Unemployment and vacancy fluctuations in the matching model: inspecting the mechanism.
Hornstein, Andreas ; Krusell, Per ; Violante, Giovanni L. 等
The state of the labor market, employment and unemployment, plays
an important role in the deliberations of policymakers, the Federal
Reserve Bank included. Over the last 30 years, economic theory has led
to substantial progress in understanding the mechanics of business
cycles. Much of this progress in macroeconomics has been associated with
the use of calibrated dynamic equilibrium models for the quantitative
analysis of aggregate fluctuations (Prescott [1986]). These advances
have mainly proceeded within the Walrasian framework of frictionless
markets. For the labor market, this means that while these theories
contribute to our understanding of employment determination, they have
nothing to say about unemployment.
Policymakers care about the behavior of unemployment for at least
two reasons. First, even if one is mainly interested in the
determination of employment, unemployment might represent a necessary
transitional state if frictions impede the allocation of labor among
production opportunities. Second, job loss and the associated
unemployment spell represent a major source of income risk to
individuals.
Over the past two decades, the search and matching framework has
acquired the status of the standard theory of equilibrium unemployment.
(1) This theory is built on the idea that trade in the labor market is
costly and takes time. Frictions originating from imperfect information,
heterogeneity of firms and workers, and lack of coordination disrupt the
ability to form employment relationships. The quantity of idle inputs in
the labor market (unemployed workers and vacant jobs) is a measure of
such disruption. In its most basic representation, a labor market
matching model focuses on the interaction between unemployment and job
creation. Higher productivity increases the return to job creation and
thereby increases the rate of job creation. In turn, a higher rate of
job creation makes it easier for unemployed workers to find jobs and
thereby reduces unemployment. This explains the observed
counter-cyclical (pro-cyclical) behavior of unemployment (job creation).
Shimer (2005) goes beyond investigating the qualitative features of
the basic matching model. He follows the research program on dynamic
equilibrium models with Walrasian frictionless markets and explores
whether or not a calibrated matching model of the labor market is
quantitatively consistent with observed aggregate fluctuations. He
surprisingly concludes that a reasonably calibrated matching model does
not generate enough volatility in unemployment and cannot explain the
strong procyclicality of the job-finding rate. In other words, the
matching model stops short of reproducing the cyclical behavior of its
two central elements: unemployment and vacancies. (2)
In this article, we present the basic matching model, also known as
the Mortensen-Pissarides model, in detail and, building on Shimer
(2005), we explain the reasons for the quantitative problems of the
model. Essentially, given the way wages are determined in the
(Nash-bargaining) model and the way Nash bargaining is calibrated, wages
respond strongly to changes in productivity so that the incentive for
firms to create jobs does not change very much. We then discuss two
possible ways of reconciling a matching model with the data.
First, as argued by Hall (2005) and Shimer (2004), if wages are
essentially rigid, the model performs much better. We contend that rigid
wages per se are not sufficient; another necessary requirement is a very
large labor share--close to 100 percent of output. Moreover, we show
that with rigid wages, the model has implications for the labor share
that seem too extreme: the labor share becomes perfectly negatively
correlated with--and as volatile as--labor productivity whereas in the
data this correlation is -0.5, and the variation of the share is not
nearly as large as that of productivity.
Second, as suggested by Hagedorn and Manovskii (2005), without
abandoning Nash bargaining, a different calibration of some key
parameters of the model also allows one to raise the volatility of
unemployment and vacancies in the model. For this calibration to work,
however, one again needs a very high wage share. This high share is
obtained by "artificially" raising the outside option of the
worker through generous unemployment benefits. (3) We tentatively
conclude, as do Costain and Reiter (2003), that this parameterization
has implausible implications for the impact of unemployment benefits on
the equilibrium unemployment rate: a 15 percent rise in benefits would
double the unemployment rate.
Why is a very large (very small) wage share (profit share) so
important in order for the model to have a strong amplification mechanism for vacancies and unemployment? The model has a free-entry
condition stating that vacancies are created until discounted profits
equal the cost of entry. If profits are very small in equilibrium, a
positive productivity shock induces a very large percentage increase in
profits, and hence a large number of new vacancies must be
created--through firm entry--thus lowering the rate of finding workers
enough that entry remains an activity with zero net payoff.
We conclude that neither one of the solutions proposed is fully
satisfactory, for two reasons. First, they both have first-order
counterfactual implications. Second, they both assume a very large value
for the labor share. It is hard to assess whether this value is
plausible because there is no physical capital in the baseline matching
model. We speculate that the addition of physical capital, besides
providing a natural way of measuring the labor share of aggregate
income, would allow the analysis of another important source of
aggregate fluctuations, investment-specific shocks, which have proved
successful in Walrasian models. (4)
The present article, which can be read both as an introduction to
the matching model of unemployment and as a way of understanding the
recent discussions of the model's quantitative implications, is
organized as follows. We first quickly describe the data. Next, we
describe in Section 2 the basic model without aggregate shocks. In
Section 3, we define and solve for a stationary equilibrium: a steady
state. In Section 4, we briefly discuss transition dynamics within the
model without shocks. In Section 5, we derive the qualitative
comparative statics for a one-time permanent change of the model's
parameters. In Section 6, we present the alternative calibration
strategies one could follow to parameterize the matching model, and in
Section 7, we show how the quantitative comparative statics results
differ according to the model calibration. In Section 8, we introduce
explicit stochastic aggregate shocks and discuss how the quantitative
comparative statics results for one-time permanent shocks have to be
modified to account for persistent but temporary shocks. Section 9
concludes the article.
1. THE DATA
The focus of the analysis is on fluctuations at the business-cycle
frequencies, and hence low-frequency movements in the data should be
filtered out. For quarterly data, the standard practice (followed by
Andolfatto and Merz) is to use a Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter with a
smoothing parameter set to 1600. Shimer (2005) chooses a much smoother
trend component, corresponding to an HP smoothing parameter of
[10.sup.5].
Table 1 summarizes the key labor market facts around which this
article is centered. We report statistics for the detrended log-levels
of each series. When we remove a very smooth trend (smoothing parameter
[10.sup.5]), we can summarize the data as follows:
* Unemployment and Vacancies. First, unemployment, u, and
vacancies, v, are about 10 times more volatile than labor productivity,
p. Market tightness, [theta], defined as the ratio of vacancies to
unemployment, is almost 20 times more volatile. Second, market tightness
is positively correlated with labor productivity. Both unemployment and
vacancies show strong autocorrelation.
* Job-Finding Rates. The job-finding rate, [[lambda].sub.w], is six
times more volatile than productivity and is pro-cyclical. It is also
strongly autocorrelated.
* Wages and Labor Share. Wages and the labor share are roughly as
volatile as labor productivity. The correlation between wages and labor
productivity is high but significantly less than one, and the labor
share is countercyclical.
Using a more volatile trend component (lower smoothing parameter)
has almost no effect on the relative volatilities. For the vast majority
of the variables, the percentage standard deviation is reduced roughly
by one-third. Interestingly, the volatility is cut in half for wages and
the labor share. Overall, the autocorrelation of the series is reduced,
since some of the persistence is absorbed by the more variable HP trend.
Finally, the correlation structure of the series with labor productivity
is, in general, unchanged except for the labor share whose negative
correlation almost doubles.
We conclude that the choice of smoothing parameter has no impact on
the unemployment and vacancy statistics but does affect the labor share
statistics somewhat.
2. THE MODEL
We now outline and discuss the basic Mortensen-Pissarides matching
model with exogenous separations. (5) We choose a formulation in
continuous time in order to simplify some of the derivations. It is
useful to first describe the stationary economy (when aggregate
productivity is constant over time) because that model is simple and yet
very informative about how the model with random shocks behaves. Later,
we will briefly discuss aggregate fluctuations with stochastic
productivity shocks that are persistent but not permanent. (6)
Workers and Firms
There is a fixed number of workers in the economy; the model does
not consider variations in the labor force or in the effort or amount of
time worked by each worker. For example, think of workers as being
uniformly distributed on the interval [0,1]--for any point on this
interval, there is one worker--though there is no particular meaning to
a worker's position on the interval.
Workers are all the same from the perspective of both their
productivity and their preferences. Workers are infinitely lived and
have linear utility over consumption of a homogeneous good, meaning that
to the extent that there is uncertainty, workers are risk-neutral. There
is constant (exponential) discounting at rate r. One can therefore think
of a worker's expected present value of utility as simply the
expected present value of income. (7)
Workers are either employed or unemployed. An employed worker earns
wage income, w, but cannot search. Unemployed workers search for jobs.
Let b > 0 denote the income equivalent of the utility flow that a
worker obtains in the nonworking activity when unemployed, e.g., the
monetary value of leisure plus unemployment benefits net of search
costs. (8)
A firm is a job. The supply of firms (jobs) is potentially
infinite. Every firm is equally productive at any point in time. Firms
are risk-neutral and they discount future income at the same rate as do
workers. Production requires one worker and one firm; firms can really
be thought of as another type of labor input, such as an
"entrepreneur." A firm-worker pair produces p units of the
homogeneous output per unit of time. We assume that the value of
production for a pair always exceeds the value of not working for a
worker, i.e., that p > b > 0. (9) There is no cost for a firm to
enter the labor market.
The Frictional Labor Market
In a "frictional" labor market, firms and workers do not
meet instantaneously. In addition, firms that want to meet workers have
to use resources to post a vacancy. In particular, a firm has to pay c
units of output per unit of time it posts a "vacancy." Let the
number of idle firms that have an open position be denoted v(t), and let
the number of unemployed workers be u(t). Lack of coordination, partial
information, and heterogeneity of vacancies and workers are all factors
that make trading in the labor market costly.
We do not model these labor market frictions explicitly but use the
concept of a matching function as a reduced form representation of the
frictions. (10) This formulation specifies that the rate at which new
matches, m, are created is given by a time-invariant function, M, of the
number of unemployed workers searching for a job and the number of
vacant positions: m = M(u, v). At this point, we will assume that M is
(1) increasing and strictly concave in each argument separately and (2)
constant returns to scale (CRS) in both arguments. Thus, matches are
more likely when more workers and firms are searching, but holding
constant the size of one of the searching groups, there are decreasing
marginal returns in matching.
New matches are formed according to Poisson processes with arrival
rates [[lambda].sub.w] and [[lambda].sub.f]. Given the rate at which new
matches are formed, the rate at which an unemployed worker meets a firm
is simply [[lambda].sub.w](t) = m(t)/u(t), the total number of
successful matches per worker searching. Similarly, the rate at which a
vacant firm meets a worker is [[lambda].sub.f](t) = m(t)/v(t). Since the
matching function is CRS, the two meeting rates depend on labor market
tightness, [theta](t) = v (t)/u (t), only:
[[lambda].sub.w] (t) = M [1, [theta] (t)] and [[lambda].sub.f] (t)
= M [1/[theta] (t), 1]. (1)
As the relative number of vacancies increases, the job-finding
rate, [[lambda].sub.w], also increases, but the worker-finding rate,
[[lambda].sub.f], decreases. We assume that once a firm and a worker
have been matched, they remain matched until "separation"
occurs. Separation occurs according to a Poisson process with exogenous
arrival rate, [sigma].
If an unemployed worker meets vacant firms according to a Poisson
process with arrival rate, [[lambda].sub.w], then the probability that
the worker meets exactly one vacant firm during a time period, [DELTA],
is [[lambda].sub.w][DELTA] if the time period is sufficiently short.
Furthermore, the probability that a worker meets two or more vacant
firms during this time period is essentially zero. (11) Similarly, the
probability that a vacant firm meets an unemployed worker is
[[lambda].sub.f][DELTA], and the probability that a matched firm-worker
pair separates is [sigma][DELTA]. Thus, if we start out with u (t)
unemployed workers and 1 - u (t) employed workers at time t, after a
short time period, [DELTA], the number of unemployed workers will be
u (t + [DELTA]) = [sigma][DELTA][1 - u(t)] + [1 -
[[lambda].sub.w](t)[DELTA]]u(t).
Subtracting u (t) from either side of this expression, dividing by
[DELTA], and taking the limit when the length of the time period goes to
zero, we obtain
[dot.u](t) = [lim.[[DELTA][right arrow]0]][[u(t + [DELTA]) -
u(t)]/[DELTA]] = [sigma] [1 - u(t)] - [[lambda].sub.w](t)u(t). (2)
Here [dot.u](t) denotes the time derivative (change per unit of
time) of u(t): [dot.u](t) = [partial derivative]u(t)/[partial
derivative]t. This equation captures that the change in unemployment is
the flow into unemployment (the number of employed workers times the
rate at which they separate) minus the flow from unemployment (the
number of unemployed workers times the rate at which they find a job).
The dynamic evolution of unemployment is one of the key concerns in
this model. Notice, however, that the job-finding rate for workers,
[[lambda].sub.w](t), in equation (2) depends on vacancies through labor
market tightness, [theta] (t). What determines vacancies, v(t)? In order
to answer this question, we need to describe what determines profits for
entering firms, which in turn requires us to discuss what wages workers
receive.
With matching frictions, both workers and firms have some
bargaining power since neither party can be replaced instantaneously, as
is commonly assumed in competitive settings. There is a variety of
theories that describe how bargaining allocates output between firms and
workers under these circumstances. Below we will determine wages
according to the widely used Nash-bargaining solution. For simplicity,
from now on we will mainly consider steady states, situations in which
all aggregate variables are stationary over time. Thus, u(t), v(t),
[[lambda].sub.w](t), and [[lambda].sub.f](t) are all constant, even
though individual workers and firms face uncertainty in their particular
experiences.
3. STATIONARY EQUILIBRIUM
Values
Denote the net present value of a matched firm J (which in general
would depend on time but in a steady state does not). Given output, p,
and the wage, w, paid to its worker, J must satisfy
rJ = p - w - [sigma] (J - V), (3)
where V is the value of the firm when unmatched. This equation is
written in flow form and is interpreted as follows: the flow return of
being matched--the capital value of being matched times the rate of
return on that value--equals the flow profits minus the expected capital
loss resulting from match separation--the rate at which the firm is
separated, [sigma], times the latter capital loss equals J - V. (12)
Similarly, the value of a vacant firm satisfies
rV = -c + [[lambda].sub.f] (J - V). (4)
Here, there is a flow loss due to the vacancy posting cost and an
expected capital gain from the chance of meeting a worker.
Turning to the net present value of a matched worker, W, and an
unemployed worker, U, we similarly have
rW = w - [sigma] (W - U), and (5)
rU = b + [[lambda].sub.w] (W - U). (6)
The flow return from not working, b, could be a monetary
unemployment benefit collected from the government, a monetary benefit
from working in an informal market activity, or the monetary equivalent
of not working in any market activity (the value of being at home). We
will discuss the role and interpretation of b more extensively below,
because it turns out that it matters how one thinks of this parameter.
Wage Determination
The values of (un)matched workers and firms depend on the
wages--yet to be determined--paid in a match. Obviously, for a match to
be maintained it must be beneficial for both the worker, W - U [greater
than or equal to] 0, and the firm, J - V [greater than or equal to] 0.
We define the total surplus of a match, S [equivalent to] (J - V) + (W -
U), as the sum of the gain of the firm and worker being in a match
relative to not being in a match. We assume that the wage is set such
that the total match surplus is shared between the worker and firm
according to the Nash-bargaining solution with share parameter [beta]:
(13)
W - U = [beta]S and J - V = (1 - [beta]) S. (7)
Summing the value equations for matched pairs and subtracting the
values of unmatched firms and workers, using the Nash-bargaining rule,
we therefore obtain
rS = p - [sigma]S + c - [[lambda].sub.f] (1 - [beta])S - b -
[[lambda].sub.w][beta]S, (8)
which implies that
S = [p + c - b]/[r + [sigma] + (1 - [beta]) [[lambda].sub.f] +
[beta][[lambda].sub.w]]. (9)
That is, we can express the surplus as a function of the primitives
and the matching rates, which are endogenous and will be determined by
the free entry of firms as shown below. We see that the surplus from
being in a match is
* decreasing in the interest rate (a higher interest rate reduces
the present value of remaining in the match),
* decreasing in the separation rate (a higher separation rate
lowers the expected value of remaining together),
* decreasing in the bargaining share of workers times the rate at
which they meet vacant firms (the higher the chance that unemployed
workers meet vacant firms and the higher the share that workers receive
in that case, the less valuable it is to be matched now), and
* decreasing in the bargaining share of firms times the rate at
which vacant firms meet unemployed workers (the higher the chance that
vacant firms meet unemployed workers and the higher the share that firms
receive in that case, the less valuable it is to be matched now).
To derive a useful expression for the wage, subtract rV from the
value equation for matched firms, (3), and use the Nash-bargaining rule
to obtain
r (1 - [beta])S = p - w - [sigma] (1 - [beta])S - rV. (10)
Also, notice that given the surplus sharing rule, (7), and the
expressions for the vacancy and unemployment values, (4) and (6), the
surplus in (8) can be written as
rS = p - [sigma] S - rV - rU. (11)
Now multiply equation (11) by 1 - [beta], subtract it from equation
(10), and solve for the wage:
w = [beta] (p - rV) + (1 - [beta])rU. (12)
Thus, the wage is a weighted average of productivity minus the flow
value of a vacancy and the flow value of unemployment with the weights
being [beta] and 1 - [beta], respectively. Intuitively, one can
understand this equation as follows: w - rU, the flow advantage of being
matched for a worker, is just its share, [beta], of the overall
advantage of being matched for the worker and the firm together,
[beta](p - rV - rU).
Firm Entry
There is an infinite supply of firms that can post vacancies, and
entry is costless. Therefore, in an equilibrium with a finite number of
firms posting vacancies, the value of a posted vacancy is zero:
V = 0. (13)
If V < 0, no firm would enter, and if V > 0, an infinite
number of firms would enter. This means that the number of vacancies,
v(t), adjusts at each point in time so that there are zero profits from
entering, given the matching rate with workers, [[lambda].sub.f], which
depends on u(t) and on v(t).
The free-entry condition (13), together with the definition of the
vacancy value (4) and the surplus sharing rule (7) then determine the
surplus value:
S = c/[(1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.f]] (14)
Moreover, we can use the free-entry condition to simplify the
expression for the surplus in (9); the surplus can now be expressed as
S = [p - b]/[r + [sigma] + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]. (15)
These two expressions for the surplus can be combined to write
[p - b]/[r + [sigma] + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]] = c/[(1 -
[beta])[[lambda].sub.f]]. (16)
This is an equation in one unknown, labor market tightness
([theta]), since both meeting rates ([[lambda].sub.w] and
[[lambda].sub.f]) depend only on the number of vacancies relative to the
unemployment rate (see equation (1)).
We also see that free entry implies that the wage expression (12)
simplifies to
w = [beta]p + (1 - [beta])rU. (17)
Equilibrium Unemployment
In a steady state, [dot.u](t) = 0, so the evolution for
unemployment as given by equation (2) becomes
[sigma] (1 - u) = [[lambda].sub.w]u. (18)
Thus, in a steady state, the flow into unemployment--the separation
rate in existing matches times the number of matches--must equal the
flow out of unemployment--the job-finding rate times the number of
unemployed.
The steady state expression for unemployment can, on the one hand,
be used to express unemployment as a simple function of the separation
rate and the job-finding rate. On the other hand, it can be used to
write the job-finding rate in terms of the unemployment rate and the
separation rate. If we know, for example, that the unemployment rate is
10 percent and that the monthly separation rate is 5 percent, then the
chance of finding a job within a month must be [sigma] [[1-u]/u] = 0.05
* [0.9/0.1] = 0.45; that is, just under one-half.
Solving the Model
Solving the model is now straightforward. We have derived (16) and
(18) in two unknowns, [theta] and u. Furthermore we can solve the two
equations sequentially. First, from (1) it follows that [[lambda].sub.w]
([[lambda].sub.f]) is increasing (decreasing) in [theta]. This, in turn,
implies that the left-hand side (LHS) of (16) is decreasing in [theta]
and that the right-hand side (RHS) is increasing in [theta]. Thus, if a
solution, [theta], to (16) exists, it is unique. Second, conditional on
[theta], we can solve (18) for the equilibrium unemployment rate.
One can show that a solution to (16) exists if we assume that the
matching function satisfies the Inada conditions. (14) We assume a
particular functional form for the matching function that meets these
conditions and that is the most common one in the literature, the
Cobb-Douglas (CD) matching function,
M(u, v) = A[u.sup.[alpha]][v.sup.1-[alpha]]. (19)
The CD matching function has convenient properties in terms of how
the matching rates change with changes in labor market tightness,
[[lambda].sub.w] = A[[theta].sup.1-[alpha]] and [[lambda].sub.f] =
A[[theta].sup.-[alpha]]. (20)
Independent of the level of unemployment, if the labor market
tightness increases by 1 percent, the rate at which a worker (firm)
finds a firm (worker) goes up (down) by 1 - [alpha] ([alpha]) percent.
(15)
Using the CD matching function, our equilibrium condition, (16),
becomes
[p - b]/[r + [sigma] + [beta]A [[theta].sup.1-[alpha]]] = c /[(1 -
[beta])A[[theta].sup.-[alpha]]]. (21)
For [theta] = 0, the LHS of (21) is finite and positive, and the
RHS is zero. As [theta] becomes arbitrarily large, the LHS converges to
zero and the RHS becomes arbitrarily large. Thus there exists a positive
[theta] that solves (21). The unemployment rate then can be solved for
in a second step, using (18), as
u = [sigma]/[[sigma] + A[[theta].sup.1-[alpha]]]. (22)
We obtain the wage by using the definitions of the matching rates,
(20), and substituting the expressions for rU and the value of S, (6),
and (15) in wage equation (17):
w = [beta]p + (1 - [beta]) (b + [[[beta]c]/[1 - [beta]]] [theta]) =
[beta] (p + c[theta]) + (1 - [beta])b. (23)
A Digression: The Frictionless Model
We now show that as search frictions become small, the equilibrium
of the economy with matching frictions converges to the equilibrium of
the corresponding economy without matching frictions. Search frictions
can become small either because the cost of searching for vacant firms,
c, becomes small or because the efficiency of the matching process, A,
improves.
The frictionless economy is identical to the one outlined so far,
except that matching between vacant firms and unemployed workers is
instantaneous and costless. The resource allocation problem in the
frictionless economy, which can be studied from the perspective of a
benevolent social planner, is trivial. There will always be the same
number of firms as workers operating because there is no cost in
creating vacancies, and the matching process is instantaneous. Leaving
workers idle would therefore be inefficient since p > b. There are no
vacancies since matching is instantaneous. There is a competitive
equilibrium that supports this allocation given some wage rates, w(t),
specified at all points in time. It is clear that for these wages, w(t)
must equal p for all t because workers are in short supply, and firms
are not. That is, firm entry bids down profits to zero, and workers
obtain the entire output.
Now suppose that the vacancy-posting costs become arbitrarily
small: c [right arrow] 0. Then for any finite [theta], the LHS of (21)
is strictly positive, but the RHS converges to zero. Therefore, it must
be that [theta] [right arrow] [infinity]. To find the wage, some care
must be taken, since the wage expression contains c[theta], i.e., 0 *
[infinity]. Since workers meet firms at an ever-increasing rate,
[[lambda].sub.w] [right arrow] [infinity], the unemployment rate becomes
arbitrarily small, u [right arrow] 0, and from equation (9) it follows
that the surplus from being in a match becomes arbitrarily small: S
[right arrow] 0. Then simply inspect (10), which implies that w [right
arrow] p, as expected: workers obtain the whole production value.
The same kind of result is obtained if the matching efficiency
becomes arbitrarily large, A [right arrow] [infinity]. Now, however,
there will be no vacancies, and [theta] will remain finite. To see this
formally, multiply (21) with A[[theta].sup.-[alpha]], divide the
numerator and denominator of the LHS by A, and take the limit as A
[right arrow] [infinity]:
[p - b]/[[beta][[theta].sub.[infinity]]] = c/[1 - [beta]].
Since [[theta].sub.[infinity]] = [lim.sub.A[right
arrow][infinity]][theta](A) is finite, the limits of both
[[lambda].sub.f] and [[lambda].sub.w] are infinite. Thus from equation
(9) it follows that the limit of the surplus is zero; from (22) it
follows that the limit of the unemployment rate is zero; and from (10)
it follows that the limit of the wage again must equal p. Since
[[theta].sub.[infinity]] is positive and finite, [v.sub.[infinity]] must
equal 0 since [u.sub.[infinity]] equals 0. There is no unemployment, and
there are no vacancies.
4. TRANSITION DYNAMICS
So far, we have discussed how the key endogenous
variables--unemployment, vacancies, job-finding rates, and wages--are
determined in steady state. But how does the economy behave out of a
steady state? To answer this question, one needs to find out what the
economy's state variables are. A state variable is a variable that
is predetermined at time t and that matters to outcomes. Here,
unemployment is clearly a state variable, because it is a variable that
moves slowly over time according to (2). In fact, it is the only state
variable. No other variable is predetermined. This means that, in
general, allocations at t depend on u(t) but not on anything else.
So what is a dynamic equilibrium path of the economy if it starts
with an arbitrary u(0) at time zero? It turns out that the equilibrium
is very easy to characterize. All variables except u(t) and v(t) will be
constant over time from the very beginning. (16) To show that this is
indeed an equilibrium, simply assume that [theta] is constant from the
beginning of time and equal to its steady state value and then verify
that all equilibrium conditions are satisfied. Since [theta] is
constant, all job-finding rates--[[lambda].sub.w](t) and
[[lambda].sub.f] (t)--will be constant and equal to their steady state
values because they depend on [theta] and on nothing else. Since the
[lambda]s are the only determinants of the values J, V, W, and U, the
solution for the values will be the same as the steady state solution.
It then also follows that the wage must be the steady state wage. To
find u(t) and v(t), we conclude that u(t) will simply follow
[dot.u](t) = [sigma][1 - u(t)] - [[lambda].sub.w]u(t), (24)
which differs from (2) only in that [[lambda].sub.w] is now
constant. Once we have solved for u(t), we can find the path for v(t)
residually from v(t) = [theta]u(t). Moreover, note that if u(0) is above
the steady state, u, the RHS of equation (24) is negative, which means
that [dot.u](0) is negative. Unemployment falls, and as long as it is
still above u, it continues falling until it reaches (converges to) u.
Similarly, if it starts below u, it rises monotonically over time toward
u. (17)
The fundamental insight here is that there are no frictions
involved in firm entry, but there are frictions in movement of workers
in and out of jobs. (18) Therefore, u(t) is restricted to follow a
differential equation which is "slow-moving," whereas v(t)
does not have to satisfy such an equation. It can jump instantaneously
to whatever is has to be so that [theta] is equal to its steady state
value from the beginning of time.
5. COMPARATIVE STATICS
We now analyze how different parameters influence the endogenous
variables. In particular, how does unemployment respond to changes in
productivity? Here, we emphasize that these are steady state
comparisons. We find the long-run effect of the permanent change in the
parameter. For most variables--all except u(t) and v(t)--the impact of a
permanent change in the parameter is instantaneous because [theta]
immediately moves to its new, long-run value (see the discussion in the
previous section). Of course, in the section below where some of the
primitives are stochastic, their changes need not be permanent, and
slightly different results apply.
For example, if we are looking at a 1 percent permanent increase in
productivity, p, the comparative statics analysis in this section will
correctly describe the effect on [theta] both in the long and in the
short run, whereas the effect on unemployment recorded here only
pertains to how it will change in the long run. The short-run effect on
unemployment of a permanent change in a parameter is straightforward to
derive, nevertheless: It simply involves tracing out the new dynamics
implied by the linear differential equation (24) evaluated at the new
permanent value for [[lambda].sub.w] (which instantaneously adopts its
new value because [theta] does). In particular, one sees from the
differential equation that an increase in [theta] will increase
[[lambda].sub.w] and thus increase the speed of adjustment to the new
steady state rate of unemployment.
We are mainly interested in how the economy responds to changes in
p, but we will also record the responses to b, [sigma], and c. We
compute elasticities, i.e., we use percentage changes and ask by what
percent [theta] and u will change when p, b, [sigma], and, c change by 1
percent. We derive the relevant expressions by employing standard
comparative statics differentiation of (21) and (22). Using [^.x] to
denote d log (x) = dx/x, it is straightforward to derive
[^.[theta]] = [[r + [sigma] + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]/[[alpha](r +
[sigma]) + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]] [[p/[p-b]][^.p] - [b/[p-b]][^.b] -
[[sigma]/[r + [sigma] + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]] [^.[sigma]] - [^.c]],
and (25)
[^.u] = (1 - u) [[^.[sigma]] - (1 - [alpha]) [^.[theta]]]. (26)
The Effect of an Increase in Productivity
From equation (25), we see that an increase in p of 1 percent leads
to more than a 1 percent increase in [theta] since [alpha] < 1, and p
> b > 0. Intuitively, p increases the value of matches, and given
that firms capture some of the benefits of this increase in value, there
will be an increase in the number of firms per worker seeking to match.
The larger the fraction of the surplus going to the firm ([beta] small),
the more vacancies and market tightness will respond to a change in
labor productivity. We also see that to the extent that b is close to p,
the effect can be large, since p/(p - b) can be arbitrarily large. Why
is this effect larger the closer b is to p? When (p - b) [equivalent] 0,
the profit from creating vacancies is small, and [theta] [equivalent] 0.
Hence, even a small change in p induces very large changes in
firms' profits and market tightness, [theta], in percentage terms,
through the free-entry condition (21).
Because the job-finding rate, [[lambda].sub.w], equals
A[[theta].sup.1-[alpha]], we obtain that [^.[lambda].sub.[omega]] = (1 -
[alpha]) [^.[theta]], so the effect of p on [theta] is higher than that
on job-finding rates by a constant factor, 1/(1 - [alpha]). If we look
at the effect on unemployment, note from (26) that a 1 percent increase
in [theta] lowers unemployment by (1 - u) (1 - [alpha]) percent.
The Effects of Changing b, [sigma], and c
Changes in income when unemployed, b, have a very similar effect to
productivity changes, p, but with an opposite sign. Increasing b, in
particular, lowers [theta] significantly if b is near p, but it has very
little effect on [theta] if b is close to zero. An increase in the match
separation rate, [sigma], decreases labor market tightness. More
frequent separations reduce the expected profits from creating a
vacancy, and, thus, [theta] falls. The effects on labor market tightness
of higher vacancy-posting costs, c, are negative as well. A 1 percent
increase in the vacancy cost lowers the labor market tightness (by less
than 1 percent) because it requires firms' finding rates to go up
in order to preserve zero profits, and, hence, there must be fewer
vacant firms relative to unemployed workers. There is less than a
one-for-one decrease because the surplus, once matched, increases as
well, as is clear from equations (14) and (15).
The effects on the job-finding rate of all the above changes in
primitives are all one minus [alpha] times the effect on [^.[theta]].
Similarly, the effects on unemployment are -(1 - u)(1 - [alpha]) times
those on [^.[theta]], with the exception of a change in [sigma] because
from (22), the total effect on unemployment of a rise in [sigma] by 1
percent is twofold. The first effect is an indirect decrease through the
impact on [theta] (a higher [sigma] leads to a higher [theta]), which
lowers unemployment. The second effect is a direct increase of
unemployment due to the higher rate at which matches separate. The total
effect cannot be signed without more detailed assumptions; for example,
if [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 1/2, the net effect is to increase
unemployment.
An Additional Friction: Rigid Wages
In the model just described, productivity changes arguably have
such a small impact on labor market tightness and unemployment that they
cannot account for the observed fluctuations in the data. Hall (2005)
and Shimer (2004) suggest that one way to address this shortcoming is to
change the wage-setting assumption. We now describe a very simple model
that captures this idea.
The values for workers and entrepreneurs continue to be defined by
equations (3), (4), (5), and (6). Now, assume that wages are fixed at
some exogenous level, [bar.w], such that the implied capital values for
entrepreneurs and workers satisfy J > 0 and W > U. Hall (2005)
justifies this assumption on wage determination as a possible
sustainable outcome of a bargaining game. The new equilibrium
zero-profit condition from a vacancy creation is
[p - [bar.w]]/[r + [sigma]] = c/[[lambda].sub.f] =
c/[A[[theta].sup.-[alpha]]]. (27)
It follows that the impact of a change in labor productivity on
market tightness is given by
[^.[theta]] = [p/[[alpha](p - [bar.w])]][^.p]. (28)
Comparing this last expression to that in equation (25), we see
that the rigid-wage model gives a stronger response. In particular,
independent of b, if the average wage, [bar.w], is large as a fraction
of output (i.e., if the labor share is large), then market tightness
will be very sensitive to small changes in productivity.
The effect on unemployment, given the changes in [theta], is the
same whether or not wages are rigid, as given by equation (26). Finally,
a comparison of equations (21) and (27), reveals that by choosing a
value for the worker's bargaining power, [beta], close to zero in
the model with Nash bargaining, one achieves essentially rigid wages,
since w is then almost the same as b.
6. CALIBRATION
In the previous section on comparative statics we demonstrated how
steady states change when primitives change. In particular, we have
analyzed qualitatively how a permanent productivity change affects labor
market tightness (recall that the effect is the same in the short as
well as in the long run) and how it influences unemployment in the long
run. However, what are the magnitudes of these effects? In order to
answer this question we need to assign values to the parameters, and we
will do this using "calibration." We will, to the extent
possible, select parameter values based on long-run or microeconomic data. Hence, we will not necessarily select those parameters that give
the best fit for the time series of vacancies and unemployment, since we
restrict the parameters to match other facts.
The parameters of the model are seven: [beta], b, p, [sigma], c, A,
and [alpha]. The steady state equations that one can use for the
calibration are three: (21), (22), and (23). Some aspects of the
calibration are relatively uncontroversial, but as we will see below,
some other aspects are not. Therefore, we organize our discussion in two
parts. We first describe how to assign values to the subset of
parameters that allows relatively little choice. We then discuss the
remaining parameters and show how, depending on what data one uses to
calibrate these, different parameter selections may be reasonable. We
also explain why this is a crucial issue--the effect of productivity
changes for vacancies, and unemployment may differ greatly across
calibrations. We summarize the different calibration procedures in Table
2.
Basic Calibration ...
In this section, we follow the calibration in Shimer (2005). We
think of a unit of time as representing one quarter. Therefore, it is
natural to select r = 0.012, given that the annual real interest rates
have been around 5 percent. We choose the separation rate, [sigma] =
0.10, based on the observation that jobs last about two and a half years
on average. (19)
Job-finding rates in the data are estimated by Shimer to be 0.45
per month. Thus, a target for [[lambda].sub.w] of 1.35 per quarter seems
reasonable. Notice from equations (25), (26), and (28) that the response
of labor market tightness and the unemployment rate to changes in
productivity and other parameters does not depend on the worker-finding
rate, [[lambda].sub.f]. We therefore follow Shimer and simply normalize labor market tightness, [theta] = 1, so that the worker-finding rate is
equal to the job-finding rate. (20)
Next, consider the elasticity of the matching function: what should
[alpha] be? Shimer plots the logarithm of job-finding rates against
log(v/u) and observes something close to a straight line with a slope
coefficient of about 0.28, which the theory's formulation,
[[lambda].sub.w] = A[[theta].sup.1-[alpha]], says it should be.
Therefore, we set [alpha] = 0.72. Since we have set [theta] equal to one
and [[lambda].sub.w] equal to A[[theta].sup.1-[alpha]], it follows that
A = 1.35. From the condition determining steady state unemployment,
(22), we now obtain that 0.1(1.35 - u) = u, so that u is 6.9 percent,
which is roughly consistent with the data. Notice also that the system
of equilibrium conditions is homogeneous of degree one in c, p, and b.
Therefore, we normalize p = 1 in steady state.
It remains to select c, b, and [beta]. We have two equations left:
the wage equation, (23), and the free-entry equilibrium condition, (21),
which is the one that solves for [theta] in terms of primitives. We can
think of this latter equation as residually determining c once b and
[beta] have been selected. Two more aspects of the data therefore need
to be used in order to pin down b and [beta].
... but what are b and [beta]?
We now turn to the more contentious part of the calibration.
Completing Shimer's Calibration
It is common to regard b as being the monetary compensation for the
unemployed. The OECD (1996) computes average "replacement
rates" across countries, i.e., the ratio of benefits to average
wages, and concludes that, whereas typical European replacement rates
can be up to 0.70, replacement rates are at most 0.20 in the United
States. (21) Shimer (2005) sets b equal to 0.4, which is even beyond
this upper bound for the replacement rate since it turns out that the
wage is close to one in his calibration. One reason why b should be
higher than 0.2 is that it also includes the value of leisure associated
with unemployment. We will discuss some alternative ways to calibrate b
below.
Regarding [beta], it is common to appeal to the Hosios condition
for an efficient search. (22) This condition says that in an economy
like the present one, firm entry is socially efficient when the surplus
sharing parameter, [beta], is equal to the elasticity parameter of the
matching function, [alpha]. Thus, Shimer (2005) assumes that [beta] =
[alpha]. This is one possible choice, though it is not clear why one
should necessarily regard the real-world search outcome as efficient. In
conclusion, if [beta] = 0.72 and b = 0.4, from the free-entry condition
we obtain c = 0.324, and the calibration in Shimer (2005) is completed.
Note that Shimer does not use the wage equation in his calibration.
Alternative: Use the Wage Equation
Let us now look at an alternative way of calibrating the model that
exploits the wage equation. Hagedorn and Manovskii (2005) point to two
observations that arguably can be used to replace those used by Shimer
to calibrate b and [beta].
First, they argue that one can look at the size of profits in the
data. Referring to empirical studies, Hagedorn and Manovskii argue that
the profit share, which they identify as (p - w)/p in the model, is
about 0.03. (23) That is, this calibration strategy is equivalent to
selecting a wage share a few percentage points below one. Second, they
argue that one can look at how much wages respond to productivity. Using
microeconomic data, Hagedorn and Manovskii conclude that a 1 percent
productivity increase raises wages by half a percent. (24) We now show
how one can use these two observations to determine b and [beta].
The wage share. The wage income share in the model is obtained by
dividing the wage equation (23) by productivity:
[w/p] = [beta] (1 + [[c[theta]]/p]) + (1 - [beta])[b/p]. (29)
Rearranging the equilibrium condition (21) yields
[c[theta]]/p = [[(1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.w]]/[r + [sigma] +
[beta][[lambda].sub.w]]] (1 - [b/p]). (30)
It is informative to calculate the wage share implied by
Shimer's calculations. Now, given Shimer's preferred parameter
values,
[c[theta]]/p [approximately equal to] [[1 - [beta]]/[beta]] (1 -
[b/p])
since (r + [sigma]) is small relative to [[lambda].sub.w].
Therefore, with this expression inserted into (29), we conclude that
[w/p] [approximately equal to] 1,
meaning that calibration of the wage share to 0.97 will not by
itself be a large departure from Shimer's parameterization. Indeed,
Shimer obtains a wage share of w/p = 0.973.
However, there are several different choices of the pair (b/p,
[beta]) that can achieve this value of the labor share. To see this,
combine equations (29) and (30) by eliminating c[theta]/p:
[w/p] = [(r + [sigma]) [[beta] + (1 - [beta])b/p] +
[beta][[lambda].sub.w]]/[(r + [sigma]) + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]. (31)
Shimer chooses a relatively large value of [beta], which makes the
wage share in (31) close to one without imposing constraints on b/p.
Alternatively, [beta] can be set close to zero, in which case a value
for b/p needs to be around one. Recall that with b close to p, the
dynamic properties of the model change dramatically. The model has a
much stronger amplification mechanism, but how can one justify this
choice of [beta]?
The wage elasticity with respect to productivity. We differentiate
(31) in order to derive a relation between [[eta].sub.[theta]p]
[equivalent to] d log [theta]/d log p, the percentage change in [theta]
in response to a 1 percent increase in p, and [[eta].sub.wp] [equivalent
to] d log w/d log p (the corresponding measure for how wages respond to
productivity). We obtain
[[eta].sub.wp] = [[beta] [1 + (c[theta]/p)
[[eta].sub.[theta]p]]]/[w/p]. (32)
When r + [sigma] is small relative to [beta][[lambda].sub.w], as in
Shimer's calibration, the elasticity of labor market tightness with
respect to productivity satisfies
[[eta].sub.[theta]p] [approximately equal to] 1/[1 - b/p],
demonstrating that the wage elasticity must be
[[eta].sub.wp] [approximately equal to] 1/[w/p]
(it must be close to one if the labor share is near one). That is,
Shimer's calibration generates a one-for-one wage increase in
response to productivity, measured in percentage terms, which is twice
as large as the estimates cited by Hagedorn and Manovskii.
To obtain such a low elasticity, one needs to decrease [beta], so
that r + [sigma] is no longer small relative to [beta][[lambda].sub.w],
and this is how Hagedorn and Manovskii accomplish the task. A
combination of (32) and the exact expression for [[eta].sub.[theta]p]
from (25) allows us, after some simplifications, to solve for
[[eta].sub.wp] as
[[eta].sub.wp] = ([beta]/[w/p]) [[[alpha](r + [sigma]) +
[[lambda].sub.w]]/[[alpha](r + [sigma]) + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]]]. (33)
It is now easy to see that using the baseline (uncontroversial)
calibration together with w/p [approximately equal to] 1 and [beta] =
0.13 takes us to a number for [[eta].sub.wp] that is closer to one-half.
(25) Notice also that when [beta] is close to zero, the approximation that [[eta].sub.[theta]p] [approximately equal to] p/(p - b) is no
longer so good; rather, [[eta].sub.[theta]p] is significantly higher
than p/(p - b), thus further strengthening the amplification of shocks
in the model.
Put differently, if we restrict the model so that it generates a
weaker response of wages to productivity, then expression (33) tells us
that [beta] has to be significantly smaller. And as we saw before, that
(together with a wage share sufficiently close to one) totally changes
the dynamics of this model.
How does the calibration influence the amplification from
productivity to unemployment? As seen in (26), the transmission from
[theta] to u depends only on [alpha] and on u itself, so there is little
disagreement here. The contentious parts of the calibration do not
influence this channel. That is, the differences in the amplification of
unemployment between the alternative calibrations are inherited from the
differences in how these calibrations amplify labor market tightness.
Some Further Remarks on Calibration
What is the value of the labor share? Apparently, relatively minor
differences in how close the wage share is to one make a significant
difference in the results. It seems to us, however, that wage shares are
very difficult to calibrate properly without having the other major
input in the model, namely capital. Of course, some search/matching
models do allow an explicit role for capital. Pissarides (2000), for
example, discusses a matching model where firms, once they have matched,
rent capital in a frictionless market for capital. Thus, a neoclassical
(or other) production function can be used, and the wage share can be
calibrated to the ratio of wage income to total income using the
national income accounts. The relevant wage income share, however, is
then net of capital income, and the same applies to the definition of
output. Alternatively, in Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante (2005), we
assume that capital is purchased in competitive markets but that an
entrepreneur has to purchase capital first in order to be able to search
for a worker--in order to qualify as a "vacant firm." It is an
open question as to whether models with capital will also embody a
sensitivity of the amplification mechanism to the calibration of the
labor share.
What is the value for the wage elasticity? If one insists that
wages are less responsive to the cycle than what is implied by
Shimer's calibration, then there is more amplification from
productivity shocks, and the model's implications are closer to the
data. Hall (2005) maintains an even more extreme assumption that wages
are entirely rigid; this is why we considered a version of the model
with rigid wages. Going back to equation (28), we see that a rather
extreme outcome is produced, provided that we still calibrate so that
the wage share is close to one. Now inelastic wages and a high wage
share interact to boost the amplification mechanism. However, the model
has the counterfactual implication that the labor share, w/p, is
perfectly negatively correlated with output while only mildly
countercyclical in the data.
What is the value for the elasticity of unemployment to benefits?
Finally, a possible third clue for calibrating this model can be
obtained if one has information about how the economy responds to
changes in unemployment compensation. (26) Of course, the absence of
controlled experiments makes it difficult to ascertain the magnitude of
such effects. The upshot, however, is that if the response of [theta] to
p is large (because b is close to p), then the response of an increase
in unemployment compensation would be a very sharp decrease in [theta]
(and increase in unemployment). In particular, as explained in Section
5, the elasticity of the exit rate from unemployment with respect to b
equals (1 - [alpha]) times [[eta].sub.[theta]b]. Given [alpha] = 0.72,
the Hagedorn-Manovskii calibration implies that this elasticity equals
-6.3 (see Table 3). Thus, a 10 percent rise in unemployment benefits
would increase expected unemployment duration (1/[[lambda].sub.w]) by
roughly 60 percent.
The existing estimates of the elasticity of unemployment duration
with respect to the generosity of benefits, which are based on
"quasi-natural" experiments, are much smaller. Bover,
Arellano, and Bentolila (2002) find for Spain that not receiving
benefits increases the hazard rate at most by 10 percent, implying a
local elasticity of 0.1. For Canada, Fortin, Lacroix, and Drolet (2004)
exploit a change in the legislation that led to a rise in benefits by
145 percent for singles below age 30 and estimate an elasticity of the
hazard rate around 0.3. For Slovenia, van Ours and Vodopivec (2004)
conclude that the 1998 reform which cut benefits by 50 percent was
associated with a rise in the unemployment hazard by 30 percent at most,
implying an elasticity of 0.6. Finally, an earlier survey by Atkinson
and Micklewright (1991) argues that reasonable estimates lie between 0.1
and 1.0.
In sum, these estimates mean that the elasticity implied by the
Hagedorn-Manovskii parametrization is between six and sixty times larger
than the available estimates.
7. QUANTITATIVE RESULTS FOR THE DIFFERENT CALIBRATIONS
In this section, we show that the three alternative calibrations
discussed in Section 6 have very different quantitative implications for
the comparative statics discussed in Section 5. Note that, although the
values for certain key parameters--[beta] and b in particular--are
different, the steady state values of the key aggregate variables are
the same across parameterizations. The reason, as explained, is that
certain parameters are not uniquely identified in steady state.
Implications for [theta], [[lambda].sub.w], and u
Table 3 summarizes the results for the preferred calibrations of
Shimer, Hagedorn and Manovskii, and Hall. Recall that Hall's
parameterization has a constant wage.
With Shimer's calibration, the model has a very poor
amplification mechanism. (27) A 1 percent permanent rise in productivity
leads only to a 1.7 percent rise in market tightness, a response that is
below that in the data by a factor of 16. Similarly, unemployment and
the job-finding rate move very little in the wake of a productivity
change. Shimer attributes the failure of the model to the fact that,
with Nash bargaining, the wage is too closely linked to productivity and
absorbs too large a fraction of the productivity fluctuations. As a
result, profits do not rise enough to give firms the incentive to create
many additional vacancies.
Hall's calibration imposes a constant wage. (28) The
consequences of this assumption are striking: Market tightness and
unemployment respond almost 50 times more than in Shimer's baseline
model. Since wages are fixed, a rise in productivity translates entirely
into profits. Firms post many more vacancies, which also boost the
volatility of the job-finding rate, [[lambda].sub.w].
Hagedorn and Manovskii's calibration, finally, leads to the
best results for the volatility of market tightness and for the
job-finding rate with respect to productivity shocks: A 1 percent
productivity increase leads to a 20 percent increase of market tightness
and a 7 percent increase of the job-finding rate. The main problem,
however, is that this calibration induces what seems to be excessive
sensitivity of u to unemployment benefits b. The elasticity is about
six--almost 20 times larger than the number resulting from Shimer's
calibration. To interpret what this magnitude means, consider a policy
experiment where unemployment benefits are raised by 15 percent; the
unemployment rate would then double under Hagedorn and Manovskii's
calibration. (29)
Quantitative Implications for the Cyclicality of the Labor Share
From equation (32), it is straightforward to rewrite the elasticity
of wages, w, and the labor share, s, with respect to a productivity
shock, p, as
[^.w] = [[beta]/s][^.p] +
[beta][[c[theta]/p]/s][[eta].sub.[theta]p], and
[^.s] = [^.w] - [^.p],
where [[eta].sub.[theta]p] denotes the elasticity of [theta] with
respect to p.
For Hall's calibration, the implications are immediate--the
model has the counterfactual implication that the volatility of wages is
zero and that the correlation between the labor share and labor
productivity is minus one. With Shimer's calibration, [^.w]
[approximately equal to] 1.15, and, hence, wages respond one-for-one to
labor productivity, absorbing most of their impact, as explained above.
Compared to the data, wages are too volatile. The labor share is
essentially acyclical, in contrast with the data. Thus, the baseline
calibration of the matching model with a low b also fails along these
two dimensions.
Hagedorn and Manovskii's parameter choice is constructed to
match [^.w] = 0.5, and therefore [^.s] = -0.5. Under this
parameterization, the model is quite successful in matching the
elasticity of the labor share, since in the data, the labor share is
about as volatile as labor productivity and is countercyclical. Here, it
is evident that the choice made by Hagedorn and Manovskii of setting
[beta] near zero is useful since one can reconcile a large value for
[[eta].sub.[theta]p] with small fluctuations in the wage and a
countercyclical labor share.
8. THE MATCHING MODEL WITH AGGREGATE RISK
In the comparative statics exercise above we have studied how
long-run outcomes in our model economy respond to one-time permanent
changes in parameters. Yet we want to evaluate how well the model
matches the business cycle facts of the labor market, and the business
cycle is arguably better described by recurrent stochastic changes to
parameters. For this reason we now modify the model and include
stochastic productivity shocks that are persistent but not permanent.
One might conjecture that the difference between the effects of
one-time permanent shocks and persistent--but not permanent--shocks will
be smaller, the more persistent the shocks are. In this case the
difference between the comparative statics exercise and the analysis of
the explicit stochastic model might be small since labor productivity is
quite persistent. The autocorrelation coefficient is around 0.8 (see
Table 1). It turns out that the difference between the two approaches is
noticeable, but it does not overturn the basic conclusion from the
comparative statics analysis. If the calibration is such that wages
respond strongly to changes in productivity, then productivity shocks
cannot account for the volatility of the labor market.
The modified model can be analyzed in almost closed form--again
because free entry makes vacancies adjust immediately to any shock.
Thus, as before, unemployment is a state variable, but it will only
influence its own dynamics (and, residually, that of vacancies), whereas
all other variables will depend only on the exogenous stochastic shocks
in the economy. Again, the argument that backs this logic up proceeds by
construction: specify an equilibrium of this sort, and show that it
satisfies all the equilibrium conditions.
We will focus on a simple case in which the economy switches
between a low-productivity state, [p.sub.1] = p (1 - [mu]), and a
high-productivity state, [p.sub.2] = p (1 + [mu]), with [mu] > 0. The
switching takes place according to a Poisson process with arrival rate
[tau]. (30) The capital values of (un)matched firms and workers, (3) to
(6), are easily modified to incorporate the dependence on the aggregate
state of the economy:
r[J.sub.i] = [p.sub.i] - [w.sub.i] - [sigma] ([J.sub.i] -
[V.sub.i]) + [tau] ([J.sub.-i] - [J.sub.i]), (34)
r[V.sub.i] = -c + [[lambda].sub.f] ([[theta].sub.i]) ([J.sub.i] -
[V.sub.i]) + [tau] ([V.sub.-i] - [V.sub.i]), (35)
r[W.sub.i] = [w.sub.i] - [sigma] ([W.sub.i] - [U.sub.i]) + [tau]
([W.sub.-i] - [W.sub.i]), and (36)
r[U.sub.i] = b + [[lambda].sub.w] ([[theta].sub.i]) ([W.sub.i] -
[U.sub.i]) + [tau]([U.sub.-i] - [U.sub.i]), (37)
for i = 1, 2, where -i denotes 1 if i = 2 and vice versa. Each
value equation now includes an additional capital gain/loss term
associated with a change in the aggregate state. We continue to assume
that wages are determined to implement the Nash-bargaining solution for
the state-contingent surplus, [S.sub.i] = [J.sub.i] - [V.sub.i] +
[W.sub.i] - [U.sub.i], and that there is free entry: [V.sub.i] = 0.
We now apply the surplus value definition and the free-entry
condition to equations (34) to (37) in the same way as for the steady
state analysis in the previous sections. The equilibrium can then be
characterized by the following equations:
[r + [sigma] + [tau] + (1 -
[beta])[[lambda].sub.f]([[theta].sub.i]) + [beta][[lambda].sub.w]
([[theta].sub.i])][S.sub.i] = [p.sub.i] + c - b + [tau][S.sub.-i], (38)
[S.sub.i] = c/[(1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.f]([[theta].sub.i])] (39)
for i = 1, 2. Expression (38) for the surplus equation is the
counterpart of the steady state expression (9). Expression (39) simply
uses the free entry condition and the surplus sharing rule in (35).
The idea is to see how an increase in [mu] from zero--when [mu] =
0, we are formally in the previous model without aggregate shocks--will
influence labor market tightness: If p goes up by 1 percent, that is,
[mu] increases by 0.01, by how many percentage points does
[[theta].sub.1] go down and [[theta].sub.2] go up? And how does the
answer depend on [tau]? We will find answers with two different methods.
First we will use a local approximation around [mu] = 0, which allows us
to derive an elasticity analytically. Then we will look at a particular
value of [tau] > 0 and compute exact values for [[theta].sub.1] and
[[theta].sub.2].
Local Approximations
For a local approximation at a point where the two states are
identical ([mu] = 0), the equilibrium is symmetric such that
[[theta].sub.1] goes down by the same percentage amount by which
[[theta].sub.2] goes up. For this case, we can show explicitly how the
equilibrium elasticity depends on the persistence parameter, [tau].
First, substitute expression (39) for the surplus in expression
(38) and take the total derivative with respect to a change in
productivity [mu]. We obtain the following expression
{[alpha][r + [sigma] + [tau] + (1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.f,i] +
[beta][[lambda].sub.w,i]] + (1 - [alpha])[beta][[lambda].sub.w,i] -
[alpha](1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.f,i]}[[[eta].sub.i]/[[lambda].sub.f,i]]
= [tau][alpha][[[eta].sub.-i]/[[lambda].sub.f,-i]] + [[1 -
[beta]]/c](-1)[.sup.i] p, (40)
where [[eta].sub.i] [equivalent to] ([partial
derivative][[theta].sub.i]/[partial derivative][mu]) (1/[[theta].sub.i])
denotes the elasticity of tightness in state i with respect to a change
in productivity. Since we consider only a small productivity difference
across states, we approximate the terms in curly brackets by the
non-state-contingent steady state values for [mu] = 0. Furthermore,
since the equilibrium is symmetric, the solution is such that
[eta] = [[eta].sub.2] > 0 > [[eta].sub.1] = -[eta]. (41)
Using symmetry for the local approximation (40) we can solve for
the elasticity of labor market tightness:
[eta] = [(1 - [beta])[[lambda].sub.f]p]/[[[alpha](r + [sigma]) +
[beta][[lambda].sub.w] + 2[alpha][tau]]c]. (42)
Inspecting the result, we note that as the aggregate state becomes
more persistent, that is, [tau] converges to zero, the response of labor
market tightness to productivity converges to the response to a one-time
permanent shock. (31) In particular, the absolute value of the
elasticity is higher, the more persistent the shock is.
In Table 4, we display the elasticity of labor market tightness
with respect to labor productivity for our three different calibrations
and how the elasticity depends on the persistence of the aggregate
state. For the purpose of business cycle analysis, an average duration
of the state between 2.5 ([tau] = 0.1) and 5 years ([tau] = 0.05)
appears to be appropriate. We see that for business-cycle durations the
results differ from the [tau] = 0 case, which reproduces the numbers
from the comparative statics analysis for a one-time permanent shock.
This difference is most pronounced for the Hall calibration and the
Hagedorn and Manovskii calibration and less apparent for the Shimer
calibration. Recall that in the U.S. economy labor market tightness is
about 20 times as volatile as labor productivity (see Table 1). For an
arrival rate consistent with the persistence of business cycles, [tau]
[member of] [0.05, 0.1], productivity fluctuations cannot account for
fluctuations in labor market tightness for the Shimer calibration,
whereas for the Hagedorn and Manovskii calibration tightness is now
about 15 times more volatile than productivity. Furthermore, with less
than permanent shocks the Hall calibration now implies that tightness is
30 to 40 times as volatile as labor productivity, a much more reasonable
amplification than the factor of 80 implied by permanent shocks.
Exact Solution
In Table 5 we display exact results for a case in which a switch
from the low productivity to the high productivity represents a 1
percent change in productivity. For Shimer's calibration, this
results in a 1.6 percent change of labor market tightness. The
approximation in Table 4 for [tau] = 0.05 is quite close to the
elasticities reported in Table 5; thus, the accuracy of the
approximations is reasonable. For the Hagedorn and Manovskii calibration
and the Hall calibration, the local approximation of the elasticity in
Table 4 reflects an average of the true elasticities in Table 5.
9. CONCLUSION: WHERE NEXT?
We have reviewed recent literature that assesses the ability of the
search/matching model of the labor market to match some key
characteristics of labor markets, namely, the large fluctuations in
vacancies and in unemployment. We have, in particular, discussed what
features of a calibration seem necessary for matching the data within
the context of the standard model or of one augmented with an assumption
that real wages are rigid. In this discussion, we have tentatively
concluded that there is no wholly satisfactory calibration of the basic
setup or a simple alteration thereof that allows the key characteristics
of the data to be roughly reproduced. On the one hand, one can assume
that the value of being at home is almost as large as that of having a
job, but that seems somewhat implausible on a priori grounds, and it
implies that there must also be strong sensitivity of unemployment to
unemployment benefits, which arguably we do not observe. On the other
hand, one can assume rigid wages, but we show that rigid wages
necessitate a wage share close to one in order to be powerful in
creating large fluctuations in labor market variables, and this route
moreover produces an excessively volatile labor share.
It is an open question as to where one might go next. In our view,
it seems important to first examine a model with capital, because the
results we report above are very sensitive to the value of the labor
share. In a model with capital, there is no ambiguity about how one
should interpret the labor share. Moreover, a model with capital offers
another natural source of fluctuations in vacancies and unemployment,
namely, fluctuations in the price of investment goods. Such fluctuations
will directly influence the incentives for firms to enter/open new
vacancies, and, hence, seem a promising avenue for further inquiry.
REFERENCES
Andolfatto, David. 1996. "Business Cycles and Labor Market
Search." American Economic Review 86 (1): 112-32.
Atkinson, Anthony B., and John Micklewright. 1991.
"Unemployment Compensation and Labor Market Transitions: A Critical
Review." Journal of Economic Literature 29 (4): 1679-1727.
Bover, Olympia, Manuel Arellano, and Samuel Bentolila. 2002.
"Unemployment Duration, Benefit Duration and the Business
Cycle." Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society 112 (127): 223-65.
Costain, James S. and Michael Reiter. 2003. "Business Cycles,
Unemployment Insurance, and the Calibration of Matching Models."
CESifo Working Paper 1008.
Fisher, Jonas D.M. 2003. "Technology Shocks Matter."
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2002-14, rev. 2003.
Fortin, Bernard, Guy Lacroix, and Simon Drolet. 2004. "Welfare
Benefits and the Duration of Welfare Spells: Evidence from a Natural
Experiment in Canada." Journal of Public Economics 88 (7-8):
1495-1520.
Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 2000. "The
Role of Investment-Specific Technological Change in the Business
Cycle." European Economic Review 44 (1): 91-115.
Hagedorn, Marcus, and Iourii Manovskii. 2005. "The Cyclical
Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies Revisited."
Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.
Hall, Robert E. 2005. "Employment Fluctuations with
Equilibrium Wage Stickiness." American Economic Review 95 (March):
50-65.
Hornstein, Andreas, Giovanni L. Violante, and Per Krusell.
Forthcoming. "The Replacement Problem in Frictional Economies: A
Near Equivalence Result." Journal of the European Economic
Association.
Hosios, Arthur J. 1990. "On the Efficiency of Matching and
Related Models of Search and Unemployment." Review of Economic
Studies 57(2): 279-98.
Lagos, Ricardo. 2000. "An Alternative Approach to Search
Frictions." Journal of Political Economy 108 (October): 851-73.
Merz, Monika. 1995. "Search in the Labor Market and the Real
Business Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics 36 (2): 269-300.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1994. "Job
Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment." Review
of Economic Studies 61 (3): 397-416.
Nash, John F. 1950. "The Bargaining Problem."
Econometrica 18 (2): 155-62.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 1996. OECD
Employment Outlook. OECD: Paris.
Osborne, Martin J., and Ariel Rubinstein. 1990. Bargaining and
Markets. San Diego: Academic Press.
Petrongolo, Barbara, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2001.
"Looking into the Black Box: A Survey of the Matching
Function." Journal of Economic Literature 39 (2): 390-431.
Pissarides, Christopher A. 1985. "Short Run Equilibrium
Dynamics of Unemployment, Vacancies, and Real Wages." American
Economic Review 75 (4): 676-90.
__________. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd edition.
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Prescott, Edward C. 1986. "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle
Measurement." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review
10 (Fall): 9-22.
Rogerson, Richard, Robert Shimer, and Randall Wright. Forthcoming.
"Search-Theoretic Models of the Labor Market." Journal of
Economic Literature.
Shimer, Robert (2004). "The Consequences of Rigid Wages in
Search Models." Journal of the European Economic Association
(Papers and Proceedings) 2 (May-April), 469-79.
__________. 2005. "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium
Unemployment and Vacancies." American Economic Review 95 (March):
24-49.
van Ours, Jan C., and Milan Vodopivec. 2004. "How Changes in
Benefits Entitlement Affect Job-Finding: Lessons from the Slovenian
'Experiment.'" Institute for the Study of Labor Discussion Paper 1181.
Andreas Hornstein is with the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Per
Krusell is with Princeton University, the Institute for International
Economic Studies, CAERP, NBER, and CEPR. Gionanni L. Violante is with
New York University and CEPR. We wish to thank Kartik Athreya, Sam
Malek, Leo Martinez, and Ned Prescott for helpful comments. The views
expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
(1) For a textbook survey, see Pissarides (2000).
(2) We should note that Andolfatto (1996) and Merz (1995) were the
first to integrate the matching approach to the labor market into an
otherwise standard Walrasian model and to evaluate this model
quantitatively. Their work, however, was not so much focused on the
model's ability to match the behavior of unemployment, but on how
the introduction of labor market frictions affects the ability of the
otherwise standard Walrasian model to explain movements in employment,
hours worked, and other non-labor-market variables. Andolfatto (1996),
however, also pointed out the model's inability to generate enough
volatility in vacancies.
(3) To be precise, a large wage share is also sufficient for a
strong amplification mechanism with rigid wages. With flexible wages,
the large wage share must be achieved by making unemployment benefits
high.
(4) See Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell (2000) and Fisher (2003)
for a quantitative account of the role of this type of shock in U.S.
business cycles over the postwar period. Costain and Reiter (2003)
illustrate quantitatively that productivity shocks affecting only new
jobs improve the performance of the baseline model.
(5) The main reference is Pissarides (1985). Mortensen and
Pissarides (1994) extend the model to endogenous separations. Pissarides
(2000) contains an excellent survey of the matching models. See also
Rogerson, Shimer, and Wright (2005) for a recent survey.
(6) The view that aggregate fluctuations in output and unemployment
are due to fluctuations in productivity is not essential here. For the
given environment, one can interpret productivity shocks as actually
representing another source of fluctuations (such as "demand
shocks," e.g., shocks to preferences).
(7) Alternatively, one could assume that workers are risk-averse
but that they can obtain complete insurance against idiosyncratic income
risk. In this case, it would also be optimal for workers to maximize the
expected present value of income.
(8) Note that unemployment benefits do not serve an insurance role
in this environment since workers are either risk-neutral or they
already obtain complete insurance.
(9) This condition is necessary for ruling out a trivial
equilibrium with zero employment: if b > p, no worker would be
willing to work even if she could extract the entire value of the output
produced from the firm.
(10) The concept of an "aggregate matching function" has
been around for some time. In their survey of the literature on matching
functions, Petrolongo and Pissarides (2001) include a short history of
the concept. Lagos (2000) warns against the dangers of such a
"reduced-form approach" to frictions when, for example,
evaluating the effects of policies. The underlying reason is that
policies may affect the search behavior of agents and change the shape
of the aggregate matching function.
(11) Note that for a Poisson process, the rate [lambda] at which
the state changes need not be bounded above by one. Since we are
interested in the limiting case when the time interval, [DELTA], becomes
arbitrarily small, the probability of a state change, [lambda][DELTA],
will eventually be less than one for any fixed and finite [lambda].
(12) This equation is written in flow form but can be derived from
a discrete-time formulation analogous to the derivation of equation (2).
Suppose that the value of being vacant is constant over time from the
perspective of a matched firm and that we are looking at one period
being of length [DELTA]. During this period, there is production, and
wages are paid, the net amount being (p - w)[DELTA] since p and w are
measured per unit of time. At the end of the period, the match separates
with probability [sigma][DELTA] and remains intact with probability 1 -
[sigma][DELTA]. So it must be that J(t) = (p - w)[DELTA] + (1 -
[sigma][DELTA])[e.sup.-r[DELTA]]J(t + [DELTA]) +
[sigma][DELTA][e.sup.-r[DELTA]]V. Here, [e.sup.-r[DELTA]] [equivalent
to] [delta]([DELTA]) is a discount factor; it gives a percentage decline
in utility as a function of the length of time,
-(d[delta]([DELTA])/d[DELTA])/[delta]([DELTA]), which is constant and
equal to r. Subtract J(t + [DELTA])[e.sup.-r[DELTA]] on both sides and
divide by [DELTA]. That delivers [J(t) - J(t+[DELTA])]/[DELTA] +
[[(1-[e.sup.-r[DELTA]])]/[DELTA]]J(t + [DELTA]) = p - w -
[sigma][e.sup.-r[DELTA]](J(t + [DELTA]) - V). Take limits as [DELTA]
[right arrow] 0. Then the left-hand side becomes j(t) + rJ(t), the
second term coming from an application of l'Hopital's rule and
the value being a continuous function of time. The right-hand side gives
p - w - [sigma](J(t) - V). In a steady state, J(t) is constant and equal
to J, satisfying the equation in the text.
(13) The Nash-bargaining solution does not describe the outcome of
an explicit bargaining process; rather, it describes the unique outcome
among the set of all bargaining processes whose outcomes satisfy certain
axioms (Nash [1950]). Also, one can derive the Nash-bargaining solution
as the outcome of a bargaining process where participants make
alternating offers until they reach agreement. For a survey of the
bargaining problem, see Osborne and Rubinstein (1990).
(14) Let f ([theta]) = M ([theta], 1). Then the Inada conditions
are f (0) = 0, f ([infinity]) = [infinity], and f'(0) = [infinity].
(15) Shimer (2005) argues that the constant elasticity CD matching
function describes the data for the U.S. labor market well. See also
Section 7 on calibration.
(16) Pissarides (1985; 2000, Chapter 1) shows that this is the
unique equilibrium path.
(17) Formally, the solution for u(t) is the solution to the linear
differential equation (24): u(t) = u +
[e.sup.-([sigma]+[[lambda].sub.w])t](u(0) - u), where u =
[sigma]/[[sigma]+[[lambda].sub.w]].
(18) The speed of movements from unemployment into employment is
regulated by the hiring rate, [[lambda].sub.w], which, in turn, depends
on the endogenous market tightness, [theta]. Separations instead are
exogenous, and, hence, the speed of movements from employment to
unemployment is simply determined by the parameter, [sigma].
(19) For a Poisson process with arrival rate [sigma], the average
time to the arrival of the state change is 1/[sigma]. Thus, the average
time from forming a match to separation is 1/[sigma] = 10 quarters.
(20) Alternatively, we could have followed Hall (2005) and set the
monthly worker-finding rate to one so that [[lambda].sub.f] = 3,
implying that [theta] = 1/3. The value chosen for [theta] does not
influence our results.
(21) In the United States, unemployment insurance replaces around
60 percent of past earnings, but in the data, unemployed workers earn
much less than the average wage.
(22) See Hosios (1990). Free entry of firms involves an externality since individual vacant firms do not take into account that variations
in the vacancy rate affect the rate at which they meet unemployed
workers and the rate at which unemployed workers meet them.
(23) A pure aggregate profit measure should probably take the cost
of vacancies into account, and, as such, it should be computed somewhat
differently:
((1 - u)(p - w) - vc)/(p(1 - u)) = 1 - (w/p) - [theta](c/p)(u/(1 -
u)).
If this expression equals 0.03, one obtains a smaller wage share,
but since c must be less than one for zero profits to be feasible, w/p
cannot be below 0.97 - 1 * 1 * 0.05/0.95 ~ 0.92. Thus, both computations
lead to a wage share close to one.
(24) When we regress the cyclical component of wages on labor
productivity (see Table 1 for a description of the data), we obtain an
elasticity of 0.57 with the low smoothing parameter and 0.72 with
Shimer's smoothing parameter. The first number is higher than, but
not too distant from, Hagerdorn and Manovskii's preferred estimate
of 0.5. In particular, it is not statistically different from 0.5.
(25) Again, we need to remind the reader that our wage elasticity
is defined for a one-time permanent change of productivity. Hagedorn and
Manovskii (2005) base their analysis on an economy with recurrent and
persistent, but not permanent, shocks. Therefore, our calibration
results for various parameters can differ somewhat.
(26) This way of assessing matching models was proposed in Costain
and Reiter (2003).
(27) Though Table 3 contains information about the comparative
statics of separation rates, we focus the discussion on the effects of
productivity. Shimer (2005) shows that in terms of equation (1), most
unemployment volatility in the U.S. economy is accounted for by
variations in job creation (the job-finding rate), as opposed to job
destruction (the job-separation rate). Furthermore, as Table 3
demonstrates, variations in the job-separation rate have a negligible effect on the job-finding rate.
(28) For the calibration of Hall's sticky-wage model, we match
the wage income share and the unemployment benefits from the Shimer
calibration. In all other respects, the calibration is the same as for
the Shimer calibration.
(29) The fact that the Hagedorn and Manovskii parameters are chosen
such that wages do not respond strongly to changes in productivity
implies that wages respond strongly to changes in benefits. For the Hall
calibration, wages are simply assumed to be fixed, which imposes no
additional restrictions on calibration. Thus, even though wages are less
responsive than under Hagedorn and Manovskii, changes in b have no
impact on the equilibrium. When wages are fixed exogenously, the level
of benefits is irrelevant.
(30) The model can easily be extended to include a large but finite
number of exogenous aggregate states.
(31) To see this, combine the expression for the steady state
elasticity (25) with the steady state equilibrium condition (21).
Table 1 Aggregate Statistics: 1951:1-2004:4
HP Smoothing Parameter: [10.sup.5]
u v [theta] [[lambda].sub.w]
Standard Deviation 0.20 0.23 0.38 0.12
Autocorrelation 0.94 0.95 0.95 0.91
Correlation with p -0.40 0.31 0.38 0.38
HP Smoothing Parameter: 1600
u v [theta] [[lambda].sub.w]
Standard Deviation 0.13 0.14 0.26 NA
Autocorrelation 0.87 0.90 0.89 NA
Correlation with p -0.29 0.45 0.38 NA
HP Smoothing Parameter: [10.sup.5]
w s p
Standard Deviation 0.02 0.02 0.02
Autocorrelation 0.95 0.91 0.89
Correlation with p 0.69 -0.35 1.00
HP Smoothing Parameter: 1600
w s p
Standard Deviation 0.01 0.01 0.01
Autocorrelation 0.81 0.77 0.76
Correlation with p 0.72 -0.61 1.000
Notes: Data are quarterly, and u is the unemployment rate of the
civilian population; v is the help-wanted advertising index; [theta] =
v/u is labor market tightness; p is output per employee in the nonfarm
business sector; s is the labor share constructed as the ratio of
compensation of employees to output in the nonfarm sector; w is the wage
computed as labor share times labor productivity, i.e., w = s * p. The
statistics for the job-finding rate, [[lambda].sub.w], are those
reported in Shimer (2005) for an HP smoothing parameter of [10.sup.5].
Table 2 Parameters and Steady States for Calibrations
Common across Calibrations
r = 0.012, [alpha] = 0.72, p = 1, A = 1.35, [lambda] = 1.35,
[theta] = 1, u = 0.07
Specific to Calibrations
Shimer Hagedorn & Manovskii Hall
[beta] 0.72 0.05 NA
b 0.40 0.95 0.40
w/p 0.98 0.97 0.98
b/w 0.41 0.98 0.41
[[eta].sub.wp] 1.00 0.50 0.00
Table 3 Steady State Elasticities
Response of [theta] [[lambda].sub.w]
to change in p b [sigma] p b [sigma]
Shimer 1.72 -0.69 -0.07 0.48 -0.19 -0.02
Hagedorn & 23.72 -22.51 -0.08 6.64 -6.30 -0.02
Manovskii
Hall 81.70 0.00 -1.24 22.88 0.00 -0.35
Response of u
to change in p b [sigma]
Shimer -0.45 0.18 0.95
Hagedorn & -6.18 5.87 0.95
Manovskii
Hall -21.30 0.00 1.25
Table 4 Elasticity of Tightness with Respect to Productivity,
[[eta].sub.[theta]p]; Local Approximation
[tau] 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.05 0.10 0.50
Average Duration (in [infinity] 25.00 12.50 5.00 2.50 0.50
years)
Shimer 1.72 1.69 1.67 1.61 1.51 1.02
Hagedorn & Manovskii 23.67 21.59 19.85 15.98 12.06 4.07
Hall 81.70 69.32 60.20 43.16 29.33 8.23
Table 5 Elasticity of Tightness with Respect to Productivity; Exact
Solution for [mu] = 0.005 and [tau] = 0.05
1 to 2 2 to 1
Shimer 1.62 -1.60
Hagedorn & Manovskii 17.45 -14.85
Hall 54.52 -35.28