Monetary policy in the new neoclassical synthesis: a primer.
Goodfriend, Marvin
Great progress was made in the theory of monetary policy in the
last quarter century. Theory advanced on both the classical and the
Keynesian sides. New classical economists emphasized the importance of
intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. (1) Real business
cycle (RBC) theorists explored the role of productivity shocks in models
where monetary policy has relatively little effect on employment and
output. (2) Keynesian economists emphasized the role of monopolistic
competition, markups, and costly price adjustment in models where
monetary policy is central to macroeconomic fluctuations. (3) The new
neoclassical synthesis (NNS) incorporates elements from both the
classical and the Keynesian perspectives into a single framework. (4)
This "primer" provides an introduction to the benchmark NNS
macromodel and its recommendations for monetary policy.
The article begins in Section 1 by presenting a monopolistically
competitive core RBC model with perfectly flexible prices. The RBC core
emphasizes the role of expected future income prospects, the real wage,
and the real interest rate for household consumption and labor supply.
And it emphasizes the role of productivity shocks in determining output,
the real wage, and the real interest rate.
The NNS model introduced in Section 2 takes costly price adjustment
into account within the RBC core. In the NNS model, firms do not adjust
their prices flexibly to maintain a constant profit maximizing markup.
Instead, firms let the markup fluctuate in response to demand and cost
shocks. Markup variability plays a dual role in the new neoclassical
synthesis. As a guide to pricing decisions, the markup is central to the
evolution of inflation. As a "tax" on production and sales,
the markup is central to fluctuations in employment and output.
Section 3 locates the transmission of interest rate policy to
employment and inflation in its leverage over the markup. That leverage
creates the fundamental credibility problem of monetary policy: the
temptation to increase employment by compressing the markup jeopardizes
the central bank's credibility for low inflation. The nature of the
credibility problem is discussed in Section 3 together with the closely
related "inflation scare" problem that confronts monetary
policy in practice.
Section 4 traces the effects on employment and inflation of three
types of disturbances: optimism or pessimism about future income
prospects, a temporary productivity shock, and a shift in trend
productivity growth. It then tells how interest rate policy can
counteract such shocks. The combination of rational forward-looking
price setting by firms, monopolistic competition, and RBC components in
the benchmark NNS model provides considerable guidance for interest rate
policy. The recommended objectives and operational guidance are
developed and presented in Section 5. Section 6 addresses three
challenges to these policy recommendations. Section 7 is a summary and
conclusion.
1. THE CORE REAL BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL
The core monopolistically competitive real business cycle model is
presented in four subsections below: First, the representative
household's optimal lifetime consumption plan is derived, given its
lifetime income prospects and the real rate of interest. Second,
household labor supply is derived. Third, employment and income are
determined, taking account of the representative household's choice
of labor supply, firm profit maximization, and the economy's
production technology. Fourth, the real interest rate is determined,
emphasizing its role in clearing the economy-wide credit market and in
coordinating aggregate demand and supply.
Household Consumption (5)
The economy is populated by households that live for two periods,
the present and the future. (6) Households have lifetime income
prospects ([y.sub.1], [y.sub.2]) and access to a credit market where
they can borrow and lend at a real rate of interest r. A household
chooses its lifetime consumption plan ([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2]) given its
income prospects and the real rate of interest to maximize lifetime
utility subject to its lifetime budget constraint
[c.sub.2] = -(1 + r)[c.sub.1] + (1 + r)x (1)
where x = [y.sub.1] + [[y.sub.2]/[1+r]] is the present (period 1)
discounted value of lifetime income prospects.
A household obtains utility from lifetime consumption according to
U([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2]) = u([c.sub.1]) + [1/[1 +
[rho]]]u([c.sub.2]) (2)
where u([c.sub.1]) is utility from consumption in the present,
u([c.sub.2]) is utility from future consumption, U([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2])
is the present discounted value of lifetime utility from consumption,
and [rho] > 0 is a constant psychological rate of time discount. For
concreteness we work with log utility: u(c) = log c, so that u'(c)
= 1/c.
To maximize lifetime utility the household chooses its lifetime
consumption plan ([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2]) so that
(1 + r) = (1 + [rho])[[c.sub.2]/[c.sub.1]] (3)
where the household's choices for [c.sub.1] and [c.sub.2]
exhaust its lifetime budget constraint (1). (7) Below we see how
lifetime income prospects are determined and how the real interest rate
adjusts to reconcile desired aggregate household consumption with
aggregate output.
Household Labor Supply
The representative household must also choose how to allocate its
time to work and leisure. In deciding how much to work, a household
takes the real hourly wage in terms of consumption goods w as given in
the labor market. The household has a time budget constraint
l + n = 1 (4)
where l is time allocated to leisure, n is time allocated to work,
and the amount of time per period is normalized to 1. A household gets
utility directly from leisure. Leisure taken in the present and the
future contributes to lifetime utility as does consumption. Again we
work with log utility so that utility from leisure is given by v(l) =
log l and v'(l) = 1/l.
The allocation of time in a given period that maximizes the
household's utility is the one for which the marginal utility earned directly by taking leisure equals the marginal utility earned
indirectly by working
1/l = w/c. (5)
Using time constraint (4) to eliminate leisure l in (5) we can
express the household's willingness to supply labor [n.sup.s] as a
function of household consumption c and the real wage w
[n.sup.s] = 1 - [c/w]. (6)
Household labor supply (6) has three important features. First,
holding the wage w constant, household labor supply is inversely related
to household consumption. This makes sense because if the household is
able to consume more goods, say, because its lifetime income prospects
have improved, then it will wish to consume more leisure as well.
Second, holding consumption fixed, labor supply varies directly with the
real wage. This also makes sense because, other things the same, a
higher hourly wage increases the opportunity cost of leisure and makes
work more attractive. Third, if both consumption and the real wage rise
equiproportionally, then the effects on labor supply are exactly
offsetting. We see below that this last feature of labor supply is
important to account for some aspects of long-run economic growth.
Firms, Employment, and Output
There are a large number of firms in the economy, each producing a
different variety of consumption goods. Because their products are
somewhat different, firms are monopolistically competitive. Each firm
has enough pricing power in the market for its own output that it can
sustain a price somewhat above the marginal cost of production. Firms
face a constant elastic demand for their products, which means that the
profit maximizing markup of price over marginal cost is a constant [mu]*
> 1, invariant to shifts in demand or in the cost of production. (8)
For the remainder of Section 1, we assume that firms adjust their prices
flexibly to maintain the constant profit maximizing markup [mu]* at all
times. The demand for all varieties of goods is symmetric, so
consumption is treated as a single composite good.
Firms produce consumption goods c from labor input n according to
the production technology
c = a * n (7)
where a is labor productivity per hour in units of consumption
goods. Productivity a fluctuates and grows over time with technological
progress.
The markup of price over the marginal cost of production is defined
as
[mu] = [P/MC] (8)
where P is the dollar price of a unit of consumption goods, and MC
is the cost in dollars of producing a unit of consumption goods.
According to production technology (7), 1/a hours of work is needed to
produce a unit of c. If the hourly wage is W dollars, then the marginal
cost in dollars (unit labor cost) of producing a unit of consumption
goods is W/a. Substituting for MC in the definition of the markup and
rearranging yields
[mu] = a/[W/P] = a/w (9)
where w is the real wage.
Note that (9) uses only the production technology and the
definition of the markup to express the markup [mu] in terms of
productivity a and the real wage w. We see immediately from (9) that the
equilibrium real wage w* is determined as
w* = a/[mu]*. (10)
If firms adjust their product prices to maintain markup constancy,
the real wage grows and fluctuates only with productivity a. Since the
profit maximizing markup exceeds unity, [mu]* > 1, the real wage is
less than labor productivity w* < a. Firms are content to stop hiring
before bidding the real wage up to the marginal product of labor because
they maximize monopoly profit by restricting their own output somewhat.
To determine equilibrium employment n*, use (7) and (10) to
substitute for c and w in labor supply function (6)
[n.sup.s] = 1 - [[a * n]/[a/[mu]*]] (11)
and equate desired labor supply [n.sup.s] to labor utilized by
firms n to find equilibrium employment n*
n* = [1/[1 + [mu]*]]. (12)
Notice that equilibrium employment n* depends only on the profit
maximizing markup [mu]* and not on productivity a. The reason is that
productivity a affects consumption c and the real wage w proportionally
given hours worked n, so that the productivity effects operating through
consumption and the real wage in labor supply function (6) are exactly
offsetting. This feature of the core RBC model is necessary to account
for some fundamental facts about long-run economic growth. For instance,
labor productivity in the U.S. economy has grown by more than 2 percent
per year for over 100 years; and output and the real wage have both
grown at roughly the same rate. Yet the fraction of time allocated to
work has changed relatively little during that same period. (9)
Equilibrium output c* is determined from production technology (7)
and equilibrium employment (12) as
c* = a * [1/[1 + [mu]*]] (13)
where output c* grows and fluctuates proportionally with
productivity a.
The Real Interest Rate: Coordinating Demand with Supply (10)
To complete our understanding of the core RBC model, we must check
that households have sufficient income to purchase all the consumption
goods that firms produce each period and that households can be induced
to choose a lifetime consumption plan that matches the current and
future production of consumption goods. The real interest rate plays the
central role in aligning the demand and supply of consumption goods over
time.
Households have two sources of income. First, there is wage income
which equals the real wage multiplied by hours worked, wn. Second, there
is profit income which equals firms' revenue from sales minus the
wage bill, an - wn. Profits are positive because w < a. Since
households own the firms, total household income each period is the sum
of wage income and profit income wn + (an - wn) = an, which is exactly
the value of consumption goods produced and sold each period. Thus,
households do indeed earn enough income each period to buy the goods
produced in each period. It follows that the lifetime consumption plan
([c.sub.1], [c.sub.2]) that matches the current and future supply of
consumption goods given by (13), [c*.sub.1] = [a.sub.1] * [1/[1+[mu]*]]
and [c*.sub.2] = [a.sub.2] * [1/[1 + [mu]*]], also satisfies the
lifetime budget constraint (1).
The real interest rate r* that makes desired lifetime consumption
match the intertemporal supply of consumption goods is found by
substituting the current and future supply of consumption goods
([c*.sub.1], [c*.sub.2]) into condition (3)
(1 + r*) = (1 + [rho])[[[a.sub.2] * [1/[1+[mu]*]]]/[[a.sub.1] *
[1/[1+[mu]*]]]] = (1 + [rho]) [[a.sub.2]/[a.sub.1]] (14)
where we see that the equilibrium real interest rate r* varies
directly with the growth of labor productivity, [[a.sub.2]/[a.sub.1]].
One can understand the determination of the real interest rate as
follows: When productivity is stagnant ([a.sub.1] = [a.sub.2]),
households are satisfied with a flat lifetime consumption plan as long
as the real interest rate equals the psychological rate of time
preference (r* = [rho]). In that case, the return to lending exactly
offsets the preference for consuming in the present. On the other hand,
if future productivity is expected to be higher than current
productivity ([a.sub.1] < [a.sub.2]), then households want to borrow
against their brighter future income prospects to bring some consumption
forward in time. In the aggregate, however, households cannot do so
because the future productivity has not yet arrived. As households try
to borrow against the future, they drive the real interest rate up to
the point where they are satisfied with the steeply sloped consumption
plan that matches the growth of productivity. The equilibrium real
interest rate clears the economy-wide credit market by making the
representative household neither a borrower nor a lender. In so doing,
the equilibrium real interest rate also clears the economy-wide goods
market by inducing the representative household to spend its current
income exactly.
2. THE NEW NEOCLASSICAL SYNTHESIS
The new neoclassical synthesis (NNS) builds on the core real
business cycle (RBC) model to provide an understanding of fluctuations
in employment and inflation and a framework for thinking about monetary
policy. The main departure is that firms do not adjust their product
prices flexibly in the NNS model to maintain a constant profit
maximizing markup. Consequently, the markup fluctuates in response to
shocks to aggregate demand and productivity. The remainder of Section 2
explains why markup variability is central to fluctuations in inflation
and employment in the benchmark NNS model. Section 3 discusses how
monetary policy exerts its leverage over employment and inflation
through the markup. Section 4 considers various shocks in the NNS model
and explains how interest rate policy actions can counteract them. The
recommendations for monetary policy implied by the benchmark NNS model
are spelled out in Section 5.
Firm Pricing Practices, Inflation, and the Markup
It is costly for a firm producing a differentiated product to
determine the price that maximizes its profits at each point in time.
Pricing requires information on a firm's own demand and cost
conditions that is costly to obtain. Moreover, that information needs to
be assessed and processed collectively by top management. Management
must prioritize pricing decisions relative to other pressing concerns,
so pricing decisions get the attention of management only every so
often. (11) Hence, a firm considers whether to change its product price
only when demand or cost conditions are expected to move the actual
markup significantly and persistently away from the profit maximizing
markup. For instance, if higher nominal wages W, or lower productivity a
were expected to compress the markup significantly and persistently,
then it would be in the firm's interest to consider raising its
product price to restore the profit maximizing markup.
These points can be summarized in four pricing principles:
1) Firms would like to keep their actual markup [mu] as close to
the profit maximizing markup [mu]* as they can over time, subject to the
cost of changing their product prices.
2) Firms must balance the one-time cost of changing prices against
the benefit of staying close to the profit maximizing markup over time.
3) A firm is more apt to change its product price to restore the
profit maximizing markup the larger and more persistent it expects a
deviation of its actual markup from the profit maximizing markup to be.
4) Firms move their prices with expected inflation on average over
time.
The implications of these pricing principles for the economy-wide
rate of inflation [pi] may be summarized as follows:
[pi] = INF([[mu].sub.1], E[[mu].sub.2]) + E[pi] (15)
where E[pi] is the expected trend rate of inflation, and
INF([[mu].sub.1], [[mu].sub.2]) is a function indicating the effect of
the current and expected future markup on inflation. (12) When the
current and expected future markup both equal the profit maximizing
markup, then firms move their prices in accordance with expected trend
inflation E[pi], i.e., INF([mu]*, [mu]*) = 0. Markup compression ([mu]
< [mu]*) moves actual inflation above trend inflation, and markup
expansion ([mu] > [mu]*) moves actual inflation below trend
inflation.
We characterize increasingly inflationary situations as follows:
A) Absolute Price Stability: [[mu].sub.1] = E[[mu].sub.2] = [mu]*,
E[pi] = 0. Current and expected future markups equal the profit
maximizing markup, and expected trend inflation is zero.
B) Low Inflation Potential: [[mu].sub.1] < [mu]*, E[[mu].sub.2]
= [mu]*, E[pi] = 0. Current markup is compressed relative to the profit
maximizing markup, but the expected future markup is not, and expected
trend inflation is still zero.
C) Modest Inflation Potential: [[mu].sub.1] < [mu]*,
E[[mu].sub.2] < [mu]*, E[pi] = 0. Markup compression is expected to
persist, but expected trend inflation is still zero.
D) Persistent Trend Inflation: [[mu].sub.1] = E[[mu].sub.2] =
[mu]*, [pi] = E[pi] > 0. Current and expected future markups are at
their profit maximizing levels, but expected trend inflation is
positive.
Employment Fluctuations and the Markup
Inflation today is reasonably low and stable in the United States and around the developed world. Hence, we consider the nature of
employment fluctuations in the NNS model in terms of situations A and B
above. In other words, we suppose that the current markup may be
compressed or elevated relative to the profit maximizing markup, but
firms do not expect that gap to persist for very long. And firms expect
zero inflation. The central bank is said to have "credibility for
zero inflation" in these situations. When the central bank has
credibility for zero inflation, firms are disinclined to raise or lower
their product prices in response to a shock to their current markup
because they expect the markup shock to be temporary. (13) In such
circumstances, the current price level P is nearly invariant to current
shocks or current monetary policy actions. (14)
In this case current employment and output are determined by the
aggregate demand for goods. The reason is two-fold. First, each firm
faces a downward sloping demand for its particular variety of
consumption good, and a firm can sell only as much as households wish to
purchase at the going price. Second, firms are happy to produce and sell
as much as households are willing to buy because labor productivity
exceeds the real wage. Hence, holding product price constant, profits
rise with employment, production, and sales. Since firms can't sell
more than demand will allow and firms are happy to accommodate demand,
aggregate demand governs output in the short run, and output governs
employment given labor productivity. (15)
We can understand the determination of employment in the benchmark
NNS model from either a Keynesian or a classical perspective. The
Keynesian transmission mechanism runs from aggregate demand to
employment. The production technology c = an shows how employment n
depends on aggregate demand c and labor productivity a. Firms attract
enough labor to meet demand given labor productivity by offering a
nominal wage W sufficient to induce households to supply the required
labor input. Since the price level P is nearly invariant to current
economic conditions, the higher nominal wage raises the real wage w.
According to labor supply function (6) given aggregate demand c, a
higher real wage increases labor supply by raising the opportunity cost
of leisure. When demand falls and firms need less labor, wages fall
since enough labor supply is forthcoming at a lower real wage.
The classical perspective takes the view that actual employment n
must equal labor willingly supplied by households [n.sup.s] regardless
of the strength of aggregate demand. Working in this direction,
substitute c = an and w = a/[mu] into labor supply function (6), equate
n and [n.sup.s], and solve for employment to arrive at
n = [1/[1 + [mu]]]. (16)
From the classical perspective, employment in the NNS model is
determined inversely with the markup, exactly as in the core RBC model.
(16) The only difference is that firms adjust their prices continually
to maintain a constant profit maximizing markup [mu]* in the flexible
price RBC model and markup constancy stabilizes aggregate employment in
that case. When circumstances are such that the price level P is sticky
in the NNS model, however, the markup fluctuates with the real wage and
labor productivity according to (9), and employment fluctuates as well
according to (16).
Employment varies inversely with the markup in (16) because the
markup drives a wedge between the price of consumption goods and the
marginal cost of production. In effect, the markup is a percentage sales
tax administered by firms, the proceeds of which are distributed as
profits to households. As is the case for any tax, a higher tax rate
reduces the supply of the good being taxed, and a lower tax rate expands
the supply of that good. Hence, a compressed markup expands (and a
higher markup contracts) the production and sale of consumption goods.
Alternatively, recall from (9) that a higher markup means a lower real
wage relative to labor productivity; so the markup also acts like a tax
on labor supply because it drives the real wage below the marginal
product of labor. Thus, the labor market perspective provides another
way of understanding why employment fluctuates inversely with the
markup. The classical perspective is compatible with the Keynesian
perspective because the markup shrinks when the wage rises to attract
more labor in order to accommodate an increase in aggregate demand.
It is useful to sum up this way: In the flexible price RBC model
firms neutralize the effect of aggregate demand and productivity shocks
on aggregate employment by adjusting their prices to maintain markup
constancy. The flexible price RBC model is classical in the sense that
aggregate output is determined independently of aggregate demand. We saw
in Section 1 that the real interest rate adjusts in the flexible price
RBC model to make household demand for aggregate consumption conform to the aggregate supply of consumer goods. In the NNS model, fluctuations
in aggregate demand can induce fluctuations in employment and output. In
that sense the NNS model is Keynesian. But since the NNS model has the
classical RBC model at its core, we call it the new neoclassical
synthesis, recalling Paul Samuelson's designation for the original
attempt to synthesize classical and Keynesian economics in the 1950s.
Since firms maintain the profit maximizing markup on average over time
in the NNS model, the NNS model behaves like the flexible price RBC
model on average but with leeway for monetary policy to influence
aggregate demand and stabilize employment and inflation.
3. INTEREST RATE POLICY, CREDIBILITY, AND INFLATION SCARES
As is common practice, assume that the central bank implements
monetary policy in the NNS model with a short-term nominal interest rate policy instrument R. By definition, the real interest rate r is R -
E[pi], the money interest rate paid or earned on a loan above and beyond
the compensation for expected inflation. In practice, a central
bank's influence over the real interest rate is limited for two
reasons. It exercises direct control of only the nominal rate. Expected
inflation is variable, possibly highly variable if the central bank has
little credibility for low inflation, so control of the nominal interest
rate translates loosely into control of the real interest rate.
Moreover, longer-term interest rates are what matter for economic
activity, and a central bank influences long-term interest rates only
indirectly via the management of its short-term nominal interest rate
policy instrument. We ignore these important complications to focus on
the essence of interest rate policy in what follows.
In order to understand the mechanism through which interest rate
policy actions are transmitted to the economy, we must first specify the
context in which policy is acting. Continue to assume that the central
bank has credibility for zero inflation so that E[pi] = 0 and the price
level P is nearly invariant to current shocks and interest rate policy
actions. In this case the central bank's choice of nominal interest
rate target [bar.R] translates into a target for the real interest rate
[bar.r]. Moreover, in this case the public expects the future markup to
be at its profit maximizing level E[[mu].sub.2] = [mu]*. Recall that
current and future productivity ([a.sub.1], [a.sub.2]) are given by
technology, independently of interest rate policy. In this context, (13)
says that expected future household consumption is anchored by future
income prospects at [c*.sub.2] = [a.sub.2][1/[1+[mu]*]].
In order to trace the effect of an interest rate policy action on
current macroeconomic variables, use (3) to express current desired
consumption [c.sub.1] in terms of expected future consumption [c*.sub.2]
= [a.sub.2][1/[1+[mu]*]] and the real interest rate target [bar.r]
[c.sub.1] = [[1 + [rho]]/[1 + [bar.r]]] * [a.sub.2][1/[1 + [mu]*]].
(17)
Expression (17) reveals the nature of the leverage that interest
rate policy exerts on aggregate demand: Current consumption [c.sub.1] is
inversely related to the real interest rate target [bar.r] when expected
future consumption is anchored at [a.sub.2][1/[1+[mu]*]]. An increase in
the real interest rate target depresses current aggregate demand by
raising the opportunity cost of current consumption in terms of future
consumption. The contraction in aggregate demand is reflected in reduced
current employment [n.sub.1], a low current real wage [w.sub.1], and an
elevated current markup [[mu].sub.1]. Conversely, a cut in the real
interest rate target expands current aggregate demand, raises the real
wage, and compresses the markup. The transmission mechanism can be
understood from either the Keynesian or the classical point of view.
From the Keynesian perspective, interest rate policy exerts leverage
over employment and output because production is demand determined in
the short run. From the classical perspective, that leverage derives
from the fact that aggregate demand influences wages, which in turn
influence the markup, which behaves like a variable tax rate in the RBC
setting.
The leverage that interest rate policy actions exert on employment
creates the fundamental credibility problem of monetary policy. The
credibility problem arises from a basic tension in the new neoclassical
synthesis. On one hand, firms set their prices so as to maintain a
profit maximizing markup on average over time. From the household's
point of view, however, the markup acts like a tax on consumption and
labor supply that reduces welfare. Therefore, the central bank has an
incentive to pursue expansionary monetary policy on behalf of households
to undo the markup tax. That temptation is greatest when the central
bank's credibility for low inflation is most secure, since then
employment can be expanded with little immediate increase in inflation
or inflation expectations. The problem is that by giving in to this
temptation the central bank undercuts its own credibility. If firms come
to expect the markup to be compressed persistently, they will raise
prices to restore the profit maximizing markup. Inflation and inflation
expectations will rise, and the central bank will lose credibility for
low inflation. In short, credibility for low inflation is fundamentally
fragile in the new neoclassical synthesis because the public recognizes
the central bank's temptation to pursue expansionary monetary
policy to depress the markup and expand employment. (17)
From time to time the public comes to doubt the central bank's
commitment to low inflation. The history of monetary policy in the
United States contains numerous "inflation scares" marked by
sharply rising long-term bond rates reflecting increased expected
inflation premia. (18) Inflation scares create a fundamental dilemma for
monetary policy. At the initial nominal interest rate target [bar.R],
expected higher inflation lowers the implied real interest rate target
[bar.r] = [bar.R] - E[pi] and exacerbates the inflation scare by
stimulating current demand and compressing the markup. The central bank
could raise [bar.R] just enough to offset the effect of expected higher
inflation on the real rate. However, neutralizing the effect of higher
inflation expectations on the real interest rate target does nothing to
fight the collapse of credibility itself.
If the inflation scare persists, a central bank must react by
raising its real interest rate target. That is, the central bank must
raise [bar.R] by more than the increase in E[pi]. A higher real interest
rate target counteracts the inflation scare by contracting current
aggregate demand, reducing employment, lowering real wages, and widening
the markup. According to (15), tight monetary policy works by elevating
the current and expected future markup significantly above the profit
maximizing markup. In the contractionary environment, firms move prices
up more slowly than expected inflation, and expected inflation comes
down as credibility for low inflation is restored.
Inflation scares are costly because ignoring them or raising
[bar.R] only enough to cover the increase in E[pi] can encourage even
more doubt about the central bank's commitment to low inflation.
But raising [bar.r] to restore credibility for low inflation only works
by contracting employment, output, and consumption to widen the markup
significantly and persistently enough to encourage firms to slow the
rate of inflation. For this reason, central banks have been reluctant to
react promptly to inflation scares. In the past such hesitation led to
"stagflation," when rising inflation encouraged by
insufficiently preemptive policy would eventually be accompanied by a
period of rising unemployment after the central bank set out to restore
its credibility for low inflation.
4. FLUCTUATIONS AND STABILIZATION POLICY
In this section we consider three shocks that cause fluctuations in
employment and output because firms choose not to adjust prices to
maintain markup constancy. Again we assume that the central bank has
credibility for low inflation. Inflationary situations A or B prevail,
there are no inflation scares, and the current price level P is nearly
invariant to current economic shocks and interest rate policy actions.
We consider the effects of optimism or pessimism about future income
prospects, a temporary productivity shock, and a shift in trend
productivity growth. In each case we trace the effect of the shock
holding the central bank's real interest rate target fixed, then we
consider how interest rate policy might react to stabilize employment
and inflation.
Optimism and Pessimism about Future Income Prospects
According to the analysis of consumption in Section 1, a household
plans lifetime consumption to satisfy (3) and to exhaust its lifetime
budget constraint (1). Using these two conditions, we can write current
aggregate demand [c.sub.1] in terms of lifetime income prospects
([y.sub.1], [y.sub.2]) and the central bank's real interest rate
setting [bar.r]
[c.sub.1] = [[1 + [rho]]/[2 + [rho]]]([y.sub.1] + [[y.sub.2]/[1 +
[bar.r]]]). (18)
Since current output and income are demand determined when the
price level P is nearly invariant to current shocks and policy actions,
we can set [y.sub.1] = [c.sub.1] in (18) and solve for [c.sub.1] in
terms of [y.sub.2] and [bar.r]
[c.sub.1] = [[1 + [rho]]/[1 + [bar.r]]] * [y.sub.2]. (19)
According to (19), households transmit increased optimism or
pessimism about future income prospects [y.sub.2] (whether in future
wage or profit income) to current consumption, employment, and output.
The reason is that households want to allocate any expected change in
lifetime resources to both current and future consumption. Moreover,
because current income is demand determined, there is a secondary
(multiplier) effect on current income that amplifies the initial impact
of increased optimism or pessimism about the future. Both the primary
and secondary effects are captured in (19).
Although households react to increased optimism or pessimism by
attempting to borrow or lend in the credit market, ultimately any change
in current aggregate demand must be reflected in an equal change in
current production. Collectively, households cannot borrow from the
future to consume more in the present because it is impossible to bring
goods forward in time. Nor is it possible to store goods for future
consumption in this benchmark NNS model. However, the real interest rate
does not react to conditions in the credit market because the central
bank intervenes by injecting or draining cash to maintain its nominal
interest rate target [bar.R]. In so doing, interest rate policy actually
facilitates the transmission of optimism or pessimism about the future
to current employment and output.
In principle, interest rate policy can counteract the effect on
current employment and output of increased optimism or pessimism about
the future. For instance, according to (19), a lower real interest rate
target [bar.r] can stabilize current consumption, employment, and output
against increased pessimism about future income prospects. At best,
however, stabilization policy can only be partially effective because it
is difficult to recognize shocks promptly and because policy actions
affect spending with a lag.
A Temporary Productivity Shock
Aggregate productivity grows on average over time as a result of
technological progress. However, productivity growth fluctuates over
time because the invention and implementation of technological
improvements do not occur smoothly. We can think of a temporary shock to
productivity as involving a period in which productivity grows more
rapidly or more slowly than its long-run average, but is expected to
return shortly to its long-run growth path. To analyze the effect of a
temporary productivity shock in the benchmark NNS model, we abstract
from trend productivity growth and consider a shortfall of current
productivity [a.sub.1] with no effect on expected future productivity
[a.sub.2].
The adverse shock to current productivity expected to be temporary
has little effect on lifetime income prospects and, therefore, on
current aggregate demand. Hence, the negative productivity shock causes
firms to hire more labor to meet the initial demand. Real wages rise as
firms bid for more labor. Household wage income rises at the expense of
profit income, but aggregate real income remains largely unchanged.
The markup is compressed directly because lower productivity raises
marginal cost and indirectly because the real wage is elevated. Firms
are inclined to raise prices to restore the profit maximizing markup,
but the price level does not change much if the negative productivity
shock is not too large and is expected to be temporary.
Again the central bank can stabilize employment and inflation
fully, in principle. According to (14) and (17), it does so by raising
the real interest rate to contract current aggregate demand enough to
stabilize the current markup at [mu]*. When the markup is stabilized,
current output, income, consumption, and the real wage all fall
proportionally with productivity.
A Shift in Trend Productivity Growth
To understand the effect of shifting trend growth, suppose that
current and future productivity are related by [a.sub.2] = (1 + g) *
[a.sub.1], where g is the trend growth rate, and current productivity
[a.sub.1] is taken as given. Assume that interest rate policy is
expected to keep the actual markup at the profit maximizing markup in
the future so that [[mu].sub.2] = [mu]*. In this case, future income
prospects vary directly with the growth rate g since [y.sub.2] = (1 +
g)[a.sub.1][1/[1+[mu]*]].
Shifting trend productivity growth affects current variables in the
same way as changing optimism or pessimism about future income
prospects. Substituting the above expression for [y.sub.2] into (19), we
see that for a given real interest rate target [bar.r], current
aggregate demand, output, and employment all move in the same direction
as the trend growth rate g. For instance, an increase in trend growth
raises current aggregate demand, raises current labor demand, raises the
real wage, and compresses the markup. Contrary to popular belief, an
increase in trend productivity growth is inflationary at the initial
real interest rate target because it compresses the current markup.
According to (14) the central bank can stabilize the current
markup, employment, and inflation against a shift in trend productivity
growth by moving its real interest rate target point for percentage
point with the growth rate g. To see this, substitute (1 + g)[a.sub.1]
for [a.sub.2] in (14) and note that r*[congruent to][rho] + g. (19)
Higher trend growth requires a higher real interest rate target to give
households an incentive not to consume the proceeds prematurely. Instead
of providing a reason to keep interest rates low, higher trend
productivity growth actually requires a higher real interest rate target
on average over time to stabilize the markup and maintain credibility
for low inflation.
5. WELFARE MAXIMIZING MONETARY POLICY
The benchmark NNS model presented here recommends that interest
rate policy should stabilize the markup at its profit maximizing level
in order to stabilize the price level and make employment and output
behave as in the core RBC model with perfectly flexible prices. The
recommended policy is referred to as "neutral" because it
stabilizes the price level, neutralizes fluctuations in employment and
output that would otherwise occur due to sticky prices, and makes
aggregate demand conform to fluctuations in productivity as in a pure
real business cycle.
Neutral monetary policy is recommended because it maximizes
household welfare. (20) This can be understood in four steps:
1) The central bank can only stabilize the markup at the value that
maximizes firm profits [mu]*. Firm price adjustments will undo any
attempt by the central bank to move the markup permanently away from
[mu]*.
2) It is feasible for monetary policy to stabilize the markup at
[mu]*. Interest rate policy can do so by making aggregate demand c
conform to movements in productivity a given the production technology c
= an so as to stabilize employment at n* = [1/[1+[mu]*]].
3) Household labor supply [n.sup.s] is invariant to productivity a
when the markup is stabilized at its profit maximizing value [mu]*. A
greater abundance of consumption makes households want to take more
leisure, but a higher real wage raises the opportunity cost of leisure
just enough to neutralize the overall effect of productivity on desired
labor supply. Thus, household welfare is maximized when consumption
moves with productivity at the profit maximizing markup.
4) Household welfare would be reduced if monetary policy were to
allow the markup [mu] to fluctuate around the profit maximizing markup
[mu]*. It is true that households would be better off in periods when
the markup tax is low. But the markup tax would have to average as much
time above as below [mu]* to be consistent with firm profit maximization
on average over time. With diminishing marginal utility, the utility
gain from above average consumption and leisure would be insufficient to
offset the utility loss from below average consumption and leisure.
Among other things, such logic means that interest rate policy would
reduce welfare if it moved the markup to smooth consumption against
productivity shocks.
The key characteristics of neutral monetary policy are these:
First, neutral policy stabilizes employment at the "natural
rate," n* = [1/[1+[mu]*]]. (21) In effect, neutral policy enables
the macroeconomy to operate as if firms adjusted their prices costlessly
and continuously to maintain the profit maximizing markup at all times.
Second, when employment is stabilized at the natural rate n*,
actual output moves with "potential output" y* = an*, where
potential output grows and fluctuates over time with productivity a. In
other words, neutral policy aims to eliminate the "output
gap," the difference between actual and potential output.
Third, the consistent pursuit of neutral policy perpetuates low
inflation according to (15) if the central bank has already attained
credibility for low inflation by its past policy actions.
Fourth, low inflation confers a number of benefits in addition to
its consistency with neutral policy. (22) For instance, low inflation
produces low nominal interest rates and less economization on the use of
currency; low inflation minimizes costly pricing decisions; low
inflation minimizes relative price distortions; and low inflation guards
against disruptive inflation scares.
Fifth, a central bank can implement neutral policy by maintaining
price stability. There is no need to target the profit maximizing markup
directly in practice. The reason is that an economy in which firms show
little inclination to raise or lower prices on average is one in which
the profit maximizing markup is realized on average.
Sixth, price stability can be maintained by consistently raising
the real interest rate target to preempt inflation and lowering it to
preempt deflation. In practice, interest rate policy should utilize
measures of the output gap, employment relative to the natural rate, and
unit labor costs to help recognize and preempt potential departures from
price stability. (23)
Seventh, according to (14) the real interest rate target [bar.r]
that consistently achieves price stability shadows the real interest
rate r* that supports pure real business cycles. Price stability must be
maintained by activist interest rate policy that makes aggregate demand
conform to potential output to keep [mu] = [mu]*, and makes the real
interest rate move with expected productivity growth
[a.sub.2]/[a.sub.1].
Eighth, an inflation target facilitates the implementation of
neutral monetary policy in three ways. (24) An inflation target mandated
by the legislature helps secure credibility for low inflation against
the temptation to stimulate employment excessively. A mandated target
for low inflation reduces the incidence of destabilizing inflation or
deflation scares. And an inflation target enables the central bank to
cut its interest rate instrument more aggressively to stimulate economic
activity when necessary without fear of an inflation scare.
6. CHALLENGES TO THE POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS
According to the benchmark NNS model, credible price stability
keeps output at its potential and employment at its natural rate. So
from this perspective even those who care mainly about output and
employment can support strict inflation targeting. Yet the benchmark NNS
model presented in this paper is only one of many possible
specifications of the new synthesis model. Taking other features of the
macroeconomy into account might overturn the strong implication that
price stability is always welfare-maximizing monetary policy. The
purpose of this section is to consider briefly three additional aspects
of the macroeconomy and whether they call for optimal departures from
strict inflation targeting. (25)
Nominal Wage Stickiness
Empirical studies of wage and price dynamics suggest that nominal
wages exhibit about the same degree of temporary rigidity as do nominal
prices. (26) Yet, nominal wages are perfectly flexible in the benchmark
NNS model and are determined in perfectly competitive labor markets. So
it is worth asking to what extent nominal wage stickiness might overturn
the strict inflation targeting policy prescription. Consider a temporary
adverse productivity shock. With flexible nominal wages, stabilization
of the markup and the price level calls for aggregate demand to contract
proportionally with productivity. At the optimum, employment is
unchanged because the markup is perfectly stabilized. The nominal and
the real wage both fall with productivity, exactly offsetting the effect
of lower productivity on marginal cost and the markup. And the economy
settles temporarily at the reduced potential output with a perfectly
stabilized price level.
Things don't work out as neatly if nominal wages are sticky.
In order to maintain price stability, monetary policy must now steer
output below potential. Monetary policy must push employment below the
natural rate to offset the adverse effect of lower productivity on
marginal cost. This is possible because labor is more productive at the
margin the less it is utilized, i.e., there is diminishing marginal
physical product of labor. (27) In the presence of nominal wage
stickiness it is no longer feasible for monetary policy to both
stabilize the price level and keep output at potential. In principle,
then, a negative productivity shock could present the central bank with
a short-run tradeoff between price stability and output stability
(relative to potential) when both nominal wages and prices are sticky.
In general, such a tradeoff would call for a departure from strict
inflation targeting.
There are two reasons, however, why such situations should be of
relatively little concern in practice. First, an inflation target
between 1 and 2 percent per year and trend productivity growth of around
2 percent produces average nominal wage growth in the 3 to 4 percent
range. Such high average nominal wage growth should keep the economy
safely away from situations in which significant downward nominal wage
rigidity, as opposed to slower nominal wage growth, is required to keep
price inflation on target and output at its potential. (28) If the
economy were to suffer a protracted productivity growth slowdown, then
the central bank could stick to its inflation target and maintain markup
constancy by allowing slower nominal wage growth to match the slower
productivity growth. Downward nominal wage stickiness should not present
a problem in this case. Upward nominal wage stickiness would not cause
problems either. If nominal wages were temporarily rigid upward in the
face of a favorable productivity shock, then the central bank could
stick to its inflation target by steering the economy temporarily above
potential output.
Second, implicit or explicit long-term relationships govern most
labor transactions in developed economies. For reasons analogous to
those discussed in Section 2, it can be efficient for firms to fix
nominal wages for a period of time and to consider wage changes only at
discrete intervals. Yet it would be inefficient for either firms or
workers to allow temporary nominal wage rigidity to upset the terms of
otherwise efficient long-term relationships. And there is scope for
firms and workers to neutralize the effect of wage stickiness since
wages already resemble installment payments in the context of long-term
relationships. (29) Hence, firms and workers could be expected to
arrange future transactions to undo any effects of nominal wage
stickiness. (30) If the price level is stabilized in the face of a
negative productivity shock, those firms whose nominal wage is
temporarily sticky will appear to pay an excessive real wage. However,
this logic suggests that non-adjusting firms record a "due
from" to be transferred from workers to the firm in the future. In
this way, "effective" real wages fall as much for firms that
do not adjust their nominal wages as for those firms that do adjust. To
the extent that such behavior is widespread, there is little reason to
depart from strict inflation targeting because nominal wages are sticky.
(31)
From this perspective the consequences for monetary policy of
stickiness in wages and prices are sharply different. We can expect
firms and workers to neutralize the allocative consequences of
temporarily sticky nominal wages in the context of long-term
relationships in the labor market. But spot transactions predominate in
product markets. There, temporarily sticky prices can cause the average
markup to fluctuate significantly and persistently over time with
adverse consequences for employment and inflation. The adverse
consequences of temporarily sticky product prices need to be eliminated
by neutral monetary policy that supports price stability.
Extreme Asset Price Fluctuations
Some analysts suggest that interest rate policy should react
directly to asset prices in order to preempt extreme fluctuations such
as those experienced in Japan and the United States in recent years.
(32) They would urge a central bank to take such action even if it has
full credibility for low inflation. Such advice amounts to a
recommendation to risk recession or deflation in order to preempt what
may become an unsustainable increase in asset prices. It is certainly
debatable whether that risk would ever be worth taking.
The main problem with this recommendation, however, is that it is
virtually impossible to put into practice. (33) The reason boils down to
this: When asset prices first appear to be surprisingly elevated, the
central bank is disinclined to react directly to them because asset
prices are not yet so high as to be clearly unsustainable. However,
interest rate policy cannot react aggressively to asset prices after
they become clearly unsustainable either. At that point a collapse of
asset prices itself, even without a tightening of policy, could put the
economy into recession. The best way to handle extreme fluctuations in
asset prices is to make sure that supervisory and regulatory safeguards
are in place to prevent a precipitous asset price correction from
immobilizing financial institutions and markets, and to make sure that
monetary policy is sufficiently sensitive to the risk of recession and
deflation after a correction takes place.
The Zero Bound on Interest Rate Policy
This potential challenge to strict low inflation targeting stems
from the fact that nominal interest rates cannot go below zero because
neither banks nor the public will lend money at negative nominal
interest when bank reserves and currency are costless to carry over
time. The zero bound on nominal interest is a potential problem for
monetary policy in a low inflation environment for two main reasons.
First, if expected inflation is nearly zero, then the central bank
cannot make real short-term interest negative if need be to fight
deflationary shocks. Second, when short-term nominal rates are zero,
further disinflation raises real short-term interest rates and worsens
the deflationary pressure.
One could keep nominal short-term interest rates safely away from
zero by targeting inflation at 3 or 4 percent per annum; but that would
mean accepting the costs of excessive inflation forever. Moreover, such
a high inflation target would invite credibility problems. An inflation
target between 1 and 2 percent is a good compromise. Inflation is kept
low, but far enough from zero to avoid deflation. One could conceivably
raise the inflation target temporarily whenever more leeway for negative
real interest was thought necessary to fight a recession. However, a
policy that resorted to higher inflation in such circumstances would
cause inflation expectations to rise whenever the economy weakened.
Variable inflation expectations would be difficult to manage. Inflation
scares would again become a significant source of shocks to the economy.
Strictly targeting inflation between 1 and 2 percent could firmly anchor
expected inflation and still give a central bank leeway to push the real
short-term rate 1 to 2 percentage points below zero. Evidence from U.S.
monetary history suggests that such leeway would be enough to enable a
central bank to preempt deflation and stabilize the economy against most
adverse shocks. (34) Moreover, other effective monetary policy options
are available if short-term nominal rates become immobilized at the zero
bound. (35)
7. CONCLUSION
Economists and central bankers will surely make further progress on
the theory and practice of monetary policy in the future. Nevertheless,
it seems clear that price stability will continue to be regarded as the
foundation of good monetary policy. For almost two decades low and
relatively stable inflation around the world has proved its worth. In
the United States the period included the two longest peacetime cyclical expansions and two mild recessions in 1990-91 and in 2001. The benchmark
new neoclassical synthesis model provides a theoretical case for price
stability that supports the practical case derived from experience.
Theory reinforces practice and strengthens the view that price stability
should be a priority for monetary policy.
The benchmark NNS model explains why price stability works well,
and why price stability is desirable from the perspective of household
welfare. A credible commitment to low inflation prevents inflation or
deflation scares that are destabilizing for both output and prices.
Price stability is welfare-maximizing monetary policy because it anchors
the markup at its profit maximizing value and thereby prevents
fluctuations in employment and output that would otherwise occur due to
sticky prices.
As an operational matter we saw how interest rate policy actions
work to implement price stability by stabilizing the markup, and how
interest rate policy secures credibility for low inflation. By anchoring
expected future inflation we saw how such credibility strengthens the
leverage that interest rate policy exerts over current aggregate demand.
In so doing, credibility for low inflation helps monetary policy make
aggregate demand conform to movements in potential output.
The author is Senior Vice President and Policy Advisor. This
article originally appeared in International Finance (Summer 2002,
165-191) and is reprinted in its entirety with the kind permission of
Blackwell Publishing
[http://www.blackwell-synergy.com/rd.asp?code=infi&goto=journal].
The article was prepared for a conference, "Stabilizing the
Economy: What Roles for Fiscal and Monetary Policy?" at the Council
on Foreign Relations in New York, July 2002. The author thanks A1
Broaddus, Huberto Ennis, Mark Gertler, Robert Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein,
Bennett McCallum, Adam Posen, and Paul Romer for valuable comments.
Thanks are also due to students at the GSB University of Chicago, the
GSB Stanford University, and the University of Virginia who saw earlier
versions of this work and helped to improve the exposition. The views
expressed are the author's and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. Correspondence:
Marvin.Goodfriend@rich.frb.org.
(1) Lucas (1981) and Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000).
(2) Prescott (1986) and Plosser (1989).
(3) Mankiw and Romer (1991), Mankiw (1990), and Romer (1993).
(4) This primer draws on ideas developed in Goodfriend and King
(1997, 2001). See also Brayton, Levin, Tryon, and Williams (1997),
Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1999), and Woodford (2003).
(5) Fisher (1930) and Friedman (1957) pioneered the theory of
household consumption.
(6) As will become clear below, it is not necessary to specify the
length of the two periods in order to explain the mechanics of the
forward-looking benchmark NNS model and its implications for monetary
policy. The features of the NNS model highlighted here are qualitatively
consistent with those of a fully dynamic version of the model specified
as a system of difference equations connecting periods of relatively
short duration.
(7) To maximize lifetime utility, a household must choose [c.sub.1]
and [c.sub.2] so that what it requires in future consumption to forgo
one more unit of current consumption, (1 + [rho])[[c.sub.2]/[c.sub.1]],
equals the interest rate, 1 + r, at which it can transform a unit of
current consumption into future consumption by lending.
(8) This point can be verified with a little algebra.
(9) Romer (1989).
(10) Fisher (1930).
(11) Calvo (1983) models price stickiness by assuming that a firm
gets opportunities to change its price on a stochastic basis; this
accords with the description of price-setting given here.
(12) Calvo's (1983) pricing model yields a forward-looking
inflation process approximately like (15). See the discussions and
derivations in Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1999), Gali and Gertler
(1999), Goodfriend and King (1997, 2001), and Taylor (1999).
(13) Markup shocks are expected to be transitory because monetary
policy is expected to make them so. See Sections 4 and 5 below.
(14) The price level is nearly invariant to current economic
conditions because firms choose not to adjust their product prices to
maintain markup constancy. Firms would adjust their prices to restore
markup constancy if they expected that otherwise their markups would
deviate persistently and significantly from the profit maximizing
markup. Prices are less flexible in the NNS model the more confident are
firms that monetary policy will manage nominal cost conditions so as to
maintain their profit maximizing markup without any price adjustments.
Hence, credibility for low inflation reinforces price stickiness in the
NNS model.
(15) Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987).
(16) Rotemberg and Woodford (1999).
(17) Barro and Gordon (1983), Chari, Kehoe, and Prescott (1989),
and Sargent (1986) discuss credibility issues in models other than those
of the new neoclassical synthesis.
(18) See Goodfriend (1993) and Chari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum
(1998).
(19) The approximate one-for-one correspondence is an implication
of log utility.
(20) Goodfriend and King (1997, 2001), Ireland (1996), and Woodford
(2003).
(21) Friedman (1968).
(22) Khan, King, and Wolman (2003).
(23) McCallum (1999).
(24) Bernanke, Laubach, Mishkin, and Posen (1999), Haldane (1995),
Leiderman and Svensson (1995), and Svensson (1999).
(25) Goodfriend and King (2001) consider a number of reasons to
depart from perfect markup constancy and price stability in an NNS
model: fully dynamic multi-period pricing, distortions involving
monetized exchange, variable labor supply elasticities, and government
spending shocks. They argue that optimal departures arising from these
sources are likely to be quantitatively minor.
(26) Taylor (1999).
(27) Production technology (7) is specified as linear in labor for
expositional purposes only. A more realistic specification such as c =
a(n)[.sup.[alpha]], 1>[alpha]>0, would exhibit diminishing
marginal product of labor.
(28) Vinals (2001).
(29) Hall (1999).
(30) Barro (1977).
(31) Goodfriend and King (2001).
(32) Interest rate policy ordinarily takes indirect account of
asset prices in so far as they help forecast aggregate demand.
(33) Bernanke and Gertler (1999), Goodfriend (2003), and Greenspan
(2002).
(34) Reifschneider and Williams (2000) and Vinals (2001).
(35) Goodfriend (2000) and McCallum (2000).
REFERENCES
Barro, Robert J. 1977. "Long-term Contracting, Sticky Prices,
and Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary Economics 3 (July):
305-16.
____________, and David Gordon. 1983. "Rules, Discretion, and
Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary
Economics 12: 101-22.
Bernanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler. 1999. "Monetary Policy and
Asset Price Volatility." Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review 4th Quarter: 17-51.
Bernanke, Ben, Thomas Laubach, Fredrick Mishkin, and Adam Posen.
1999. Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki. 1987. "Monopolistic
Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand." American Economic
Review 77 (September): 647-666.
Brayton, Flint, Andy Levin, Ralph Tryon, and John Williams. 1997.
"The Evolution of Macro Models at the Federal Reserve Board."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 47 (December):
43-81.
Calvo, Guillermo. 1983. "Staggered Prices in a Utility
Maximizing Framework." Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 383-98.
Chari, V. V., Patrick Kehoe, and Edward Prescott. 1989. "Time
Consistency and Policy." Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. Robert
Barro. Cambridge: Harvard University Press: 265-305.
Chari, V. V., Larry Christiano, and Martin Eichenbaum. 1998.
"Expectation Traps and Discretion." Journal of Economic Theory
81 (August): 462-92.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler. 1999. "The
Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective." Journal
of EconomicLiterature 37 (December): 1661-1707.
Fisher, Irving. [1930] 1986. The Theory of Interest. Fairfield,
N.J.: Augustus M. Kelley.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
____________. 1968. "The Role of Monetary Policy."
American Economic Review 58 (March): 1-17.
Gali, Jordi, and Mark Gertler. 1999. "Inflation Dynamics: A
Structural Econometric Analysis." Journal of Monetary Economics 44
(October): 195-222.
Goodfriend, Marvin. 1993. "Interest Rate Policy and the
Inflation Scare Problem: 1979-92." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 79 (Winter): 1-24.
____________. 2000. "Overcoming the Zero Bound on Interest
Rate Policy," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 32 (November):
1007-35.
____________. 2003. "Interest Rate Policy Should Not React
Directly to Asset Prices." Asset Price Bubbles: Implications for
Monetary, Regulatory, and International Policies, ed. W.C. Hunter, G.G.
Kaufman, and M. Pomerleano. Cambridge: MIT Press: 445-57.
____________, and Robert G. King. 1997. "The New Neoclassical
Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12, ed. Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg. Cambridge: MIT Press:
231-83.
____________. 2001. "The Case for Price Stability." Why
Price Stability? ed. A. Herrero, V. Gaspar, L. Hoogduin, and B. Winkler.
Proceedings from the First ECB Central Banking Conference, Frankfurt:
European Central Bank. Also: NBER Working Paper 8423 (August).
Greenspan, Alan. 2002. "Economic Volatility." Remarks at
a symposium in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, sponsored by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City (August).
Haldane, Andy, ed. 1995. Targeting Inflation. London: Bank of
England.
Hall, Robert E. 1999. "Labor-Market Frictions and Employment
Fluctuations." Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. John B. Taylor and
Michael Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.: 1137-70.
Ireland, Peter. 1996. "The Role of Countercyclical Monetary
Policy." Journal of Political Economy 104 (August): 704-24.
Khan, Aubhik., Robert G. King, and Alexander Wolman. 2003.
"Optimal Monetary Policy." Review of Economic Studies 70 (4):
825-60.
Leiderman, Leonardo, and Lars Svensson, eds. 1995. Inflation
Targets. London: Center for Economic Policy Research.
Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent. 2000. Recursive Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1981. Studies in Business Cycle Theory.
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 1990. "A Quick Refresher Course in
Macroeconomics." Journal of Economic Literature 28 (December):
1645-60.
____________, and David Romer, eds. 1991. New Keynesian
Macroeconomics, 2 vols. Cambridge: MIT Press.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1999. "Issues in the Design of Monetary
Policy Rules." Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. John B. Taylor and
Michael Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.: 1483-1530.
____________. 2000. "Theoretical Analysis Regarding the Zero
Bound on Nominal Interest Rates." Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 32 (November): 870-905.
Plosser, Charles I. 1989. "Understanding Real Business
Cycles." Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (Summer): 51-77.
Prescott, Edward. 1986. "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle
Measurement." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review
10 (Fall): 9-22.
Reifschneider, David, and John Williams. 2000. "Three Lessons
for Monetary Policy in a Low Inflation Era." Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 32 (November): 936-66.
Romer, David. 1993. "The New Keynesian Synthesis."
Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (Winter): 5-22.
Romer, Paul. 1989. "Capital Accumulation in the Theory of
Long-Run Growth." Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. Robert Barro.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press: 51-127.
Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford. 1999. "The Cyclical
Behavior of Prices and Costs." Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. John
B. Taylor and Michael Woodford. Amsterdam, Elsevier Science B.V.:
1051-1135.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1986. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New
York: Harper and Row.
Svensson, Lars E. O. 1999. "Inflation Targeting as a Monetary
Policy Rule." Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (June): 607-54.
Taylor, John B. 1999. "Staggered Price and Wage Setting in
Macroeconomics." Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. John B. Taylor and
Michael Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.: 1009-50.
Vinals, Jose. 2001. "Monetary Policy Issues in a Low Inflation
Environment." Why Price Stability? ed. Herrero, V. Gaspar, L.
Hoogduin, and B. Winkler. Proceedings from the First ECB Central Banking
Conference, Frankfurt: European Central Bank.
Woodford, Michael. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a
Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Velde, Francois R. 2004. "Poor Hand or Poor Play? The Rise and
Fall of Inflation in the U.S." Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives (First Quarter): 34-51.