Sustaining price stability.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr. ; Goodfriend, Marvin
The year 2003 was a watershed in Federal Reserve history. In his
semiannual testimony to Congress on monetary policy in July, Chairman
Greenspan declared that measures of core consumer inflation had
decelerated in the first half of the year to a range that could be
considered "effective price stability." (1) The Chairman
paused briefly to acknowledge, with understated satisfaction, the
achievement of this goal, which Congress had assigned to the Federal
Reserve and the Fed had pursued for over two decades. He quickly pointed
out, however, that the Fed would be confronted now with new challenges
in sustaining price stability--specifically preventing deflation as well
as inflation. Earlier in the year, at the conclusion of its May meeting,
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) had expressed concern for the
first time that inflation might decline too far, saying that "the
probability of an unwelcome substantial fall in inflation, though minor,
exceed(ed) that of a pickup in inflation from its already low
level." (2)
The case for maintaining price stability--in the United States and
elsewhere--is rooted in experience and theory, which indicate that
monetary policy best supports employment, economic growth, and financial
stability by making price stability a priority. The full rationale for
price stability has been elaborated elsewhere, and we will refrain from
repeating it here. (3) This article, instead, is about how to sustain
price stability now that it has been achieved. We build our argument in
several stages. First, we present a framework for understanding the
inflation and deflation processes. Our framework, borrowed from the
"new neoclassical synthesis" macroeconomic model, focuses on
the management of the markup of price over marginal cost by
monopolistically competitive firms. (4) Next, we provide examples of
shocks that are potentially inflationary or deflationary and explain how
interest rate policy actions can counteract them effectively to maintain
price stability.
The Fed's current hard-won credibility for low inflation is a
foundation of efficient monetary policy because it anchors expected
inflation. We review briefly why inflation scares create problems for
monetary policy. Addressing the challenge noted by Chairman Greenspan,
we explain why deflation scares are equally problematic. Unfortunately,
credibility for containing inflation does not necessarily imply
credibility against deflation because while there is no upper bound on
nominal interest rates to resist inflation, there is a lower bound at
zero. We explain how the Fed can use monetary policy--even at the zero
bound--to preempt deflation and acquire credibility against deflation to
complement its anti-inflation credentials.
Communication has come to play an increasingly important and
substantive role in the Fed's conduct of monetary policy because
open and effective communication is a crucial ingredient in building and
maintaining credibility for price stability. Good communication requires
clear long-run policy objectives and clarity in conveying the reasoning
behind short-run policy actions aimed at achieving those objectives. In
line with our macroeconomic framework, we believe that both purposes
would be well served if the Fed publicly announced an explicit long-run
inflation target and made more prominent use of price-cost gap,
employment gap, and output gap indicators in explaining the stance of
monetary policy. In particular, we explain how, in our view, these
changes would help minimize the kind of communication problems the Fed
faced in 2003 in signaling its concern about deflation and its policy
intentions for dealing with the rising risk of deflation at that time.
Having outlined what we want to accomplish in this article, let us
emphasize that what follows is our understanding of the issues and our
suggestions for dealing with them. Some of our views are shared by our
Fed colleagues, others are not. This is no cause for embarrassment.
Monetary policy and its effect on the economy is a complex and subtle
subject; there is plenty of room for different approaches and divergent
views.
1. THE FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLE OF PRICE STABILITY
Our approach to thinking about the maintenance of price stability
focuses on how monopolistically competitive firms set their prices over
time. (5) This approach is useful because it highlights how monetary
policymakers must create an environment within which firms choose to
maintain stable prices on average. (6)
For our purposes, a key feature of price-setting in practice is its
discontinuous character. It is costly for a firm producing a distinctive
product to determine the exact price that maximizes its profits at every
point in time. Forecasts of demand and cost conditions are expensive to
obtain. Moreover, pricing must compete with other claims on
management's time, such as production and marketing decisions.
Consequently, pricing gets the attention of management only every so
often.
For all these reasons, a firm is apt to consider changing its
product price only when demand and cost conditions threaten to move its
actual markup of price over cost significantly and persistently away
from its profit-maximizing markup. (7) Given a firm's current
product price, higher production costs compress its markup, and lower
production costs elevate its markup. Production costs, in turn, increase
with the hourly wage a firm must pay its workers and decrease as labor
productivity (output per hour) rises. (8)
Potential inflation arises when a significant compression of
markups is widely expected by firms to persist. In this case, firms
raise product prices over time to cover higher expected costs. Potential
deflation develops if firms expect significantly elevated markups to
persist. Competition for product market share in this latter case
induces firms to pass along lower costs via lower prices.
Such reasoning implies the fundamental principle of price
stability: inflation will remain low and stable if and only if
departures from profit-maximizing markups are expected to be relatively
small and transitory across firms, so firms are content to raise prices
at the existing low inflation rate on average. Note that we consider low
and stable inflation to be "effective price stability," in
keeping with Chairman Greenspan's characterization.
The historical record shows that in the long run competition among
firms for labor pushes real wages (nominal wages adjusted for inflation)
up at about the same rate as labor productivity grows. Consequently,
real production costs in the aggregate are stable in the long run.
Nominal wages, in turn, tend to rise at the rate of productivity growth
plus the rate of inflation; therefore, nominal production costs rise at
about the rate of inflation in the long run. In the short run, however,
shocks to aggregate demand and productivity can cause production costs
to vary significantly and persistently relative to prices.
2. COUNTERACTING SHOCKS TO PRICE STABILITY
This section builds on the fundamental principle of price stability
discussed in the previous section to explain how monetary policy,
working through short-term interest rates, can counteract inflationary
or deflationary shocks to the economy. The argument is straightforward:
interest rate policy maintains price stability by managing aggregate
demand so as to stabilize the actual markup at the profit-maximizing
markup on average across firms. (9) (What follows is tightly reasoned
but well worth working through, since it describes the core
relationships policymakers must focus on to succeed in maintaining price
stability.)
An inflationary shock generates a sustained acceleration in
production costs, and therefore a compression of the average markup that
inclines firms to raise prices above the previously expected low
inflation rate unless the Fed uses interest rate policy actions to
reverse the increase in costs and the markup compression. A deflationary
shock, in contrast, generates a sustained deceleration or decline in
production costs and an increase in the markup that requires offsetting
Fed interest rate actions. Exactly how interest rate policy works to
stabilize the markup is explained below.
For expositional purposes, it is useful to divide shocks with
inflationary or deflationary potential into two categories. We consider
first shocks to expected future income prospects. Subsequently, we take
up shocks to current productivity growth.
Shocks to Expected Future Income Prospects
Whatever the source of optimism or pessimism about the future,
shocks to expected future wages and profits are likely to be transmitted
to current aggregate demand. (10) Households will want to adjust current
as well as future consumption to reflect any changes in expected
lifetime resources. And firms will want to invest more or less currently
in response to any changes in expected future profits.
In these circumstances, optimism about future income prospects is
potentially inflationary because it increases the current demand for
labor, raises wages, and compresses markups. On the other hand,
pessimism about future prospects is potentially deflationary because it
eases competition in the labor market, slows wage growth, and elevates
markups.
The key point for monetary policy is this: one way or another,
profit-maximizing markups will be restored. The shock may dissipate before inflationary or deflationary forces build up. If not, then either
the Fed must restore profit-maximizing markups promptly with interest
rate policy actions, or else firms will attempt to restore these markups
by raising or cutting product prices, whichever the case may be.
Clearly, it is better that profit-maximizing markups be restored by
interest rate policy actions without inflation or deflation.
Bottom line: the Fed can offset a potentially inflationary increase
in current demand arising from an increase in expected future income
prospects by raising real interest rates to increase the return to
saving, raise the cost of borrowing, and induce households and firms to
defer spending. Higher real rates preempt inflation by reversing the
increased current demand for labor, which reduces the pressure on wages
and production costs, and restores profit-maximizing markups.
Conversely, by lowering real interest rates, the Fed can lower the
return to saving and the cost of borrowing, stimulate spending, and
offset a potentially deflationary reduction in aggregate demand. Lower
real rates, in turn, preempt deflation by strengthening current labor
demand, reversing the downward pressure on wages, and recompressing
markups.
The argument above proceeded as if firms were not fully confident
that the Fed would act promptly to stabilize production costs that would
otherwise be affected by shocks to future income prospects. If firms are
confident, then they will meet a temporary increase in demand by working
current employees more intensively or by hiring temporary workers,
rather than by raising product prices. And firms will lay off labor
rather than cut prices if they expect the Fed to stabilize production
costs in the face of a shortfall in current demand. Note that the
average markup will tend to be compressed temporarily in the first case
and elevated temporarily in the second case. We will say more below
about why the Fed's "credibility" for price stability is
the foundation of efficient monetary policy.
Shocks to Current Productivity Growth
Consider next a sequence of current shocks to productivity growth
that persists unexpectedly at first, but subsequently comes to be
expected to persist. Initially, unanticipated increases in productivity
growth are potentially deflationary, and decreases are potentially
inflationary. We take the deflationary case; the inflationary case is
exactly the reverse.
For a given growth rate of wages, accelerated productivity growth
lowers production costs directly. If, at first, the acceleration is not
expected to persist, there is little effect on expected future income
and little effect on current aggregate demand. In such circumstances,
faster productivity growth also slows production costs indirectly by
reducing current labor demand and slowing the growth of wages. Two
historical examples of these effects are particularly noteworthy.
Surprisingly persistent strong productivity growth in conjunction with a
weak labor market helped lower production costs and produce disinflation in 2003. Conversely, surprisingly persistent weak productivity growth
helped produce inflation in the 1970s. (11)
The longer a surprising acceleration or deceleration of
productivity growth persists, the more likely it will come to be
expected to persist. If these changes in expectations are sufficiently
pronounced, they have the potential to offset and reverse the initial
risk to price stability arising from the change in productivity growth.
This appears to be what happened in the late 1990s when surprisingly
persistent increases in productivity growth apparently came to be
expected and were extrapolated far into the future. The brightening
future income prospects caused aggregate demand to grow even faster than
productivity for a time near the end of the decade. Labor markets
tightened, real wages grew about as fast as productivity, and inflation
remained low and stable. Indeed, there was concern at the time that
inflation might
rise if the increase in demand stimulated by the higher expected
future income growth outstripped the restraining effect of the higher
productivity growth on prices.
Whether current shocks to productivity are potentially inflationary
or deflationary, the Fed can act to offset that potential with interest
rate policy. Again, the guiding policy principle is to manage aggregate
demand to stabilize production costs so as to sustain profit-maximizing
markups on average. The Fed must reduce real interest rates to defuse the potential for deflation when a period of faster productivity growth
is not expected to persist. In this situation, lower real interest rates
must stimulate aggregate demand sufficiently to offset the weakness in
labor markets and thereby allow wage increases to reflect the higher
productivity. Alternatively, if the public comes to regard a period of
faster productivity growth as an increase in trend growth, then the Fed
might have to increase real interest rates to relieve the potential for
inflation. Specifically, interest rates would have to rise enough to
limit the increase in current aggregate demand to what can be satisfied
by the current increase in productivity at the profit-maximizing markup.
Having outlined these policy prescriptions, we want to be quick to
acknowledge--as practical policymakers--that implementing them with
consistent success is far from rote. Measuring and predicting the
relevant aggregate variables is difficult enough; estimating and
tracking indicators of the average profit-maximizing markup is even more
so. Modeling the transmission of interest rate policy actions to demand,
production costs, and inflation requires sophisticated econometric techniques. And discerning whether the public perceives an increase in
productivity growth as transitory or more lasting, for example, is not
easy. Tasks like these are as challenging as they are crucial. Some
would refer to the judgments involved in this work as the
"art" of monetary policy.
3. THE IMPORTANCE OF CREDIBILITY FOR STABLE PRICES
As the foregoing has already suggested, credibility is an essential
component of effective monetary policy. The long campaign from the late
1970s through the early 1990s to reduce inflation and establish price
stability arguably succeeded only when the Fed finally acquired
credibility for low inflation in the eyes of the public in the late
1990s. Indeed, the acquisition of this credibility was essentially
equivalent to establishing price stability--two ways to describe the
same achievement. Similarly, the Fed needs to acquire credibility for
sustaining price stability going forward.
The previous section showed how interest rate policy actions can
counteract inflationary or deflationary shocks and perpetuate
credibility presuming that it has already been established. In this
section we explain why full credibility for maintaining price stability
is so useful, and how its absence can cause serious problems.
Credibility for stable prices produces three critically important
benefits. First, credibility anchors inflation expectations so that
nominal federal funds rate target changes translate clearly into real
interest rate changes, which helps the Fed gauge the likely impact of
its policy actions on the economy. Second, credibility buys time for the
Fed to recognize and counteract threats to price stability. Third,
credibility enhances the flexibility of interest rate policy to respond
aggressively to transitory shocks that threaten to destabilize financial
markets and create unemployment.
The absence of credibility, on the other hand, creates problems for
monetary policy. The history of post-World War II monetary policy in the
United States features numerous inflation scares marked by sharply
rising long-term bond rates reflecting increased expected inflation
premia. (12) Inflation scares create a fundamental dilemma for monetary
policy. At the initial nominal federal funds rate target, higher
expected inflation lowers the real federal funds rate and intensifies
the inflation scare by stimulating current aggregate demand and
compressing the markup. In these circumstances, the Fed could raise its
nominal federal funds rate target just enough to leave the real rate
unchanged; but that would do nothing to reverse the collapse of
confidence.
Inflation scares are dangerous because ignoring them encourages
even more doubt about the Fed's commitment to low inflation. And
restoring credibility for low inflation requires the Fed to weaken labor
markets deliberately with higher real interest rates in order to slow
wage growth, elevate markups, and induce firms not to raise
prices--rarely a popular policy stance with the public or the political
establishment. It is in large part to avoid the risk of recession posed
by inflation scares that the Fed has learned to preempt inflation with
interest rate policy.
Unfortunately--and this is a crucial point in appreciating fully
the policy implications of the transition from fighting for price
stability to maintaining it--credibility for controlling inflation does
not automatically translate into credibility for preventing deflation. A
deflation scare obviously does not confront the Fed with a choice
between contracting employment and loosing credibility. On the contrary,
the way to resist a deflation scare is to reduce real interest rates in
order to stimulate demand, tighten labor markets, raise wages, and
compress the markup. The problem is that given the zero bound on the
nominal federal funds rate, interest rate policy alone might have
insufficient leeway to deter deflation, especially since the federal
funds rate is low on average when expected inflation is low. Moreover,
the Fed would have to drive the nominal federal funds rate ever closer
to zero to prevent disinflationary expectations from raising the real
federal funds rate. And deflation expectations would actually raise the
real federal funds rate at the zero bound and exacerbate the deflation
scare.
In addition, a policy vacuum at the zero bound could encourage
ill-advised fiscal actions. Some fiscal actions would be desirable as we
explain below; but many would not be. For instance, the government might
enact legislation that results in wasteful government spending,
inefficient credit subsidies, or forbearance in the banking system
related to deposit insurance. The government might also resort to
off-budget policies such as anti-competitive measures to support wages
or prices in particular sectors. All told, such fiscal actions could
lower potential GDP substantially. (13) In doing so, they would lower
future income prospects, lower current aggregate demand, contract
current employment, lower wages and production costs, and exacerbate the
deflation problem. This appears to be what happened in the Great
Depression of the 1930s. (14)
Ultimately then, a deflation scare, like an inflation scare, is
problematic because it has the potential to lead to a protracted recession. From this perspective, even those who care mainly about
employment and output can understand why the Fed must establish
credibility as a deflation fighter as well as an inflation fighter by
making price stability a priority and resisting deviations from it in
either direction.
Moreover, credibility against inflation and credibility against
deflation are mutually supportive: each strengthens the other, and each
is weaker without the other. (15) As we pointed out above with respect
to inflation scares, policy must compensate for insufficient credibility
in one direction by taking risks in the other direction. We make this
point again as it pertains to establishing credibility against
deflation.
4. DEFEATING DEFLATION AT THE ZERO BOUND
But how can the Fed establish credibility for preventing deflation
given the zero bound on the nominal funds rate? In brief, the Fed should
make arrangements to overcome operational and institutional obstacles
identified below that could impede the effectiveness of monetary policy
at the zero bound. The publication of a contingency plan for the
aggressive pursuit of monetary policy against deflation at the zero
bound would greatly reduce the likelihood and force of deflation scares
and help guarantee that the devastating effects of deflation experienced
earlier in U.S. history will not be repeated. (16)
But how, specifically, can the Fed confront a deflationary risk
when the funds rate is at the zero bound? Most importantly in our view,
the Fed can continue to inject money into the economy by buying assets
and expanding its balance sheet when conventional interest rate policy
is immobilized at the zero bound. (17) Some economists believe that
expanding the monetary base would stimulate spending directly through a
monetarist channel of monetary transmission. Others focus on how Fed
purchases of long-term bonds would stimulate spending by lowering
long-term interest rates. Still others believe that expanding the
balance sheet would work by creating expectations of inflation that
would push real interest rates below zero if the Fed held the nominal
federal funds rate at zero.
Even though we do not know the relative strength of these three
transmission channels, and others that may exist, we do know this:
monetary policy must be able to defeat deflation at the zero bound;
otherwise, the government could eliminate explicit taxes and finance all
of its expenditure forever with money created by the Fed! (18) The
challenge is to identify and overcome operational and institutional
obstacles to the credible implementation of quantitative monetary policy
as opposed to interest rate policy, where "quantitative monetary
policy" refers to open market purchases that expand the volume of
assets and monetary liabilities on the Fed's balance sheet.
What are these operational and institutional obstacles? One problem
is that the bang for the buck of quantitative monetary policy at the
zero bound is unknown and may be relatively weak. It follows that the
Fed must be prepared, if necessary, to overshoot temporarily the
long-term, steady state size of its balance sheet by a wide margin. But
to do so, the Fed must have a credible exit strategy for draining
whatever monetary base threatens excessive inflation after it has
successfully concluded its deflation-fighting policy actions.
A second problem is that short-term government securities are
perfect substitutes for the monetary base at the zero bound; therefore,
the Fed would have to buy longer-term government securities, private
assets, or foreign assets for quantitative policy to be effective at the
zero bound. (19) The current outstanding stock of longer-term government
securities together with the prospective flow of future government
borrowing may very well provide sufficient government securities for the
Fed to buy--that is, monetize--to defeat deflation at the zero bound.
To lock in credibility against deflation, however, the Fed will
need more fiscal support for quantitative policy at the zero bound than
it is usually granted by the fiscal authorities, i.e., Congress and the
Treasury. For example, in some circumstances, there might not be enough
outstanding longer-term government bonds to purchase, or government
budget deficits to monetize, to make the quantitative policy effective.
Of course, the Fed could buy other assets. But buying domestic private
assets or foreign assets on the large scale contemplated here would
create other credibility problems. (20) Additionally, this strategy
would expose the Fed to capital losses that might leave it with
insufficient assets to reverse a huge expansion of its balance sheet,
should that be required. (21)
The fiscal authorities could enter the process in a number of ways.
In particular, they could support the Fed's exit strategy by
committing to transfer enough government securities to the Fed--in
effect to recapitalize the Fed if necessary--to allow the Fed to drain
whatever base money needed to be withdrawn from the economy following an
aggressive anti-deflation action by the Fed at the zero bound. In
addition, the fiscal authorities could agree to run a budget deficit to
help inject money into the economy. The Fed could monetize short-term
debt issued to finance the deficit and then withdraw excess base money
later by selling the debt back to the public. In this way, monetary
policy could be made completely credible against deflation in virtually
any situation.
This discussion may strike some readers as far-fetched. But while
the probability is low that a deflationary threat of the magnitude
contemplated here at the zero bound will emerge in the future, if it
did, the consequences of not being fully prepared to deal with it could
be exceptionally damaging to the economy. Consequently, we believe it is
essential to have contingency arrangements of the kind we have just
described firmly in place in advance.
5. IMPROVING COMMUNICATION IN SUPPORT OF PRICE STABILITY
Up to this point, we have explained the economics of maintaining
price stability in the context of a modern macroeconomic model, and
indicated the critical importance of credibility in this effort,
including credibility for confronting the risk of deflation at the zero
bound. This last section of our article addresses a final element in the
strategy for maintaining price stability: clear communication with the
public regarding both the strategy itself and short-term actions taken
in the defense of price stability. (22)
The macroeconomic model of the inflation and deflation processes
outlined above suggests two substantial opportunities for the Fed to
improve its communication practices in ways that would strengthen its
strategy for maintaining price stability. First, the Fed can lock in
long-run price stability and clarify its short-run concerns and policy
intentions regarding inflation by publicly announcing an explicit low
long-run inflation target. Second, the Fed can clarify its reasons for
taking particular short-run policy actions to preempt potential
inflation or deflation by talking in terms of the average gap between
the actual markup and the profit-maximizing markup, and closely related
indicators of labor market tightness, which we identified earlier as the
proximate determinants of price pressures. Our arguments for these two
recommendations are developed below.
Clarifying Short-Run Policy Aims with an Inflation Target
Although the Fed has made price stability a priority for monetary
policy, it does not publicly and explicitly specify a target range for
inflation. Instead, the Fed signals its concerns about inflation or
deflation in its post-FOMC meeting statements and minutes, and in the
Chairman's monetary policy reports to Congress. We believe that the
Fed's experience in the May-June 2003 period indicates that
references to inflationary or deflationary risks cannot reliably
substitute for an explicit long-run inflation target.
The indication in the announcement following the May 2003 FOMC
meeting that significant further disinflation would be unwelcome, in our
view, effectively put a lower bound on the Fed's tolerance range or
comfort zone for inflation. At the time, inflation was running at around
1 percent in terms of the core PCE, one of the Fed's preferred
inflation measures. (23) The assertion of a lower bound seemed prudent
given the deflation risk discussed above and the fact that the federal
funds rate at the time was 1 1/4 percent. The Fed's statement
served two useful purposes--it alerted the public to the small but real
risk of deflation while also asserting implicitly that the Fed would act
to deter further disinflation.
The assertion of the lower bound on inflation, however, came as a
surprise that took the expected future path of the federal funds rate
sharply lower and pulled longer-term interest rates down as well.
Commentary in the media amplified nervousness about deflation well
beyond what was justified in the economic data. In the event, the Fed
reduced its federal funds rate target only 25 basis points, rather than
the widely anticipated 50 basis points, at the June FOMC meeting. And
longer-term interest rates promptly reversed field. (24)
Our reading of this episode is that references to the probability
of rising or falling inflation in FOMC policy statements cannot reliably
substitute for an announced, explicit inflation target range. One of the
most important lessons of rational expectations theory is that it is
particularly difficult for the public to gauge the intent of a policy
action taken out of context, and, therefore, it is particularly
difficult for the Fed to predict the effect of an unsystematic policy
action. (25) We think this reasoning extends to policy announcements as
well. Since the ad hoc implicit announcement of a lower bound on the
Fed's tolerance range for inflation was unsystematic by definition,
it is not surprising that the announcement caused confusion, nor that
the Fed failed to predict the public's reaction. In this case the
reaction was excessive, but in another situation there might have been
an insufficient reaction.
If an inflation target range had been in place in 2003, the public
could have inferred the Fed's growing concern about disinflation as
the inflation rate drifted down toward the bottom of the range through
the first half of the year. Expected future federal funds rates and
longer-term interest rates would have moved lower continuously, with
less chance of overshooting or undershooting the Fed's intended
policy stance. We recommend that the Fed publicly commit to maintaining
core PCE inflation within a target range of 1 to 2 percent over the long
run so that such misunderstandings won't recur at either end of the
Fed's tolerance range for inflation. (26)
The Fed's assertion of an inflation target might appear to
some to usurp a congressional prerogative. We think otherwise for three
reasons.
First, we believe a compelling case can be made that, beyond
underlining the Fed's long-term responsibilities for price
stability, an inflation target would be a valuable addition to the
Fed's operational communications procedures. From this perspective,
we believe that at least implicitly Congress has already delegated
authority to set an inflation target to the Fed as part of its
operational independence.
Second, as we emphasized earlier, monetary policy best facilitates
achievement of the Fed's other mandated policy goals--such as
maximum sustainable employment, economic growth, and financial
stability--by making price stability a priority.
Third, an inflation target would not prevent or hinder the Fed from
taking the kinds of policy actions it takes today to stabilize
employment and output in the short run. What it would do is discipline
the Fed to ensure that these actions are consistent with its commitment
to protect the purchasing power of the currency. (27)
Clarifying Short-Run Policy Aims with Gap Indicators
The second opportunity for improved communication noted above is
more effective explanation of the reasons for particular short-term
policy actions. The macroeconomic framework presented above locates the
potential for departures from price stability in the sign, size, and
expected persistence of the average price-cost gap between actual
markups and the respective profit-maximizing markups. In practice,
indicators of the employment gap and the output gap are also used, in
conjunction with preferable but hard-to-measure price-cost gap
indicators, to assess the risks to price stability. (28) (Recall that
tightness or slack in the labor market is what causes nominal wages to
accelerate or decelerate. Markup dynamics then govern the transmission
of these nominal wage dynamics to the price level.) Recently, the Fed
has mentioned only the growth of output or productivity, and the
improvement or deterioration in employment in its policy statements, and
has rarely if ever mentioned markups, price-cost gaps, or employment and
output gaps.
We recognize that gap indicators are particularly difficult to
estimate, especially in real time. One must measure the average markup,
aggregate employment and output and estimate the time-varying levels of
these aggregates believed to be consistent with price stability. And one
must forecast future changes in these gap indicators in order to assess
the risks to price stability. Furthermore, one must decide how to weight
the various indicators in the overall assessment when inevitable
inconsistencies occur.
There is a natural reluctance to feature gaps in the Fed's
policy statements because of the unfortunate experience in the 1960s and
'70s, when calling attention to employment and output gaps created
pressure that ultimately led to inflationary monetary policy and very
poor macroeconomic performance. (29) Even so, Fed economists necessarily
employ, internally at least, implicit estimates of the price-cost gap,
the employment gap, and the output gap to evaluate the potential for
inflation or deflation. Therefore, gaps ought to be mentioned more
prominently in the Fed's post-FOMC policy statements and other
important regular policy reports such as the FOMC meeting minutes and
the semiannual monetary policy reports to Congress. (30) This would help
to avoid confusion in periods such as the recent past when productivity
growth has been rising and fluctuating widely with substantial effects
on employment and production costs.
In the second half of 2003 the Fed had difficulty convincing
financial markets of its inclination to maintain a low federal funds
rate for a "considerable period." (31) One reason for this, in
our view, was that its policy statements emphasized explicitly strong
real economic growth during the period but paid insufficient attention
to the sizable gap in employment and the cumulative deflation in unit
labor costs that had almost certainly widened the price-cost gap. The
apparent size and likely persistence of these gaps produced the
disinflation that occurred in 2003 and constituted the deflation risk
that inclined the Fed to keep the federal funds rate low.
To sum up, we believe that the Fed has much to gain and little to
lose by referring to price-cost, employment, and output gaps more
prominently. (32) By communicating more explicitly in terms of gap
indicators, the Fed could clarify substantially its views regarding
inflationary or deflationary risks and make expected future federal
funds rates conform more closely to its preemptive policy intentions.
If the Fed clarifies its short-run policy aims with gap indicators,
however, it is critical that it also discipline itself by announcing an
explicit long-run inflation target to deal with any inconsistencies that
may appear between gap indicators and inflation performance. The Fed
should acknowledge its definition of price stability to avoid repeating
either the inflationary mistakes of the 1960s and '70s or the
deflationary mistakes of the 1930s.
6. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
In this article, we have sought to provide a framework for thinking
about how monetary policy can maintain price stability. The core
principle--taken from the new neoclassical synthesis--is that inflation
will remain low and stable if and only if firms, on average across the
economy, expect departures from their profit-maximizing markups to be
relatively small and transitory. We explained how interest rate policy
works to maintain price stability by managing aggregate demand to offset
the effect on production costs of shocks to expected future income
prospects and current productivity.
Monetary policy is most effective when the public is confident that
the Fed will act to stabilize production costs promptly after a
shock--what we referred to as "credibility" for price
stability. When the Fed has credibility, prices are relatively
insensitive to cost shocks on average, since firms expect the Fed to
manage aggregate demand to reverse pressures on costs in either
direction promptly. Credibility anchors expected inflation and enables
the Fed to act aggressively to prevent recessions. On the other hand, we
indicated how the absence of credibility raises the risk of recession
whenever the economy is confronted with either an inflation scare or a
deflation scare.
The Fed's current credibility as an inflation fighter is now
firmly established, but the zero bound on interest rate policy impedes
the extension of that credibility, in any straightforward way, to
deflation. We pointed out, however, that ultimately monetary policy must
be able to deter deflation at the zero bound; otherwise, the government
could eliminate explicit taxes and finance all of its expenditure
forever with money created by the Fed.
We identified several operational and institutional obstacles that
the Fed should address to make quantitative policy (as opposed to
interest rate policy) credible against deflation at the zero bound. In
particular, we pointed out that in order to secure full credibility
against deflation, the Fed will need more fiscal support for
quantitative policy at the zero bound than is usually granted by the
fiscal authorities.
Finally, we offered two recommendations for improving the
Fed's communication policy designed to address the kinds of
problems the Fed faced in conveying its concerns about deflation in
2003. First, the Fed should commit publicly to maintaining core PCE
inflation within a target range of 1 to 2 percent over the long run. We
think that an inflation target should be regarded, not just as a policy
goal, but as an essential part of communication policy.
Second, the sign, size, and expected persistence of price-cost,
output, and employment gap indicators play a central role in gauging the
risks to price stability and in preempting inflation and deflation. We
recommend that the Fed feature such gap indicators more prominently in
its statements and discussions about policy to clarify the potential for
inflation or deflation in its outlook, and to clarify its intentions for
dealing with these threats. We emphasize that the Fed should announce an
explicit inflation target so that it does not stray from price stability
under any circumstances.
The role of monetary policy in halting what seemed to be an
inexorable rise in inflation in the 1970s, and subsequently reducing it
during the '80s and '90s to an acceptable level, is in our
view one of the greatest achievements in the Fed's history. We hope
that our article will help the Fed to surmount its next challenge--the
maintenance of price stability--in the years ahead.
This article first appeared in the Bank's 2003 Annual Report.
The authors are President, and Senior Vice President and Policy Advisor,
respectively. Robert Hetzel, Jeffrey Lacker, Bennett McCallum, Aaron
Steelman, and John Walter contributed valuable comments. The views
expressed are the authors' and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve System.
(1) See Greenspan (2003, 5).
(2) See Bernanke (2003) for a discussion of the nature of the
deflation risk.
(3) See, for instance, Goodfriend and King (2001) and Goodfriend
(2004).
(4) New neoclassical synthesis (NNS) models feature complete
microeconomic foundations as in real business cycle economies and
imperfect competition and sticky prices as in New Keynesian economies.
New synthesis models are thoroughly discussed and analyzed in Goodfriend
and King (1997, 2001) and Woodford (2003). The Federal Reserve
Board's FRB-US macromodel shares many of the central features of
the NNS approach (see Brayton et al. [1997]), as does the model of
monetary policy discussed extensively in Clarida, Galf, and Gertler
(1999).
(5) Monopolistically competitive firms have the market power to set
their product price above the marginal cost of production.
(6) The term "on average" is important. Obviously,
individual firms adjust particular prices in response to sector- and
firm-specific demand and supply conditions as well as the broader
pricing environment.
(7) An excessively high markup is counterproductive because it
yields too much market share to competitors; conversely, a markup that
is too small does not exploit a firm's market power sufficiently.
(8) We focus on labor and ignore capital and raw material costs to
simplify our exposition. Labor costs alone account for about two-thirds
of the cost of producing goods and services.
(9) See Goodfriend (2002) for an exposition of the mechanics of
interest rate policy geared to maintaining price stability in a new
synthesis model. Woodford (2003) presents an extensive treatment of
interest rate policy. Clarida, Galf, and Gertler (1999) provide a useful
survey. We ignore the zero-bound constraint on interest rate policy in
this section, assuming, in effect, that the shocks are small enough that
the zero-bound constraint never binds.
(10) Optimism or pessimism regarding job prospects, profitable
investment opportunities, taxes, and war, for example, would all affect
future income prospects.
(11) Weak productivity growth, however, was only part of the story
in the 1970s: inflation rose long before the extended productivity
slowdown began in 1974 and fell briefly thereafter, before rising again
in 1978.
(12) See Goodfriend (1993). See Orphanides and Williams (2004) for
a quantitative, theoretical analysis of inflation scares in a model of
perpetual learning.
(13) Potential GDP refers to the path of output consistent with the
maintenance of price stability.
(14) Kennedy (1999) describes U.S. economic policies in the 1930s
as a collection of market interventions taken to support favored sectors
of the economy. Cole and Ohanian (2001) model these interventions and
show quantitatively that they can explain the persistence of the Great
Depression in the United States.
(15) It is worth pointing out that credibility for price stability
is also threatened when Fed participation in foreign exchange operations
with the Treasury creates doubt about whether monetary policy will
support domestic or international objectives. See Broaddus and
Goodfriend (1996).
(16) Deflations in the early 1920s and in the 1930s were
particularly destructive; milder deflations at other times caused less
distress.
(17) The Fed is not free to expand the size of its balance sheet as
long as it targets a federal funds rate even slightly above zero. In
that case, the size of its balance sheet is constrained to create a
scarcity of bank reserves just sufficient to maintain the desired
positive federal funds rate.
(18) Technically, a deflation trap is not a possible
rational-expectations equilibrium if the nominal value of total
government liabilities will not decline, even in the presence of
sustained deflation. See Woodford (2003, 133).
(19) When the federal funds rate has been pushed to zero, there is
no opportunity cost to holding currency or bank reserves relative to
short-term securities. Hence, the public is indifferent at the margin
between holding cash or short-term securities, and open market purchases
of short-term securities have no effect.
(20) See Broaddus and Goodfriend (2001).
(21) For instance, long-term bonds purchased to stimulate the
economy when interest rates are near zero suffer large capital losses
when interest rates rise as the economy recovers.
(22) See Dudley (2003).
(23) See Federal Open Market Committee (1996, 11).
(24) See Ip (2003, June 27 and August 15).
(25) McCallum (2004) makes a related point.
(26) While the core PCE, the Fed's preferred inflation measure
internally, seems a straightforward choice for the index on which to
base its target measure, the better-known consumer price index could be
used instead. Our framework suggests that the Fed should target a core
inflation index that closely reflects sticky prices set by
monopolistically competitive firms.
(27) This repeats a point made by Broaddus at the January 1995 FOMC
meeting. See Federal Open Market Committee (1995, 41).
(28) The output gap measures aggregate output relative to an
estimated potential level of output consistent with price stability. The
employment gap measures aggregate employment relative to an estimated
level of employment believed to be consistent with price stability.
(29) See, for example, Orphanides (2002).
(30) McCallum (2001) discusses conceptual and operational problems
involved in measuring employment gaps and output gaps, and argues that
monetary policy should not respond strongly to such gaps in its monetary
policy rule.
(31) These words were employed initially in the policy statement
following the August 2003 FOMC meeting. See Ip (2003, August 13). The
FOMC dropped the "considerable period" language at its January
2004 meeting, saying instead that it could be "patient" in
raising interest rates.
(32) Our recommendation is consistent with evidence presented in
Kohn and Sack (2003) that greater clarity in the Fed's statements
about the economic outlook would improve monetary policy.
REFERENCES
Bernanke, Ben S. 2003. "An Unwelcome Fall in Inflation?"
Remarks before the Economics Roundtable, University of California, San
Diego; La Jolla, Calif. (July 23).
Brayton, Flint, Andrew Levin, Ralph Tryon, and John C. Williams.
1997. "The Evolution of Macro Models at the Federal Reserve
Board." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 47
(December): 43-81. Ed. Bennett McCallum and Charles Plosser.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr., and Marvin Goodfriend. 1996.
"Foreign Exchange Operations and the Federal Reserve." Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 82 (Winter): 1-19.
________________. 2001. "What Assets Should the Federal
Reserve Buy?" In The Fiftieth Anniversary of the Accord: Issues in
Treasury-Federal Reserve Relations, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 87 (Winter): 7-22.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler. 1999. "The
Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective." Journal
of Economic Literature 37 (December): 1661-707.
Cole, Harold, and Lee Ohanian. 2001. "New Deal Policies and
the Persistence of the Great Depression: A General Equilibrium Analysis." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Department
Working Paper 597 (May).
Dudley, Bill. 2003. "The Need for Clear Communication."
Goldman Sachs U.S. Economics Analyst (September 12): 1-6.
Federal Open Market Committee. 1995. Transcript, January
31-February 1: 39-59.
______________. 1996. Transcript, July 2-3.
Goodfriend, Marvin. 1993. "Interest Rate Policy and the
Inflation Scare Problem: 1979-1992." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 79 (Winter): 1-24.
______________. 2002. "Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical
Synthesis: A Primer." International Finance 5 (Summer): 165-91.
Reprinted in Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 90
(Summer 2004).
______________. 2004. "Inflation Targeting in the United
States?" Forthcoming in Inflation Targeting, ed. Ben S. Bernanke
and Michael Woodford. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Also: NBER Working Paper 9981 (September 2003).
______________, and Robert King. 1997. "The New Neoclassical
Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg. Cambridge: MIT Press, 231-83.
______________. 2001. "The Case for Price Stability." Why
Price Stability? Proceedings from the First ECB Central Banking
Conference, ed. A. Herrero, V. Gaspar, L. Hoogduin, J. Morgan, and B.
Winkler. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. Also: NBER Working Paper 8423
(August).
Greenspan, Alan. 2003. Federal Reserve Board's Semiannual
Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, testimony before the Committee
on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate (July 16).
Ip, Greg. 2003. "Fed Fails to Sway Bond Investors--Yields Rise
as Market Holds to Economic View; Rate Cut Found Lacking." Wall
Street Journal (June 27): A2.
______________. 2003. "The Economy: Fed Keeps Interest-Rate
Target at 1%--Expected Decision Comes with Surprise Commitment to
Continue Very Low Levels." Wall Street Journal (August 13): A2.
______________. 2003. "The Economy: Fed Missed Mark On Impact
of Cut on Bond Market." Wall Street Journal (August 15): A2.
Kennedy, David. 1999. Freedom from Fear: The American People in
Depression and War, 1929-1945. New York: Oxford University Press.
Kohn, Donald L., and Brian P. Sack. 2003. "Central Bank Talk:
Does It Matter and Why?" Finance and Economics Discussion Series
2003-55, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
McCallum, Bennett. 2001. "Should Monetary Policy Respond
Strongly to Output Gaps?" American Economic Review 91 (May):
258-62.
______________. 2004. "Misconceptions Regarding Rules vs.
Discretion for Monetary Policy." Cato Journal 23 (Winter): 365-72.
Orphanides, Athanasios. 2002. "Monetary Policy Rules and the
Great Inflation." American Economic Review 92 (May): 115-20.
______________, and John C. Williams. 2004. "Imperfect
Knowledge, Inflation Expectations, and Monetary Policy."
Forthcoming in Inflation Targeting, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Michael
Woodford. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. Also: NBER
Working Paper 9884 (August 2003).
Woodford, Michael. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a
Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.