
[x.sub.i,t]/[[[summation].sub.j=1.sup.I][x.sub.j,t]], and
[[theta].sub.i,t] [equivalent to]
[[x.sub.i,t]/[[pi].sub.i,t]]/[[[summation].sub.j=1.sup.I]
([x.sub.j,t]/[[pi].sub.j,t])], .for i = 1,..., I.
Both objects in square brackets in (1) are weighted averages of the
rates of price change for each good and service. The weights,
[[omega].sub.i,t-1], are simply the expenditure shares for category i in
period t - 1; thus, the first weighted average,
[[summation].sub.i=1.sup.I] [[omega].sub.i,t-1][[pi].sub.i,t], measures
the rate of price change for the basket of goods purchased in period t -
1. The weights, [[theta].sub.i,t], are the hypothetical expenditure
shares that are derived by combining period t real quantities with
period t - 1 prices. Thus, the second weighted average,
[[summation].sub.i=1.sup.I][[theta].sub.i,t][[pi].sub.i,t], measures the
rate of price change in period t for the basket of goods purchased in
period t. Finally, PCE inflation ([[pi].sub.t]) is the geometric average
of these two inflation rates.
It is clear from (1) that changes in expenditure shares on
different goods and services are incorporated in the behavior of the
PCE. In contrast, the CPI is a fixed-weight index; changes in
expenditure shares are incorporated in the CPI only every two years. The
precise way in which changing expenditure shares are incorporated in PCE
inflation is somewhat complicated, as seen in (1). Fortunately, for our
purposes, the true PCE inflation rate is well approximated by a simpler
formula that aggregates prices for the three major spending categories
using what is known as a Divisia index. The Divisia approximation to the
PCE which we will use is
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[[pi].sub.t.sup.D] = [summation over
(i=N,D,S)][[omega].sub.i,t-1][[pi].sub.i,t], (2)
that is, the expenditure-share-weighted average of price changes
for non-durable goods, durable goods, and services. This approximation
is convenient because it allows us to easily decompose the behavior of
inflation into the part accounted for by changing expenditure shares and
the part accounted for by changing rates of price change for the main
spending categories.
The Level of Inflation
Figure 2 displays the quarterly PCE inflation rate from 1947 to
2004, expressed in annualized percentage terms. (3) This figure displays
the major facts about inflation in the United States. Inflation was
highly volatile immediately after World War II, then declined and became
more stable during the 1950s. In the mid-1960s, inflation began a steady
rise that continued for the rest of the decade. The 1970s were
characterized by high and volatile inflation, and then in the early
1980s inflation declined dramatically. Over the last 15 to 20 years,
inflation has been low and stable, apart from a moderate increase in the
late 1980s. The average PCE inflation rate from 1947 to the present has
been 3.42 percent. Though these basic facts are clear, much about the
behavior of the level of U.S. inflation remains in dispute. For example,
economists agree that the Federal Reserve can determine the average
level of inflation over periods of several years. Thus, there is
consensus that the Federal Reserve could have brought about a much lower
average inflation rate in the 1970s. However, there is no consensus
about why the Fed behaved as it did. We direct interested readers to
Hetzel (1998), Orphanides (2003), and Cogley and Sargent (2003) for an
introduction to the vast literature analyzing that question.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Inflation Volatility
Panel A of Figure 3 displays two measures of inflation volatility.
The first, the solid line, is the variance of inflation, measured over
ten-year rolling windows ending at the date on the horizontal axis. For
example, the entry labeled "4/79" is the sample variance of
inflation from the third quarter of 1969 through the second quarter of
1979.
Variance is the most natural way to measure volatility. However,
variance can be a misleading measure of volatility if a time series is
serially correlated. For example, consider the first-order
autoregressive process,
[y.sub.t] = [rho][y.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (3)
where [[epsilon].sub.t] is an i.i.d. normal random variable with
mean zero and variance v. The variance of [y.sub.t] is var(y) = (1 -
[[rho].sup.2])[.sup.-1] v. Thus, even though v is the only source of
random volatility in y, the autoregressive coefficient [rho] contributes
to the variance of y.
The effect of serial correlation (that is, persistence) on variance
leads us to present a second measure of volatility along with variance.
The dashed line is the variance of the residual in an autoregressive
representation of inflation, where the autoregression is estimated by
OLS, and the lag length is chosen by the Akaike information criterion (AIC). This residual variance can be thought of as a measure of the
volatility that remains after taking out predictable variation in the
series during the particular ten-year window. For both measures,
volatility fell dramatically until 1961, then remained low until the
early 1970s. It rose in the 1970s, fell in the 1980s, and has been
historically low over the last five years. The fact that the variance of
inflation rose much more than the shock variance from the late 1960s
through the late 1980s suggests that there were changes in the serial
correlation properties of inflation over this period. We consider these
next.
Inflation Persistence
"Inflation persistence" refers to the degree to which a
sudden change in the inflation rate tends to persist over time. As we
just saw, persistence leads to higher variance, other things equal. In
recent years much research has been devoted to estimating the
persistence of inflation in the United States. This literature was
spawned by Fuhrer and Moore (1995), who argued that inflation in the
United States was characterized by high persistence and that models with
forward-looking pricing behavior were unable to replicate the observed
level of persistence. Fundamentally, however, interest in inflation
persistence dates back to Lucas (1972) and Sargent (1971). These authors
showed that the accuracy of econometric procedures for estimating
Phillips curve slopes could be sensitive to the univariate persistence
properties of inflation. Recent research on inflation persistence has,
like Fuhrer and Moore, been concerned with quantifying the degree of
inflation persistence and then assessing whether and to what degree
observed persistence is an inherent structural feature or an artifact of
the particular monetary policy in place. The extent to which inflation
persistence is structural has important implications for the
consequences of alternative monetary policies. (4)
There are several ways to measure inflation persistence. Pivetta
and Reis (2004) discuss the different measures in detail. In the case of
the first-order autoregression discussed above, the different measures
of persistence are all equivalent, and persistence is summarized by the
parameter, [rho]. For more complicated processes, the different measures
can give different rankings of persistence. We will follow Levin and
Piger (2003) and Clark (2003) in measuring inflation persistence by the
sum of autoregressive coefficients in a univariate autoregressive
representation of inflation. (5) If the sum of autoregressive
coefficients is [rho], then 1/(1 - [rho]) represents the long-run effect
of a permanent unit shock to the autoregression. That is, if in each
period from t = 0 to [infinity], the autoregression in (3) is hit by
[[epsilon].sub.t] = 1, and [[epsilon].sub.t] = 0 for t < 0, then at t
= [infinity], we have [y.sub.t] = 1/(1 - [rho]).
Panel B of Figure 3 displays ten-year rolling-window estimates of
PCE inflation persistence from the second quarter of 1959 to the first
quarter of 2004. For each quarter, we take the ten years of prior data
and estimate an autoregression for inflation, using the AIC to select
lag length. The sum of autoregressive coefficients is then plotted in
this panel, along with centered 90 percent confidence intervals
constructed by semiparametric bootstrapping. (6)
Persistence fluctuates between 0.16 and 1.20 over the full sample.
It was low until the late 1960s, then jumped up in late 1968 and early
1969, and remained high (roughly 0.8 or above) until 1999, apart from a
brief period in 1983 and some rapid fluctuations between 1991 and 1995.
In the last five years, our persistence measure has declined steadily,
reaching 0.23 in the first quarter of 2004. The confidence intervals are
quite wide. However, they encompass zero a much greater percentage of
the time than they encompass unity, shedding some doubt on the
conventional wisdom that inflation is inherently highly persistent. (7)
The increase in inflation persistence in the late 1970s corresponds to
the divergence (panel A of Figure 3) between the variance of inflation
and the variance of the shock to the inflation autoregression. It is not
as easy to reconcile the joint behavior of these three objects later in
the sample when the variance of inflation drops sharply. That is, the
sharp drop in the variance of inflation without a sharp drop in the
shock variance is not explained by a sharp drop in inflation
persistence. Such a discrepancy can occur because, for autoregressions
with more than one lag, the relationship between variance of the series
and variance of the shock depends on the individual autoregressive
coefficients, not just their sum.
2. SECTORAL INFLATION AND OVERALL INFLATION
Having laid out the basic features of inflation behavior in the
United States, we now turn to the components of inflation, expenditure
shares, and price changes for the three consumer spending categories of
durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. In this section we
document the behavior of expenditure shares and price changes. The
changes in expenditure shares over time and the variation in rates of
price change across sectors then motivate our attempts in the next
section to quantify the contribution of changing expenditure shares to
the behavior of overall inflation.
Figure 1 plots expenditure shares for durable goods, nondurable
goods, and services from 1947 to the present. Whereas the expenditure
share for durable goods has fluctuated narrowly, between 12 and 18
percent, the shares of nondurables and services have respectively risen
and fallen dramatically. In January 1947 services accounted for only 31
percent, and nondurable goods accounted for 56 percent of personal
consumption expenditure. In January 2004, services accounted for 59
percent, and nondurable goods only 29 percent of personal consumption
expenditure.
Figure 4 plots rates of price change for the three first-level
components of personal consumption expenditure, together with the
overall PCE inflation rate. Each series differs somewhat from overall
inflation. Services price changes have generally been above PCE
inflation, averaging 4.22 percent, compared to 3.42 percent for overall
inflation. Durables price changes have generally been below PCE
inflation, averaging 1.59 percent. The main distinguishing feature of
nondurables price changes--which have averaged 3.09 percent--is that
they have been more volatile than PCE inflation. This feature is
reflected in Figure 5, which plots rolling-window variances of the
sectoral rates of price change. (8) Figure 6 shows that the differences
in rates of price change across sectors have cumulated significantly
over time: the price index for services rose by a factor of eleven since
1947, whereas the price index for durables rose by less than a factor of
three. In the last eight years, the price index for durable goods has
actually been falling.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Figure 7 plots persistence for rates of price change of durables,
nondurables, and services. The persistence measure is, again, the sum of
auto-regressive coefficients. The persistence measure moves broadly
together across sectors, with services usually being the most
persistent. Early in the sample, nondurables price changes are more
persistent than durables price changes, but this ordering is reversed
after about 1980. At the end of the sample, when persistence of PCE
inflation is declining, the same is happening to rates of price change
for services and nondurables, but persistence rises dramatically for
durables price changes in 1998 and stays high until the present.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Together with the large swing in expenditure shares, differential
behavior of price changes across sectors suggests that expenditure share
changes may have been important contributors to the behavior of
inflation. We will estimate this contribution in the next section.
However, even if we find little contribution, the existence of
expenditure shifts together with differing rates of price change across
sectors is an important observation. Sectoral shifts and heterogeneous
price behavior across sectors may have implications for monetary policy.
For example, the nature of optimal monetary policy may be sensitive to
these factors. (9)
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
3. REINTERPRETING CHANGES IN THE BEHAVIOR OF INFLATION
To assess the importance of changing expenditure shares for the
behavior of inflation, we construct two series that control for long-run
shifts in expenditure shares. The first series we call "1947
inflation," and we create it by replacing the actual expenditure
shares, [w.sub.i,t-1], in (2) with expenditure shares that fluctuate
only transitorily around their 1947:4 levels. We generate 1947 inflation
in two steps. First we estimate quadratic time trends for the
expenditure shares under the restriction that the trends sum to one.
Then we create a series of synthetic weights (expenditure shares) for
each date in our sample by adding the 1947:4 value of the trend weight
to the difference between the actual weight at each date and the trend
weight estimated for that date. The initial values for the trend weights
are 0.12 for durables, 0.31 for services, and 0.56 for nondurables. We
allow for fluctuations around the trends because these may be
independent of the long-run sectoral shifts we want to control for.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Our second approach to controlling for changing expenditure shares
involves extracting the first principal component of the three sectoral
rates of price change. The principal component is a weighted average of
the three sectoral rates of price change, with the weights being chosen
in order to maximize the variance of the weighted average. The weights
are 0.76 for services, 0.21 for durables, and 0.03 for nondurables. The
principal component can be viewed as the common component of the
sectoral rates of price change. Because actual expenditure shares are
not used to compute the principal component, they do not directly
influence this series. Kapetanios (2002) suggests a similar measure as
reflecting a notion of core inflation. The weighted median inflation
measure emphasized by Bryan and Cecchetti (1994) is similar in spirit to
the first principal component in that it attempts to cut down the
contribution of noisy components of inflation. (10)
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The Level of Inflation
Figure 8 displays the time series for 1947 inflation, and Figure 9
displays the first principal component of sectoral inflation. In each
case we plot annual averages of the series and display them along with
the corresponding series for actual PCE inflation. Both series share the
broad patterns that characterize actual PCE inflation. If someone
familiar with postwar U.S. inflation were shown either panel, it might
not be difficult to convince them that it was a plot of actual
inflation. However, there are some differences between both series and
actual PCE inflation.
In the case of 1947 inflation, it is not surprising that these
differences arise in the latter part of the sample, when the actual
weights are quite different from the 1947 weights (services having risen
and nondurables having fallen). Because nondurables inflation is more
volatile than services inflation, the 1947 inflation series with its
higher weight on nondurables is noticeably more volatile than actual
inflation in the last 20 years of the sample. In addition, because the
average rate of price change for nondurables has been lower than that
for services, 1947 inflation has a somewhat lower average level, 3.27
percent versus 3.42 percent. The lower level is obscured, however, by
the higher volatility.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The principal component of sectoral price changes has a higher
average than PCE inflation, at 3.64 percent. This is attributable to the
high weight the principal component places on services. The high weight
on services and low weight on volatile nondurables explains the fact
that the principal component is less volatile than either PCE inflation
or 1947 inflation. A notable feature of the principal component's
behavior is that, unlike actual inflation and 1947 inflation, it is
quite stable between 1983 and 1991. The other two series exhibit a sharp
fall around 1986 and then a sharp rise followed by an additional steady
increase. Referring to the sectoral price changes in Figure 4, we can
understand this divergence as reflecting the fact that the volatility in
the mid-to-late 1980s is largely accounted for by volatility in
nondurables price changes.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Volatility and Persistence
Figures 10 and 11 display volatility and persistence of our
alternative measures in the same way that Figure 3 displays volatility
and persistence of actual inflation. Neither 1947 inflation nor the
principal component of sectoral price changes displays markedly
different volatility patterns than does actual inflation. There are some
minor differences across the series, however. Figures 10 and 11 confirm
that the principal component has lower volatility than actual inflation
or 1947 inflation. The inflation shock volatility displayed in the
middle panels behaves similarly for actual inflation and the principal
component, declining smoothly from the mid-1970s until the early 1980s.
In contrast, for 1947 inflation, there is a sharper decline in shock
volatility, and it does not occur until the mid-1980s.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
Rolling-window estimates of inflation persistence for the two new
series are in the bottom panels of Figures 10 and 11. Over the first
two-thirds of the sample, there is little difference between the
persistence of 1947 inflation and the persistence of PCE inflation. This
similarity is to be expected, because the underlying inflation series
for the two figures do not differ much from each other. Since 1990,
however, the two sets of estimates have diverged noticeably. For PCE
inflation, persistence has been generally high over this period (with an
average of 0.63), declining below 0.50 only in the last four years. In
contrast, persistence of 1947 inflation has been generally low since
1990, averaging 0.45.
To some degree, the lower level of persistence in recent years for
1947 inflation is easy to explain. Nondurables has generally been the
least persistent component of inflation (see Figure 7)--at least during
the second half of the sample; therefore, because our 1947 inflation
series places a relatively higher weight on nondurables later in the
sample, this direct effect will make 1947 inflation more persistent than
PCE inflation. However, this direct effect cannot explain all of the
differences between the persistence of 1947 inflation and PCE inflation.
The persistence of 1947 inflation is not simply the
expenditure-share-weighted average of the persistence of the components.
Our persistence measure has the flavor of a covariance, and, as such, it
depends in a complicated manner on the covariance between sectoral rates
of price change.
The bottom panel of Figure 11 plots the same rolling-window
estimate of persistence for the principal component. Unlike 1947
inflation, the principal component places a very low weight on
nondurables. Thus, it is not surprising that its persistence behaves
quite differently than that of 1947 inflation. Although persistence of
the principal component has declined in recent years, the decline has
been smaller in magnitude than that of actual inflation; the relatively
high weight on durables means that the increase in persistence of price
changes of durables is reflected more in the principal component than in
1947 inflation. More generally, fluctuations in the persistence of the
principal component have been smaller than fluctuations in the
persistence of actual inflation or 1947 inflation.
4. CONCLUSION
We began by noting the dramatic changes in consumption expenditure
shares that have occurred in the United States over the last 50 years.
The fact that these shares serve as weights in consumption price
inflation measures then led us to investigate the quantitative
importance of shifts in expenditure shares for the behavior of U.S.
inflation. Using two different methods, we found that controlling for
expenditure share changes led to a picture of U.S. inflation over the
last 50 years that was somewhat--but not dramatically--different from
the picture provided by actual PCE inflation. This analysis is
exploratory only. That changing expenditure shares do not account for
much of the behavior of inflation does not mean that those changes are
inconsequential for monetary policy. Large changes in expenditure
shares, together with trend changes in relative prices across sectors
(as displayed in Figure 6) may interact with other differences across
sectors in a way that has important implications for monetary policy.
For example, if the nature of price stickiness differs systematically
across sectors (as tentatively suggested by the work of Bils and Klenow
[2004]) or if money demand varies systematically across expenditure
types, then the monetary policy prescriptions from one-sector models may
differ markedly from those in models with multiple categories of
consumption.
We wish to thank Bob Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein, Tom Humphrey, and
Eric Nielsen for helpful comments and Sam Malek for his assistance. The
views here are the author's and should not be attributed to the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) Wolman (1999) is an example of an article that fits this
description.
(2) See Webb (2004) and Clark (1999) for more detailed discussions
of how the PCE price index is constructed.
(3) In all figures, the month and year on the x-axis indicate the
first month of the quarter represented by the tick mark.
(4) Different degrees of structural inflation persistence
correspond to different degrees of price rigidity or other nominal
frictions. Different specifications of nominal frictions, in turn,
correspond to different real implications of changing policy rules.
(5) In the first-order example, the sum of coefficients is simply
[rho].
(6) To generate the confidence intervals for a given quarter, we
simulated 5000 samples by combining the estimated autoregressive
coefficients with resampled residuals. These confidence intervals should
be interpreted with caution; Hansen's (1999) grid bootstrap method
deals more effectively with the bias associated with persistence being
close to unity.
(7) This statement requires the caveat that the confidence
intervals will be misleading when persistence is near unity.
(8) Volatility of price changes of nondurables will not be a
surprise to readers familiar with the concept of core PCE inflation.
Core PCE inflation excludes food and energy prices, which are
notoriously volatile and comprise a large share of nondurables
expenditures. For short-run monetary policy purposes, core PCE inflation
is generally preferred to overall PCE inflation.
(9) Aoki (2001), Erceg and Levin (2002), and Huang and Liu (2003)
study cyclical fluctuations and monetary policy in multi-sector models.
Wolman (2004) considers the optimal steady state inflation rate when
there are relative price trends across sectors.
(10) As a measure of core inflation, Bryan and Cecchetti (1994) use
the weighted median of 36 components of the all-urban consumers CPI.
This is the "central point, as implied by the CPI expenditure
weights, in the cross-sectional histogram of inflation each month"
(p. 203).
REFERENCES
Aoki, Kosuke. 2001. "Optimal Monetary Policy Response to
Relative Price Changes." Journal of Monetary Economics 48
(December): 55-80.
Bils, Mark, and Pete Klenow. 2004. "Some Evidence on the
Importance of Sticky Prices." Journal of Political Economy 112
(October): 947-85.
Bauer, Andrew, Nicholas Haltom, and William Peterman. 2004.
"Examining Contributions to Core Consumer Inflation Measures."
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 04-07.
Bryan, Michael, and Stephen Cecchetti. 1994. "Measuring Core
Inflation." Monetary Policy, ed. N. Gregory Mankiw. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press: 195-215.
Clark, Todd E. 1999. "A Comparison of the CPI and the PCE
Price Index." Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review
84 (Third Quarter): 15-29.
__________. 2003. "Disaggregate Evidence on the Persistence of
Consumer Price Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Research Working Paper 03-11.
Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent. 2003. "The Conquest of
U.S. Inflation: Learning, Model Uncertainty, and Robustness."
Manuscript.
Erceg, Christopher, and Andrew Levin. 2002. "Optimal Monetary
Policy with Durable and Nondurable Goods." FRB International
Finance Discussion Paper 748 and ECB Working Paper 179.
Fuhrer, Jeffrey, and George Moore. 1995. "Inflation
Persistence." Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (February):127-59.
Hansen, Bruce E. 1999. "The Grid Bootstrap and the
Autoregressive Model." The Review of Economics and Statistics 81
(November): 594-607.
Hetzel, Robert L. 1998. "Arthur Burns and Inflation."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 84 (Winter): 21-44.
Huang, Kevin, and Zheng Liu. 2003. "Inflation Targeting: What
Inflation Rate to Target?" Journal of Monetary Economics.
Forthcoming.
Kapetanios, George. 2002. "Modelling Core Inflation for the UK
Using a New Dynamic Factor Estimation Method and a Large Disaggregated
Price Index Dataset." Queen Mary, University of London, Department
of Economics Working Paper 471.
Levin, Andrew, and Jeremy Piger. 2002. "Is Inflation
Persistence Intrinsic in Industrial Economies?" Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 23E.
Lucas, Robert E. 1972. "Econometric Testing of the Natural
Rate Hypothesis." The Econometrics of Price Determination, ed. O.
Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System: 50-9.
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2003. "The Quest for Prosperity
Without Inflation." Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (April):
633-63.
Pivetta, Frederic, and Ricardo Reis. 2004. "The Persistence of
Inflation in the United States." Manuscript.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1971. "A Note on the
'Accelerationist' Controversy." Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking 3 (August): 721-25.
Webb, Roy. 2004. "Which Price Index Should a Central Bank
Employ?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 90
(Spring): 63-76.
Wolman, Alexander L. 1999. "Sticky Prices, Marginal Cost, and
the Behavior of Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 85 (Fall): 29-48.
__________. 2004. "The Optimal Rate of Inflation with Trending
Relative Prices." Manuscript.