Tom Humphrey: an appreciation.
Weinberg, John A.
This issue of the Economic Quarterly marks the end of Tom
Humphrey's tenure as editor. Tom, who is retiring at the end of
2004, took on the role of editor of the Monthly Review in 1975 and
continued in that post as the publication evolved, first into the
bimonthly Economic Review, and eventually into its current form as the
Economic Quarterly. Over that time, Tom has guided to publication
hundreds of articles by Department economists and visiting scholars. He
has also found the time to write more than 70 articles for this
publication, its predecessors, and the Bank's Annual Report, not to
mention numerous articles for external publications. His editorial gaze
has seen many changes in our publication, our department, and the
economics profession over the last 30 years. Despite these changes,
Tom's editorial guidance has provided a constancy to the quality of
our publications, just as his own work has stressed a certain constancy
to the ideas and debates that have engaged economists throughout the
history of our profession.
Tom came to this Bank in 1970, an opportune time for a young
monetary economist with an interest in the history of thought on the
subject. Much of the profession's thinking on aggregate
fluctuations and inflation was still dominated by the Keynesian view
that emphasized movements in aggregate demand as the force driving real
output. The taxonomy of "demand-pull" and
"cost-push" inflation allowed for a variety of causes, mostly
unrelated to the central bank's monetary policy. Empirical evidence
on the Phillips curve trade-off seemed to suggest that price stability
could only be had at an unacceptable cost of long-lasting, high
unemployment. In the Keynesian view, money was just one part of a broad
spectrum of liquid assets, the evolution of which further limited the
central bank's ability to control inflation.
The Keynesian view, however, faced a challenge from the monetarist school of thought that placed the quantity of money at the center of the
determination of the price level and other nominal variables. This
quantity theory view, which presumed the long-run neutrality of money,
allowed for short run real effects when money growth and inflation
deviated from their expected rates. Indeed, under this view erratic
monetary policy was seen as a primary cause of economic fluctuations.
Where the Keynesian school saw causation running from prices to money,
the monetarist view was the opposite; the central bank, through its
control of the monetary base, could achieve price stability without a
long-run inflation-unemployment tradeoff.
Of course, the 1970s experience of high unemployment and high
inflation presented a particular challenge to the traditional Keynesian
view. It all appeared to underscore the importance of expectations, a
view that gave rise ultimately to the rational expectations revolution.
This evolution of thinking played itself out in the profession
throughout Tom's career at the Richmond Fed and in the Economic
Quarterly and its predecessors under Tom's editorial eye. Along the
way, he established himself as a leading scholar on the history of
monetary thought.
Tom's notable contribution has been to make clear that the
debates that took place during his career as a Federal Reserve economist
were in fact not new to the 1970s, or even to the 20th century. Applying
his knowledge of the history of monetary thought, Tom traced the debate
from the mercantilist writers John Law and James Steuart to their
classical quantity theory critics David Hume and others in the 18th
century, to the Bullionist-Antibullionist controversy in the early 19th
century, to the Currency School-Banking School debate in the middle
decades of that century, to the mid-19th / early 20th century disputes
between cost-pushers Thomas Tooke and James Laurence Laughlin and their
opponents Knut Wicksell and Irving Fisher, and finally to the German
hyperinflation debate of the early-to-mid-1920s. He showed that the
debate keeps recycling because people forget the lessons of the past and
because, for better or worse, politicians and the public have tended to
believe that central banks have the power to boost output, employment,
and growth permanently. The result is that Keynesian ideas and their
antecedents gained currency when unemployment was the main concern, just
as monetarist ideas tended to reign when price stability was the
dominant problem.
This historical perspective makes it clear that the central
dimensions along which people have thought and debated about monetary
policy and inflation have always remained essentially the same, even as
economic thinking and methodology have evolved. It also shows that
intellectual debate can be affected by political forces and the
fluctuating degree of social concern for different problems. This last
point provides an important cautionary tale for current and future
economists and policymakers. Indeed, Tom's article in this issue
shows that the recurrence of debates and the interaction of political
forces with intellectual discourse are not unique to monetary concerns.
Similar patterns can be seen in the history of thinking on such
questions as the effects of technology on labor.
We at the Richmond Fed have gained much from our association with
Tom Humphrey. We have benefited both from the red pen he has wielded to
make our papers more readable and, more importantly, from the long-view
perspective he has brought to our thinking about economics and monetary
policy. For all this we thank him, and we offer him our best wishes. We
won't say good-bye, though, as I'm sure we'll be hearing
from him again.